Get 20M+ Full-Text Papers For Less Than $1.50/day. Start a 14-Day Trial for You or Your Team.

Learn More →

Wage determination, Global Value Chains and role played by wage bargaining schemes: The case of Poland

Wage determination, Global Value Chains and role played by wage bargaining schemes: The case of... Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022: 88-110 DOI: 10.18559/ebr.2022.4.5 Wage determination, Global Value Chains and role played by wage bargaining schemes: The case of Poland 2 3 Dagmara Nikulin , Joanna Wolszczak-Derlacz Abstract: This study examines the linkages between GVC involvement and wages in Poland given die ff rent wage bargaining schemes. The analysis is based on microdata from the European Structure of Earnings Survey for Poland combined with sectoral data from the World Input-Output Database. In particular, two measures of GVC involve- ment were used: the share of foreign value added (FVA) to export and the measure of traditional os ff horing. e Th institutional settings are represented by the wage bargaining scheme which ree fl cts the level at which the collective pay is agreed. The results show that despite the lack of a signic fi ant relationship between the sectoral involvement in GVC and the level of wages in Poland, on average workers covered by the collective pay agreement receive higher wages. Moreover, the wage-GVC nexus is conditioned on the type of pay agreements: the positive wage ee ff ct from national agreements is eliminated for a certain range of GVC intensity. Keywords: wages, Global Value Chains, wage bargaining. JEL codes: F16, F66, J81. Introduction Wage determination is a popular topic that has been tackled by many scientists over the years. Moreover, for post-communist countries the aspect of deter- minants of individual workers’ wages is even more interesting since the wage behaviour of firms changed considerably during the transition to a  market economy (evidence for the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland and Hungary is described in Basu, Estrin, & Svejnar, 2004). The changes which took place ae ft r Article received 1 December 2021, accepted 5 October 2022. This paper is carried out within the project financed by the National Science Centre, Poland (grant number: 2015/19/B/ HS4/02884). Gdańsk University of Technology, Faculty of Management and Economics, Naruto wi- cza 11/12, 80-233 Gdańsk, Poland, corresponding author: dnikulin@zie.pg.gda.pl, https://orcid. org/0000-0002-0534-4553. Gdańsk University of Technology, Faculty of Management and Economics, Naruto wi- cza 11/12, 80-233 Gdańsk, Poland, jwo@zie.pg.gda.pl, https://orcid.org/0000-0002-3392-5267. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 89 the breakdown of communism contributed significantly to the new shape of the industrial relations. The large-scale privatisation, inflows of foreign direct investments as well as the accession to the EU which forced the modernisation of the labour law started to create new patterns of relations between labour market actors (Stockhammer & Onaran, 2009). The experience of the global financial crisis and related rapid decline in exports resulting from decreasing foreign demand accelerated the conclusion of labour agreements in order to help companies survive during the crisis and retain employees in Central and Eastern European countries (CEECs) (Bernaciak, 2015). Nowadays the literature indicates two new important trends describing the determinants that create current labour market outcomes: involvement in the global production sharing processes on the one hand and the role played by the labour market institutions on the another. Referring to the r fi st trend the pro - cess of global production sharing was developed through the concept of Global Value Chain (GVC) which is understood as “the full range of activities that r fi ms and workers perform to bring a product from its conception to end use and beyond” (Gereffi & Fernandez-Stark, 2016, p. 7). Despite the fact that the ef - fects of GVC on labour markets (wages, inequalities, job losses, labour produc- tivity) are widely examined in the literature (Baumgarten, Geishecker, & Görg, 2013; Geishecker, Görg & Munch, 2010; Parteka & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2019), the institutional factors are described less frequently. e Th majority of existing research focuses on the ee ff ct of globalised production on wages. Early studies on the impact of os ff horing (as international trade involvement measure) on wages (Baumgarten et al., 2013; Ebenstein, Harrison, McMillan, & Phillips, 2014; Hummels, Jørgensen, Munch, & Xiang, 2014) as well as further studies based on the concept of GVC (Autor, Dorn & Hanson, 2016; Parteka & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2020; Szymczak & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2022) reveal divergent results (for meta- analysis see Cardoso, Neves, Afono, & Sochirca, 2021). In general for developed countries a slightly negative impact of GVC participation is conr fi med as far as backward linkages are considered, whilst in the case of forward linkages the as- sociation may be ambiguous (Szymczak & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2022). Importantly, a relevant research question concerns the role played by the technological progress and the related process automatization which is widely described in the literature (among others Acemoglu & Autor, 2011; Acemoglu & Restrepo, 2018; Goos, Manning & Salomons, 2014). Moreover, recently increasing attention is being paid to the role of new technology on the labour market (Gruetzemacher, Dorner, Bernaola-Alvarez, Giattino, & Manheim, 2021). However, as the main focus of this study is the labour market institutions and GVC additional covariates are not included. The authors are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing this out. For detailed presentation of the concept and governance of GVC see the book by Milberg and Winkler (2013). e a Th mbiguous results may be explained by three die ff rent forces: productivity, relative price and labour-supply ee ff cts which may ae ff ct the labour market outcomes (Grossman & Rossi-Hansberg, 2008). 90 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 On the other hand labour market institutions are claimed to be a key factor in creating the wage-setting mechanisms (Gerlach & Stephan, 2006; Aringa & Pagani, 2007; Avouyi-Dovi, Fougére & Gautier, 2013; Eurofound, 2015; and oth- ers). According to the publication Collective bargaining in Europe: Towards an endgame issued by the European Trade Union Institute (ETUI) which is deeply involved in the concept of collective bargaining the wages of about two-thirds of European workers are negotiated in a collective way (Müller, Vandaele, & Waddington, 2019a). However, having in mind that the story related to the industrialisation process differs fundamentally in Central and Eastern coun - tries when compared to Western ones (Bernaciak, 2015), there are signic fi ant die ff rences in the collective bargaining coverage across countries—from 12% in Bulgaria, 14% in Latvia, to 46% in the Czech Republic (Müller, Vandaele, & Waddington, 2019c). Regarding Poland, the collective bargaining coverage rate has declined in recent decades from 25% in 2000 to about 18% in 2017. Similarly, Poland’s unionisation rate is one of the lowest in the European Union and accounts for 12% (Müller, Vandaele, & Waddington, 2019b). In this study the two above-mentioned literature trends are analysed to- gether namely: GVC and wage bargaining schemes and their association with wages. Past evidence shows that only a few studies describe the relationships between wage determinations, GVC and labour market institutions (Las Heras, 2018; Guschanski & Onaran, 2021; Luo & Yang, 2020). The recent study from Ndubuisi & Owusu (2022) who use sectoral data reveals that in strictly regu- lated labour markets the impact of GVC on wages may be positive. As regards post-communist countries there are hardly any studies in this area. Against this background the trade-related shocks may be moderated by the institution- al environment (Rodrik, Subramanian, & Trebbi, 2004). Going further if the institutional environment is taken into account the impact of trade on wages may be negligible (Rodrik et al., 2004). e Th refore the simultaneous analysis of the association between wages, trade and institutional background is of great importance. The main goal of this paper is to investigate the wage determination in Poland and to examine the role of wage bargaining level and the involvement in global production fragmentation processes. The contribution is based on providing simultaneously an analysis of wages, GVC and labour market insti- tutions where both wages as well as wage bargaining schemes are considered on an individual level. The study is based on a Polish case, where Poland is characterised by rather weak collective bargaining schemes: the trade unions Stockhammer and Onaran (2009) examined the association between wage determina- tion and wage bargaining schemes controlling for the trade openness and foreign direct invest- ment stocks. Parteka and Wolszczak-Derlacz (2020) added labour market institution variables on country level in their cross-country analysis. Among existing studies Guschanski and Onaran (2021) examined the nexus among wages, wage bargaining and os ff horing on the basis of sectoral data. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 91 are fragmented, sectoral agreements are scarce and the bargaining is largely decentralised (Bernaciak, 2015). We argue that an analysis of the relationship between wages and involvement in international trade in a  country differ - ent from Western countries (which have a much longer tradition of collec- tive labour agreements) is interesting. In order to fulfil the aim of this study an econometric analysis based on the augmented Mincerian wage regression is employed. i Th s paper consists of five sections. Section 1 is a review of the literature re - garding wage determination, GVC and labour market institutions. Section 2 is empirical and presents data, the model and results. Section 3 adds extensions to the baseline model. Last section contains conclusions. 1. Literature review The association between trade, institutions and wage determination is not straightforward. Starting with the considerations of Milberg and Houston (2005) on the linkages between bargaining and international competitiveness the stronger institutional arrangements may be associated with better inter- national economic performance. That is to say that the authors claim a hump- shaped relationship (following the findings from Calmfors and Driffill (1988) between the wage bargaining coverage and international competitiveness. On the other hand international trade involvement and the related increased competition may cause a downward pressure on wages while strong unions may mitigate this ee ff ct. As Schulten (2016) argues the high rate of bargaining coverage may ensure sustainable and inclusive growth. However, it has to be taken into account that GVC involvement may be associated with decreased market power and therefore the extent to which the wages may be negotiat- ed through collective bargaining is limited (Nickell & Layard, 1999). Ramirez and Rainbird (2010) discuss a relationship between GVC and institutions one element of which is the above-mentioned pressure caused by international competition. They note that the institutions have an impact on the process of skill formation among firms participating in GVC and the skill structure de - termines the wage structure. Importantly, the impact of bargaining power on wages may be dependent on the level at which the bargaining is coordinated (Nunziata, 2005). In turn the existing evidence for developing countries shows that through introducing collective pay bargaining it is possible to achieve an improvement of working conditions (e.g. a rise in pay levels) and therefore a minimalization of the negative implications of GVC participation (Selwyn, 2013). Moreover, as Selwyn (2013) argues since greater involvement in GVC may be associated with a downgrade of working conditions it may be mitigated by the proper in- stitutional interventions such as collective bargaining. In the case of Europe the 92 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 situation regarding the collective bargaining structures is varied. In European countries collective pay agreements are predominantly set as wage floors for die ff rent occupation groups (Card & Cardoso, 2021). Moreover, in several European countries (Portugal, Spain, Italy, Belgium, the Netherlands, France) the system of wage bargaining is based on sectoral schemes in which the wage o fl or is established. This results in considerable flexibility and latitude in wage determination even in the same sector. Going further a shift towards decen - tralisation is visible in the form of the two-tier structure of collective bargain- ing. The two-tier structure is based on the assumption that the negations which take place at the plant level have a complementary role in relation to the mul- ti-employer wage agreements which take place at the national, industry or re- gional level (Boeri, 2014). As the post-communist countries have a die ff rent institutional background from the Western countries the economic ee ff cts of the collective bargaining may also be die ff rent for the Central and Eastern economies (Stockhammer & Onaran, 2009). Following the hypothesis proposed by Calmfors and Driffill (1988) the best labour market outcomes are obtained for industrial relations which are highly organised or highly disorganised while the worst outcomes are recorded for the intermediate level of industrial organisation. As Kohl and Platzer (2007) argue in the case of Central and Eastern European countries it is possible to identify the transitional model of industrial relations according to which in the private sector and multinational companies “union-free” zones may be distinguished. This results in low bargaining coverage. Consequently the existing evidence assessing the linkages between wage determination, labour market institutions and trade involvement is mainly focused on the Western European countries. Summing up the existing evidence on the wage bargaining schemes nexus from European countries gives contrasting results: on the one hand see the re- search of Schäfer and Gottschall (2015) who find a positive relationship be - tween the wage bargaining centralisation degree and the wage level and on the other hand—the review by the European Commission (2015) which argues that for decentralised bargaining schemes the wages are higher. What is more once the impact of international production fragmentation is covered the existing evidence is much more scarce (Guschanski & Onaran, 2021). Based on the literature review the following research questions are formu- lated: 1. What is the association between wage bargaining scheme and wages? 2. Is the relationship between GVC and wages dependent on the type of col- lective pay agreement? An up-do-date compilation of industrial relations and wages across Europe is presented in Brandl and others (2021). D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 93 2. Empirical analysis 2.1. Data In order to answer the research question formulated above micro-level data for the Polish economy is used. The core database is derived from Eurostat (the European Structure of Earnings Survey: SES) for the year 2014 and contains information about over 700,000 Polish representative workers. The access to this micro-level data was granted based on an individual research proposal. The SES is a cyclical survey conducted in EU Member States as well as EU candidate countries and European Free Trade Association (EFTA) countries. The cross- sectional data covers information on the level of pay and individual character- istics of employees (sex, age, occupation, length of service, highest educational level attained, etc.) and their employers (economic activity, size and location of the enterprise). The descriptive statistics of the variables used are presented in Table A2 in the Appendix. The micro-level data are merged with the sec - toral data derived from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD) (Timmer, Dietzenbacher, Los, Stehrer, & de Vries, 2015) based on which die ff rent meas - ures of GVC involvement are calculated. Table A1 in the Appendix provides information on the distribution of the collective bargaining coverage in Poland across die ff rent industries. Detailed description of the variables is presented in the next section of this paper. 2.2. Model e m Th ain aim of this study is to check whether wages of individual workers are associated with GVC involvement and collective agreements. In order to verify these propositions the following form of augmented Mincerian wage regres- sion (reviewed in Heckman, Lochner, & Todd, 2006) is proposed: lnw = α + β GVC + β Agreement + β Pers + β Firm + β Sec + ε (1) ifs 1 s 2 i 3 i 4 f 5 s ifs where: i – worker; f – company, s – sector of employment. The log of worker’s wage (lnw) on set of personal variables (Pers) and firm’s characteristics ( Firm) was regressed. Personal variables include: sex (sex, male = 1); age of the work- ers (expressed via three binary variables: [ageyoung] which takes the value 1 A longer description of the SES database as well as the detailed description of the variables is available on the Eurostat web page https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/microdata/structure-of- earnings-survey. Specic fi ally the decomposition is done with the usage of R package decompr (Quast & Kummritz, 2015). See also: (Szymczak, Parteka, & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2022). e h Th ourly average wage was used. 94 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 for workers classie fi d as under 30 years old, [ ageaverage] with the value 1 for workers between 30–49 years old and [ageold] indicating workers over 50 years old); educational level (grouped into 3 categories: low education which includes less than primary, primary and lower secondary levels [loweduc = 1], medium education covering upper secondary and post-secondary levels [mededuc = 1] and higher education which denotes tertiary education up to and above 4 years [higheduc = 1]); skills levels (four skill categories based on occupation classification: skill_1 [elementary occupations], skill_2 [clerical support work- ers, service and sales workers, skilled agricultural, forestry and fishery workers, craft and related trades workers, plant and machine operators, and assemblers], skill_3 [technicians and associate professionals], skill_4 [managers and profes- sionals]); and type of employment (full time versus part time [full time = 1]). Among the set of firm characteristics ( Firm), there is information about the duration of employee’s experience working within a given unit (split into bi- nary variables: less than 1 year [shordur = 1], between 1–4 years [meddur = 1] and more than 4 years [longdur = 1]), size of the company (described by the number of employees (binary variables: between 1–49 employees [small = 1], between 50-249 [medium = 1] and above 250 employees [large = 1]), informa- tion on the form of economic and financial control (classie fi d into public and private [public = 1]) and the type of the contract (permanent versus temporal [temp = 1]). Moreover, the information about sector productivity calculated as value added per number of hours worked (WIOD) was included. e Th re are two variables of major interest. Firstly, the type of a collective pay agreement (Agreement) which equals 1 if a worker is covered by a collective pay agreement regardless of its level and 0 otherwise. According to the data derived from the SES it is possible to distinguish four levels at which collective bargaining takes place: (1) the national level (Agreement_nat) if the negotia- tions take place at the national or interconfederal level, (2) the industry level if the negotiations are held for a given industry, economic sector or individual industries in individual regions, (3) the enterprise level (Agreement_enter) if the negotiations cover only the employees of the same employer and (4) no agreement (Eurostat, 2014). Secondly, the variables related to the measures of GVC involvement. For this study two measures were calculated: (1) the share of foreign value added (FVA) to export (as presented by Wang, Wei, & Zhu, 2013) which measures the backward linkages in the international production pro- cesses and (2) the measure of traditional os ff horing calculated as the share of intermediate inputs to the value added (as in Feenstra & Hanson, 1999). As the impact of traditional trade and GVC may be die ff rent depending on the type of product traded (final vs. intermediate) (Szymczak & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2022) In the case of Poland this level of collective bargaining is not observed and not included in the empirical analysis. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 95 both of the measures in order to examine the possible die ff rence in the impact are employed. These variables are represented by the term GVC in the models. In the next step the baseline model (Equation 1) is augmented to include the interaction term between variables Agreement and GVC: lnw = α + β GVC + β Agreement + β Agreement × GVC + ifs 1 s 2 i 3 i s + β Pers + β Firm + β Sec + ε (2) 4 i 5 f 6 s ifs According to Equation (2), the association between GVC and wages varies with the type of collective pay agreement, e.g. for workers without pay agree- ment for whom Agreement = 0, the marginal ee ff ct of GVC on wages ( ceteris paribus) corresponds to β , while in the case of workers with pay agreement (Agreement = 1), the marginal ee ff ct equals β + β . 1 3 Finally, the analogous analysis is repeated but replacing the variable Agreement with binary variables describing the exact level of collective pay agreement: en- terprise agreement (Agreement_enter), national agreement (Agreement_nat) or no agreement (Agreement_no) which is the default/missing category. lnw = α + β GVC + β Agreement_enter + β Agreement_nat + β Pers + ifs 1 s 2 i 3 i 4 i + β Firm + β Sec + ε (3) 5 f 6 s ifs lnw = α + β GVC + β Agreement_enter + β Agreement_nat + ifs 1 s 2 i 3 i + β Agreement_enter × GVC + β Agreement_nat × GVC + β Pers + 4 i s 5 i s 6 i + β Firm + β Sec + ε (4) 7 f 8 s ifs e m Th arginal ee ff ct of GVC on wages depends on the exact level of collec - tive bargaining: for enterprise agreement: δlnw/δGVC = β + β , whereas for 1 4 national agreement: δlnw/δGVC = β + β . Estimations are carried out using 1 5 the OLS method, applying the weights obtained from SES corresponding to grossing-up factor for employees and with robust standard errors clustered at the level of sectors. 2.3. Results Table 1 presents the results of Equation 1 (columns 1 and 2) and Equation 2 (col- umns 3 and 4). Based on the results presented in Table 1 the variable Agreement is positive and statistically signic fi ant for the first model (Equation 1). Therefore it indicates that on average workers with a collective pay agreement earn more compared to those who are not covered by any agreement. These results are in line with the view postulated that more organised industrial relations should bring better economic performance (for review, see Eurofound, 2015). However, 96 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 if the interactions between collective bargaining schemes and GVC involve- ment are added to the consideration (according to Equation 2), the story will change: interaction terms turn to be statistically insignic fi ant regardless the GVC measure used. To some extent these results are not surprising: as Rodrik and others (2004) argue if both the institutional environment and the trade- related variables are taken into account the conclusions may be diversie fi d and even the impact of trade may be negligible. Table 1. Estimation of wage regression, illustrating Equations 1 and 2 GVC measure FVA OFF FVA OFF (1) (2) (3) (4) GVC –0.003 0.015 –0.009 0.007 [0.020] [0.012] [0.018] [0.013] Agreement 0.037** 0.034** 0.016 0.011 [0.018] [0.016] [0.050] [0.027] GVCxAgreement 0.015 0.02 [0.027] [0.016] sex 0.172*** 0.168*** 0.172*** 0.168*** [0.029] [0.027] [0.029] [0.027] ageyoung –0.127*** –0.127*** –0.127*** –0.126*** [0.032] [0.032] [0.032] [0.032] ageaverage –0.012 –0.012 –0.011 –0.011 [0.020] [0.020] [0.020] [0.020] loweduc –0.316*** –0.318*** –0.315*** –0.318*** [0.032] [0.033] [0.032] [0.032] mededuc –0.277*** –0.280*** –0.276*** –0.279*** [0.034] [0.034] [0.033] [0.033] full time –0.026 –0.029 –0.026 –0.028 [0.022] [0.022] [0.022] [0.021] skill_1 –0.586*** –0.587*** –0.585*** –0.586*** [0.071] [0.070] [0.071] [0.070] However, one should also take into account the specic v fi alues of GVC e.g. based on the values of coeci ffi ents from column 3 of Table 1 the marginal ee ff ct of Agreement equals to 0.016 + 0.015 × FVA and 0.011 + 0.02 × OFF (column 4). For high values of FVA and OFF the final effect can be different from zero. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 97 skill_2 –0.461*** –0.465*** –0.461*** –0.464*** [0.050] [0.050] [0.050] [0.050] skill_3 –0.315*** –0.316*** –0.315*** –0.317*** [0.055] [0.055] [0.055] [0.055] shortdur –0.109*** –0.106*** –0.109*** –0.106*** [0.017] [0.016] [0.017] [0.016] meddur –0.092*** –0.091*** –0.092*** –0.090*** [0.016] [0.015] [0.015] [0.015] small –0.211*** –0.205*** –0.211*** –0.205*** [0.062] [0.061] [0.062] [0.061] medium –0.070* –0.068 –0.070* –0.068 [0.041] [0.040] [0.041] [0.041] public 0.099 0.110* 0.098 0.109* [0.063] [0.062] [0.063] [0.062] temp –0.154*** –0.155*** –0.154*** –0.155*** [0.026] [0.026] [0.026] [0.026] ln_prod 0.053*** 0.051*** 0.053*** 0.051*** [0.015] [0.016] [0.015] [0.016] R 0.51 0.51 0.51 0.51 N 723706 723706 723706 723706 Notes: sex (male = 1), full time (full-time employed = 1), public (public unit = 1), temp (temporary contract = 1), ln_prod (log of productivity: sector value added to the number of hours worked). Default/omitted categories: ageold, higheduc, skill_4, longdur and large. Regression with weights and robust standard errors clustered at the sector level (in parentheses); *p ≤ 0.10, **p ≤ 0.05, *** p ≤ 0.01. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. Additionally, it is conr fi med that personal and firm characteristics are impor - tant in the wage determination of individual workers. In particular, higher aver- age wages are recorded for men, older and better educated workers. Moreover, people performing high-skill occupations (managers and professionals) earn more compared to people in other occupations. Similarly, the seniority in indi- vidual companies is positively related to the wage: employees who work longer in a given company are usually characterised by a higher wage. Moving onto the characteristics of the company the results are in line with expectations: higher wages are observed in larger, public enterprises and for workers with inden fi ite contracts. Moreover, it is meaningful to consider an alternative cod - ing of the variables related to wage bargaining: when the collective pay agree- 98 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 ment scheme is divided into specic l fi evels (enterprise and national pay agree - ments) the obtained results prove to be interesting. Table 2 presents the results of Equation 3 (columns 1 and 2) and Equation 4 (columns 3 and 4). Table 2. Estimation of wage regression, illustrating Equations 3 and 4 GVC measure FVA OFF FVA OFF (1) (2) (3) (4) GVC –0.003 0.015 –0.01 0.006 [0.021] [0.012] [0.018] [0.013] Agreement_enter 0.034* 0.031* 0.003 0.002 [0.019] [0.017] [0.054] [0.029] Agreement_nat 0.058*** 0.058*** 0.126*** 0.085*** [0.019] [0.018] [0.032] [0.021] GVCxAgreement_enter 0.022 0.025 [0.029] [0.017] GVCxAgreement_nat –0.061*** –0.031** [0.022] [0.014] R 0.51 0.51 0.51 0.51 N 723706 723706 723706 723706 Notes: All RHS variables (personal, firm and sector characteristics) included as in Table 1. Default (missing) category: no agreement. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. In the case of Equation 3 the results show that agreements (of any kind) are associated with higher wages. Additionally, the ee ff ct of national agreements is both statistically more robust and larger in terms of its size ee ff ct than for en - terprise-level agreements. When the interactions are added the statistical sig- nic fi ance is sustained in the case of national agreements (positive coeci ffi ent in front of Agreement_nat) but the coeci ffi ent is negative in front of its inter - action with GVC (GVCxAgreement_nat). The figures (Figure 1 and Figure 2) showing the association between GVC and wages depending on the level of agreement are compiled to better illustrate the results. Following the relationships presented in Figures 1 and 2, in the case of en- terprise agreements the association between GVC and wages is positive. This may be interpreted that when the involvement in GVC increases the wages of individual workers also increase. Conversely, in the case of national agree- ments wages decrease with the increase in GVC involvement. Please note that only 3.7% of workers in the sample is characterised by a national wage agree- D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 99 Figure 1. Predicted wages due to the changes in GVC across different categories of collective pay agreements (illustrating the results from Table 2, column 3). GVC measured as FVA to export, FVA in range (0–40%), rescaled (0–4) Notes: predicted wage expressed as ln wages; FVA: the higher the index the greater involvement in GVC. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. Figure 2. Predicted wages due to the changes in GVC across different categories of collective pay agreements (illustrating the results from Table 2, column 4). GVC measured as OFF, OFF in range (0–40%), rescaled (0–4) Notes: predicted wage expressed as ln wages; OFF: the higher the index the greater involvement in GVC. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. ment. This trend is common for two distinct measures of GVC: FVA to export (Figure 1) and OFF (Figure 2). Taking into account the statistical signic fi ance of the estimations in this study (the cond fi ence intervals intersect) the result should be interpreted with caution. The positive ee ff ct of national agreements is reduced with the level of GVC participation. In fact, the ee ff ct is such that the positive wage ee ff ct from national agreements is eliminated for a certain range of GVC intensity. It is also important to differentiate the between statistical and economical significance of the results. Although the results for national agreements are statistically sig- nic fi ant (Table 2) their economic signic fi ance is marginal (Figures 1 and 2). 100 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 In the case of less centralised agreements (e.g. enterprise wage bargaining schemes) the workers have more power to negotiate their wages (Felbermayr, Hauptmann, & Schmerer, 2014). This is especially true for GVC-involved sectors where the integration with global links may enhance the firms’ productivity and competitiveness. The wages under less centralised bargaining may be more flex - ible and therefore related more strongly to productivity gains. At the same time for centralised bargaining schemes the workers have less bargaining power and the wages are more dependent on the macro situation of the whole economy. As Boeri, Brugiavini and Calmfors (2001) assert for decentralised bargaining schemes the linkages between productivity gains (here induced by GVC involve- ment) and wages are tighter. In this way enterprise-based wage negotiations may overcome the negative impact from greater GVC participation. However, given the fact that the information about GVC involvement is only available on the sectoral level a further discussion of this relationship remains open. One should also take into consideration the fact that when looking at Figures 1 and 2 there are no statistically signic fi ant die ff rences between a na - tional agreement and no agreement however, in Table 2 (column 3 and 4), na- tional agreements and interaction between GVC and national agreement are statistically significant. Moreover, despite the lack of statistical significance of some results the diverse trends within enterprise agreement/no agreement and GVC, and national agreement/no agreement and GVC are meaningful and worth future closer investigation. 3. Extension e a Th bove analysis is based on two die ff rent measures of GVC, however, both of them are calculated on the basis of trade statistics: trade in intermediate goods and input-output tables (Timmer et al., 2015). In the next step sector specic e fi xport to value added (Export) instead of GVC is employed in order to check whether the above analysis gauges the ee ff ct of GVC involvement rather than simply the ee ff ct of openness of a given sector. e Th results are presented in Table 3. Based on the results presented in Table 3 and Figure 3 the follow- ing can be concluded for an enterprise agreement: firstly, the predicted wages are rather stable with the increase in export penetration secondly, there is no distinct difference in wages of the workers covered by an enterprise agree - ment and those without any agreement. e Th trend in wages of workers with a national agreement (right hand graph) is similar to the trends shown by the GVC measures, However, the wide statistical cond fi ence intervals causes the die ff rences between national agreement and no agreement to be less obvious. In this way the results indicate that the specic t fi rends for wage determination and specic fi levels of collective pay agreements are indeed characterised for Global Value Chains (not for general trade). D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 101 Table 3. Estimation of wage regression, with variable Export GVC measure FVA OFF FVA OFF (1) (2) (3) (4) Export –0.001 0.002 –0.001 0.001 [0.011] [0.009] [0.011] [0.009] Agreement 0.036** 0.045 [0.017] [0.035] Agreement_enter 0.034* 0.039 [0.018] [0.038] Agreement_nat 0.058*** 0.099*** [0.019] [0.024] ExportxAgreement –0.006 [0.013] ExportxAgreement_enter –0.003 [0.014] ExportxAgreement_nat –0.037*** [0.013] R 0.51 0.51 0.51 0.51 N 723706 723706 723706 723706 Notes: All RHS variables (personal, firm and sector characteristics) included as in Table 1. Default (missing): no agreement. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. Figure 3. Predicted wages due to the changes in Export across different categories of collective pay agreements (illustrating the results from Table 3, column 4) Notes: Predicted wage expressed as ln wages. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. 102 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 Finally, the estimations with more disaggregated classic fi ation of workers’ oc - cupation are conducted. Instead of four different skill levels, nine different occupa - tions (ISCO 1 digit level) are introduced. In this way it is possible to better account for the occupational variation. The results are presented in Table 4 and Figure 4. Table 4. Estimation of wage regression, with detailed occupation classification GVC measure FVA OFF FVA OFF (1) (2) (3) (4) GVC –0.029 0.001 –0.037* –0.01 [0.024] [0.012] [0.022] [0.014] Agreement_enter 0.032* 0.028* –0.005 –0.005 [0.018] [0.017] [0.051] [0.028] Agreement_nat 0.065*** 0.065*** 0.139*** 0.094*** [0.019] [0.019] [0.038] [0.023] GVCxAgreement_enter 0.026 0.029* [0.027] [0.017] GVCxAgreement_nat –0.066** –0.033** [0.025] [0.015] R 0.52 0.52 0.52 N 723706 723706 723706 723706 Notes: All RHS variables (personal, firm and sector characteristics) included as in Table 1. Instead of skill levels, there are 9 die ff rent occupations. Default (missing): no agreement. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. Figure 4. Predicted wages due to the changes in GVC across different categories of collective pay agreements (illustrating the results from Table 4, column 3) Notes: Predicted wage expressed as ln wages. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 103 Regardless of the level of occupational aggregation (four skill levels vs. nine occupation levels) the main conclusion considering the die ff rence between the association between GVC and wages depending on enterprise and national collective agreements is conr fi med. The overall association between collective pay agreements and wages is positive. However, the greater intensification of GVC links may contribute to weakness of the positive impact from national pay agreements. Conclusions e m Th ain objective of this paper was to examine the wage determination in Poland focusing on the role played by GVC involvement and wage bargaining schemes. As the existing evidence mainly considers the role of collective bar- gaining in wage determination in Western Europe where the industrial rela- tions are more developed this study is devoted to Poland a country in which industrial relations may be described as fragmented. In other words the aim of this paper was to investigate the linkages between institutions, wages and GVC in a post-communist economy which has a relatively short history of in- dustrial relations. e r Th esults show that controlling for a varied range of personal, company and sectoral characteristics the role played by the labour market institutions might be signic fi ant. In particular the existence of the collective bargaining schemes may have a positive impact on individual wage determination. On average workers who are covered by any type of collective pay agreement (ne- gotiated at company or national level) earn more compared to those who are not covered by collective bargaining. This is in line with the previous empirical evidence (European Commission, 2015; Schäfer & Gottschall, 2015). However, if the interactions between the level of wage bargaining and GVC involvement are considered the association turns to be less obvious. Although the predicted wages are growing along with the GVC intensic fi ation for workers covered by enterprise agreement, this ee ff ct is rather negligible in economic terms. More large and robust is the evidence for national level agreements: the initially posi- tive impact on wage growth is weakened by the growing involvement in GVC. However, it is claimed that workers whose pay is agreed during the negotia- tions at company level are less ae ff cted by the negative impact resulting from the greater links with global production fragmentation processes (due to greater negotiation power and closer links between the productivity gains and wages: Boeri et al., 2001; Felbermayr et al., 2014), was not conr fi med using Polish data. Among the limitations of this research it may be mentioned that the GVC involvement measures are available on the sectoral and not on the company level. Secondly, the focus was only on the impact of GVC and institutions on wages while other aspects of labour market performance may be also be af- 104 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 fected (Calmfors & Driffill, 1988). Thirdly, the GVC-wage nexus was observed only in the static framework while a dynamic analysis would allow for a deep- er explanation of these associations. However, with the given dataset, such an exercise was impossible to implement. Fourthly, only one measure of labour market institutions related to the wage bargaining level was included. Finally, not all results are statistically signic fi ant. As Kohl and Platzer (2007) argue various forms of government activities may be important in the determination of individual renumeration especially when taking into account the low bargaining coverage and weak unions. Therefore the wider institutional background might give more insight into the aspects of wage determination and provide a direction for further research in this context. Appendix Table A1. Collective bargaining coverage and GVC measures in Poland across different industries na­ Code of enter­ Name of industry noagr tio­ FVA OFF industry pagr nagr TOTAL 0.591 0.372 0.037 1.298 1.077 B Mining and quarrying 0.203 0.762 0.034 0.718 1.113 Manufacture of food products, bever- C10-C12 0.524 0.461 0.014 2.409 1.112 ages and tobacco products Manufacture of textiles, wearing ap- C13-C15 0.628 0.354 0.018 2.993 2.972 parel and leather products Manufacture of wood and of products of wood and cork. except furniture; C16_C17 0.568 0.414 0.018 1.919 1.812 manufacture of articles of str.; manu- facture of paper and paper products Printing and reproduction of recorded C18 0.679 0.303 0.018 1.828 1.818 media Manufacture of coke and refined petro - C19_C20_ leum products; manufacture of chemi- 0.47 0.494 0.036 2.531 3.409 C22 cals and chemical products; manufac- ture of rubber and plastic products Manufacture of basic pharmaceutical C21 products and pharmaceutical prepara- 0.333 0.617 0.049 2.100 1.405 tions Manufacture of other non-metallic C23 0.607 0.383 0.010 2.078 1.571 mineral products Manufacture of basic metals; manu- C24_C25 facture of fabricated metal products, 0.471 0.500 0.030 1.854 2.725 except machinery and equipment D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 105 Manufacture of computer. electronic C26_C27_ and optical products; manufacture of 0.454 0.530 0.017 3.294 3.601 C33 electrical equipment; repair and instal- lation of machinery and equipment Manufacture of machinery and equip- C28 0.389 0.583 0.028 2.511 2.726 ment n.e.c Manufacture of motor vehicles, trail- C29_C30 ers and semi-trailers; manufacture of 0.472 0.489 0.038 2.584 2.828 other transport equipment Manufacture of furniture; other manu- C31_C32 0.512 0.484 0.004 2.669 1.815 facturing Electricity, gas, steam and air condi- D35 0.072 0.831 0.097 1.512 1.740 tioning supply E36 Water collection, treatment and supply 0.256 0.739 0.005 0.700 0.561 Sewerage; waste collection, treatment E37-E39 and disposal activities; materials recov- 0.436 0.562 0.002 1.213 1.213 ery; remediation activities F Construction 0.503 0.473 0.025 2.048 1.168 Wholesale and retail trade and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles; G45_G46 0.709 0.278 0.014 0.822 0.564 wholesale trade. except of motor ve- hicles and motorcycles Retail trade. except of motor vehicles G47 0.695 0.243 0.062 0.772 0.473 and motorcycles Land transport and transport via pipe- H49_H50_ lines; water transport; air transport; 0.317 0.644 0.038 1.433 0.868 H51_H52 warehousing and support activities for transportation H53 Postal and courier activities 0.073 0.927 0.000 0.901 0.527 Accommodation and food service ac- I 0.675 0.226 0.099 1.188 0.558 tivities Publishing activities; motion picture, J58_J59_ video and television programme pro- 0.744 0.256 0.000 1.236 0.790 J60 duction, sound recording and music publishing activities Telecommunications; computer pro- J61_J62_ gramming, consultancy and related 0.605 0.31 0.084 1.419 1.290 J63 activities; information service activities Financial service activities. except in- surance and pension funding; insur- K64_K65_ ance, reinsurance and pension fund- 0.609 0.359 0.031 0.924 0.531 K66 ing except compulsory social security; activities auxiliary to financial services and insurance activities 106 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 L68 Real estate activities 0.448 0.484 0.068 0.925 0.324 Legal and accounting activities; activi- M69_M70 ties of head offices; management con - 0.772 0.228 0.00 0.633 0.505 sultancy activities Legal and accounting activities; activi- ties of head offices; management con - M69_ sultancy activities; architectural and 0.662 0.300 0.038 0.840 0.561 M70_M71 engineering activities; technical testing and analysis Scientific research and development; M72_M73_ advertising and market research; other 0.516 0.474 0.010 0.828 0.662 M74_M75 professional, scientific and technical activities; veterinary activities Other professional, scientific and tech - M74_M75 0.592 0.308 0.100 0.655 0.568 nical activities; veterinary activities Administrative and support service N 0.672 0.269 0.059 1.120 0.773 activities Public administration and defense; O84 0.965 0.033 0.002 0.524 0.280 compulsory social security P85 Education 0.745 0.184 0.071 0.485 0.232 Human health and social work activi- Q 0.567 0.403 0.030 0.861 0.621 ties R_S Other service activities 0.682 0.274 0.044 1.070 0.701 Notes: Industry-level GVC indicators calculated from WIOD are matched with SES data using classic fi ation NACE Rev. 2. In some cases, however, the sectors provided in SES cover broader categories. In order to assure the correspondence between SES and WIOD we calculated an average of industry indexes (e.g. FVA) for the non-standard industry classic fi ations e.g. C16_ C17, C26_C27_C33, J61_J62_J63. Source: SES and WIOD. Table A2. Descriptive statistics Obser­ Standard Variable Mean Min Max vations deviation wage 723706 24.422 15.815 9.13 95.11 sex 723706 0.497 0.500 0 1 ageyoung 723706 0.16 0.367 0 1 ageaverage 723706 0.554 0.497 0 1 loweduc 723706 0.055 0.228 0 1 mededuc 723706 0.528 0.499 0 1 FT 723706 0.923 0.266 0 1 skill 1 723706 0.078 0.268 0 1 D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 107 skill 2 723706 0.434 0.496 0 1 skill 3 723706 0.121 0.326 0 1 shortdur 723706 0.097 0.296 0 1 meddur 723706 0.268 0.443 0 1 small 723706 0.234 0.423 0 1 medium 723706 0.285 0.452 0 1 nationagr 723706 0.037 0.189 0 1 industagr 723706 0.000 0.000 0 0 enterpagr 723706 0.372 0.483 0 1 ln Prod 723706 3.135 0.874 1.242 5.133 FVA 723706 1.298 0.795 0.485 3.294 OFF 723706 1.077 0.960 0.232 3.601 Source: SES and WIOD. References Acemoglu, D., & Autor, D. (2011). Skills, tasks and technologies: Implications for em- ployment and earnings. In D. Card & O. Ashenfelter (Eds.), Handbook of labor eco- nomics (vol. 4, part B, pp. 1043–1171). Elsevier. Acemoglu, D., & Restrepo, P. (2018). The race between man and machine: Implications of technology for growth, factor shares, and employment. American Economic Review, 108(6), 1488–1542. Aringa, C. D., & Pagani, L. (2007). Collective bargaining and wage dispersion. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 45(1), 29–54. Autor, D. H., Dorn, D., & Hanson, G. H. (2016). The China shock: Learning from labor- market adjustment to large changes in trade. Annual Reviews, 8, 205–240. https:// doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-080315-015041 Avouyi-Dovi, S., Fougére, D., & Gautier, E. (2013). Wage rigidity, collective bargaining, and the minimum wage: Evidence from French agreement data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(4), 1337–1351. https://doi.org/10.1162/REST_a_00329 Basu, S., Estrin, S., & Svejnar, J. (2004). Wage determination under communism and in transition: Evidence from Central Europe. (IZA Discussion Papers No. 1276, pp. 1–20). Retrieved from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=586065 Baumgarten, D., Geishecker, I., & Görg, H. (2013). Os ff horing, tasks, and the skill-wage pattern. European Economic Review, 61, 132–152. Bernaciak, M. (2015). All roads lead to decentralization? Collective bargaining trends and prospects in Central and Eastern Europe. Transfer: European Review of Labour and Research, 21(3), 373–381. https://doi.org/10.1177/1024258915585947 Boeri, T. (2014). Two-tier bargaining. (IZA Discussion Paper No. 8358). Bonn. 108 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 Boeri, T., Brugiavini, A., & Calmfors, L. (Eds.). (2001). The role of unions in the twenty-first century: A report for the Fondazione Rodolfo Debenedetti . Oxford: Oxford University Press. Retrieved from https://econpapers.repec.org/ RePEc:oxp:obooks:9780199246588 Brandl, B., Bechter, B., Czarzasty, J., Lehr, A., Molina, O., Nordin, P, ..., Toa, A. (2021). European, national and transnational industrial relations: Visible and invisible hands in European and national wage setting. Durham. Calmfors, L., & Driffill, J. (1988). Bargaining structure, corporatism and macroeco - nomic performance. Economic Policy, 3(6), 13–61. https://doi.org/10.2307/1344503 Card, D., & Cardoso, A. R. (2021). Wage flexibility under sectoral bargaining . (NBER Working Paper Series No. 28695). Cardoso, M., Neves, P. C., Afonso, O., & Sochirca, E. (2021). The ee ff cts of os ff horing on wages: A meta-analysis. Review of World Economics, 157, 149‒179. https://doi. org/10.1007/s10290-020-00385-z Ebenstein, A., Harrison A., McMillan, M., & Phillips, S. (2014). Estimating the impact of trade and os ff horing on American workers using the current population sur - veys. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(4), 581–595. https://doi.org/10.1162/ REST_a_00400 Eurofound. (2015). Collective bargaining in Europe in the 21st century. Luxembourg. European Commission. (2015). Developments in European industrial relations. In Industrial Relations in Europe 2014 (pp. 41–66). Luxembourg: Publications Oc ffi e of the European Union. Eurostat. (2014). Structure of Earnings Survey 2014 Eurostat ’s arrangements for imple- menting the Council Regulation 530/1999, the Commission Regulations 1916/2000 and 1738/2005. Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1999). e i Th mpact of outsourcing and high-technol - ogy capital on wages: Estimates for the United States, 1979‒1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 907–940. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355399556179 Felbermayr, G., Hauptmann, A., & Schmerer, H. J. (2014). International trade and col- lective bargaining outcomes: Evidence from German employer–employee data. e Th Scandinavian Journal of Economics , 116(3), 820–837. https://doi.org/10.1111/ SJOE.12067 Geishecker, I., Görg, H., & Munch, J. R. (2010). Do labour market institutions matter? Micro-level wage ee ff cts of international outsourcing in three European countries. Review of World Economics, 146(1), 179–198. Gere, ffi G., & Fernandez-Stark, K. (2016). Global Value Chain analysis: A primer. Duke CGGC (Center on Globalization, Governance & Competitiveness). Gerlach, K., & Stephan, G. (2006). Pay policies of firms and collective wage contracts— An uneasy partnership?. Industrial Relations, 45(1), 47–67. https://doi.org/10.1111/ j.1468-232X.2006.00413.x Goos, M., Manning, A., & Salomons, A. (2014). Explaining job polarization: Routine- biased technological change and os ff horing. American Economic Review, 104(8), 2509–2526. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.8.2509 Grossman, G. M., & Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2008). Trading tasks: A simple theory of off - shoring. American Economic Review, 98(5), 1978–1997. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 109 Gruetzemacher, R. , Dorner, F. E., Bernaola-Alvarez, N., Giattino, C., & Manheim, D. (2021). Forecasting AI progress: A research agenda. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 170, 120909. Guschanski, A., & Onaran, Ö. (2021). The decline in the wage share: falling bargaining power of labour or technological progress? Industry-level evidence from the OECD. Socio-Economic Review, 20(3), 1091–1124. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwaa031 Heckman, J. J., Lochner, L. J., Todd, P. E. (2006). Earnings functions, rates of return and treatment ee ff cts: The Mincer equation and beyond. In E. A. Hanushek & F. Welch (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of education (pp. 307–458). Elsevier. Hummels, B. D., Jørgensen, R., Munch, J., & Xiang, C. (2014). The wage ee ff cts of off - shoring: Evidence from Danish matched worker-firm data. American Economic Review, 104(6), 1597–1629. Kohl, H., & Platzer, H. (2007). The role of the state in Central and Eastern European industrial relations: The case of minimum wages. Industrial Relations Journal, 38(6), 614–635. Las Heras, J. (2018). International political economy of labour and collective bargain- ing in the automotive industry. Competition & Change, 22(3), 313–331. https://doi. org/10.1177/1024529418764350 Luo, S., & Yang, T. (2020). Why worker-supported collective bargaining may still fail: Union strategies and supply chain structure in South China. Employee Relations: e Th International Journal , 42(2), 471–491. https://doi.org/10.1108/ER-06-2019-0250 Milberg, W., & Houston, E. (2005). The high road and the low road to international competitiveness: Extending the neo-Schumpeterian trade model beyond tech- nology. International Review of Applied Economics, 19(2), 137–162. https://doi. org/10.1080/02692170500031646 Milberg, W., & Winkler, D. (2013). Outsourcing economics: Global value chains in capi- talist development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Müller, T., Vandaele, K., & Waddington, J. (2019a). Collective bargaining in Europe: Towards an endgame (vol. 1). Brussels: European Trade Union Institute. Müller, T., Vandaele, K., & Waddington, J. (2019b). Collective bargaining in Europe: Towards an endgame (vol. 2). Brussels: European Trade Union Institute. Müller, T., Vandaele, K., & Waddington, J. (2019c). Collective bargaining in Europe: Towards an endgame (vol. 4, Source materials). Brussels: European Trade Union Institute. Ndubuisi, G., & Owusu, S. (2022). Wage ee ff cts of global value chains participation and position: An industry-level analysis. e Th Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 1086‒1107. https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2022.2058068 Nickell, S., & Layard, R. (1999). Labor market institutions and economic performance. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (vol. 3, pp. 3029– 3084). Elsevier. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4463(99)30037-7 Nunziata, L. (2005). Institutions and wage determination: A multi-country approach. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 67(4), 435–466. https://doi.org/10.1111/ j.1468-0084.2005.00127.x Parteka, A., & Wolszczak-Derlacz, J. (2019). Global value chains and wages: International evidence from linked worker-industry data. Open Economies Review, 30(3), 505–539. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-018-9518-8 110 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 Parteka, A., & Wolszczak-Derlacz, J. (2020, April). Wage response to global production links: Evidence for workers from 28 European countries (2005–2014). Review of World Economics, 156, 769‒801. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-020-00380-4 Quast, B., & Kummritz, V. (2015). decompr: Global Value Chain decomposition in R. The Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies. Ramirez, P., & Rainbird, H. (2010). Making the connections: bringing skill formation into global value chain analysis. Work, Employment and Society, 24(4), 699–710. https://doi.org/10.1177/0950017010380641 Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institu - tions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2), 131–165. https://doi.org/10.1023/B:JOEG.0000031425.72248.85 Schäfer, A., & Gottschall, K. (2015). From wage regulation to wage gap: How wage-setting institutions and structures shape the gender wage gap across three industries in 24 European countries and Germany. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 39(2), 467‒496. Schulten, T. (2016). e m Th eaning of extension for the stability of collective bargaining in Europe. (ETUI Research Paper—Policy Brief 3/2016). Selwyn, B. (2013). Social upgrading and labour in global production networks: A cri- tique and an alternative conception. Competition and Change, 17(1), 75–90. https:// doi.org/10.1179/1024529412Z.00000000026 Stockhammer, E., & Onaran, Ö. (2009). National and sectoral inu fl ences on wage deter - mination in Central and Eastern Europe. European Journal of Industrial Relations, 15(3), 317–338. https://doi.org/10.1177/0959680109339417 Szymczak, S., Parteka, A., Wolszczak-Derlacz, J. (2022). Position in global value chains: e i Th mpact on wages in Central and Eastern European Countries. European Journal of Industrial Relations, 28(2), 211–230. Szymczak, S., & Wolszczak-Derlacz, J. (2022). Global value chains and labour mar- kets—simultaneous analysis of wages and employment. Economic Systems Research, 34(1), 69‒96. Timmer, M. P., Dietzenbacher, E., Los, B., Stehrer, R., & de Vries, G. J. (2015). An illus- trated user guide to the World Input–Output Database: The case of global automo - tive production. Review of International Economics, 23, 575–605. Wang, Z., Wei, S. J., & Zhu, K. (2013). Quantifying international production sharing at the bilateral and sector levels. Revised version 2018. (NBER Working Papers No. 19677). https://doi.org/10.3386/w19677 http://www.deepdyve.com/assets/images/DeepDyve-Logo-lg.png Economics and Business Review de Gruyter

Wage determination, Global Value Chains and role played by wage bargaining schemes: The case of Poland

Loading next page...
 
/lp/de-gruyter/wage-determination-global-value-chains-and-role-played-by-wage-t9SzEkRXlf

References

References for this paper are not available at this time. We will be adding them shortly, thank you for your patience.

Publisher
de Gruyter
Copyright
© 2022 Dagmara Nikulin et al., published by Sciendo
eISSN
2450-0097
DOI
10.18559/ebr.2022.4.5
Publisher site
See Article on Publisher Site

Abstract

Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022: 88-110 DOI: 10.18559/ebr.2022.4.5 Wage determination, Global Value Chains and role played by wage bargaining schemes: The case of Poland 2 3 Dagmara Nikulin , Joanna Wolszczak-Derlacz Abstract: This study examines the linkages between GVC involvement and wages in Poland given die ff rent wage bargaining schemes. The analysis is based on microdata from the European Structure of Earnings Survey for Poland combined with sectoral data from the World Input-Output Database. In particular, two measures of GVC involve- ment were used: the share of foreign value added (FVA) to export and the measure of traditional os ff horing. e Th institutional settings are represented by the wage bargaining scheme which ree fl cts the level at which the collective pay is agreed. The results show that despite the lack of a signic fi ant relationship between the sectoral involvement in GVC and the level of wages in Poland, on average workers covered by the collective pay agreement receive higher wages. Moreover, the wage-GVC nexus is conditioned on the type of pay agreements: the positive wage ee ff ct from national agreements is eliminated for a certain range of GVC intensity. Keywords: wages, Global Value Chains, wage bargaining. JEL codes: F16, F66, J81. Introduction Wage determination is a popular topic that has been tackled by many scientists over the years. Moreover, for post-communist countries the aspect of deter- minants of individual workers’ wages is even more interesting since the wage behaviour of firms changed considerably during the transition to a  market economy (evidence for the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland and Hungary is described in Basu, Estrin, & Svejnar, 2004). The changes which took place ae ft r Article received 1 December 2021, accepted 5 October 2022. This paper is carried out within the project financed by the National Science Centre, Poland (grant number: 2015/19/B/ HS4/02884). Gdańsk University of Technology, Faculty of Management and Economics, Naruto wi- cza 11/12, 80-233 Gdańsk, Poland, corresponding author: dnikulin@zie.pg.gda.pl, https://orcid. org/0000-0002-0534-4553. Gdańsk University of Technology, Faculty of Management and Economics, Naruto wi- cza 11/12, 80-233 Gdańsk, Poland, jwo@zie.pg.gda.pl, https://orcid.org/0000-0002-3392-5267. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 89 the breakdown of communism contributed significantly to the new shape of the industrial relations. The large-scale privatisation, inflows of foreign direct investments as well as the accession to the EU which forced the modernisation of the labour law started to create new patterns of relations between labour market actors (Stockhammer & Onaran, 2009). The experience of the global financial crisis and related rapid decline in exports resulting from decreasing foreign demand accelerated the conclusion of labour agreements in order to help companies survive during the crisis and retain employees in Central and Eastern European countries (CEECs) (Bernaciak, 2015). Nowadays the literature indicates two new important trends describing the determinants that create current labour market outcomes: involvement in the global production sharing processes on the one hand and the role played by the labour market institutions on the another. Referring to the r fi st trend the pro - cess of global production sharing was developed through the concept of Global Value Chain (GVC) which is understood as “the full range of activities that r fi ms and workers perform to bring a product from its conception to end use and beyond” (Gereffi & Fernandez-Stark, 2016, p. 7). Despite the fact that the ef - fects of GVC on labour markets (wages, inequalities, job losses, labour produc- tivity) are widely examined in the literature (Baumgarten, Geishecker, & Görg, 2013; Geishecker, Görg & Munch, 2010; Parteka & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2019), the institutional factors are described less frequently. e Th majority of existing research focuses on the ee ff ct of globalised production on wages. Early studies on the impact of os ff horing (as international trade involvement measure) on wages (Baumgarten et al., 2013; Ebenstein, Harrison, McMillan, & Phillips, 2014; Hummels, Jørgensen, Munch, & Xiang, 2014) as well as further studies based on the concept of GVC (Autor, Dorn & Hanson, 2016; Parteka & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2020; Szymczak & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2022) reveal divergent results (for meta- analysis see Cardoso, Neves, Afono, & Sochirca, 2021). In general for developed countries a slightly negative impact of GVC participation is conr fi med as far as backward linkages are considered, whilst in the case of forward linkages the as- sociation may be ambiguous (Szymczak & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2022). Importantly, a relevant research question concerns the role played by the technological progress and the related process automatization which is widely described in the literature (among others Acemoglu & Autor, 2011; Acemoglu & Restrepo, 2018; Goos, Manning & Salomons, 2014). Moreover, recently increasing attention is being paid to the role of new technology on the labour market (Gruetzemacher, Dorner, Bernaola-Alvarez, Giattino, & Manheim, 2021). However, as the main focus of this study is the labour market institutions and GVC additional covariates are not included. The authors are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing this out. For detailed presentation of the concept and governance of GVC see the book by Milberg and Winkler (2013). e a Th mbiguous results may be explained by three die ff rent forces: productivity, relative price and labour-supply ee ff cts which may ae ff ct the labour market outcomes (Grossman & Rossi-Hansberg, 2008). 90 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 On the other hand labour market institutions are claimed to be a key factor in creating the wage-setting mechanisms (Gerlach & Stephan, 2006; Aringa & Pagani, 2007; Avouyi-Dovi, Fougére & Gautier, 2013; Eurofound, 2015; and oth- ers). According to the publication Collective bargaining in Europe: Towards an endgame issued by the European Trade Union Institute (ETUI) which is deeply involved in the concept of collective bargaining the wages of about two-thirds of European workers are negotiated in a collective way (Müller, Vandaele, & Waddington, 2019a). However, having in mind that the story related to the industrialisation process differs fundamentally in Central and Eastern coun - tries when compared to Western ones (Bernaciak, 2015), there are signic fi ant die ff rences in the collective bargaining coverage across countries—from 12% in Bulgaria, 14% in Latvia, to 46% in the Czech Republic (Müller, Vandaele, & Waddington, 2019c). Regarding Poland, the collective bargaining coverage rate has declined in recent decades from 25% in 2000 to about 18% in 2017. Similarly, Poland’s unionisation rate is one of the lowest in the European Union and accounts for 12% (Müller, Vandaele, & Waddington, 2019b). In this study the two above-mentioned literature trends are analysed to- gether namely: GVC and wage bargaining schemes and their association with wages. Past evidence shows that only a few studies describe the relationships between wage determinations, GVC and labour market institutions (Las Heras, 2018; Guschanski & Onaran, 2021; Luo & Yang, 2020). The recent study from Ndubuisi & Owusu (2022) who use sectoral data reveals that in strictly regu- lated labour markets the impact of GVC on wages may be positive. As regards post-communist countries there are hardly any studies in this area. Against this background the trade-related shocks may be moderated by the institution- al environment (Rodrik, Subramanian, & Trebbi, 2004). Going further if the institutional environment is taken into account the impact of trade on wages may be negligible (Rodrik et al., 2004). e Th refore the simultaneous analysis of the association between wages, trade and institutional background is of great importance. The main goal of this paper is to investigate the wage determination in Poland and to examine the role of wage bargaining level and the involvement in global production fragmentation processes. The contribution is based on providing simultaneously an analysis of wages, GVC and labour market insti- tutions where both wages as well as wage bargaining schemes are considered on an individual level. The study is based on a Polish case, where Poland is characterised by rather weak collective bargaining schemes: the trade unions Stockhammer and Onaran (2009) examined the association between wage determina- tion and wage bargaining schemes controlling for the trade openness and foreign direct invest- ment stocks. Parteka and Wolszczak-Derlacz (2020) added labour market institution variables on country level in their cross-country analysis. Among existing studies Guschanski and Onaran (2021) examined the nexus among wages, wage bargaining and os ff horing on the basis of sectoral data. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 91 are fragmented, sectoral agreements are scarce and the bargaining is largely decentralised (Bernaciak, 2015). We argue that an analysis of the relationship between wages and involvement in international trade in a  country differ - ent from Western countries (which have a much longer tradition of collec- tive labour agreements) is interesting. In order to fulfil the aim of this study an econometric analysis based on the augmented Mincerian wage regression is employed. i Th s paper consists of five sections. Section 1 is a review of the literature re - garding wage determination, GVC and labour market institutions. Section 2 is empirical and presents data, the model and results. Section 3 adds extensions to the baseline model. Last section contains conclusions. 1. Literature review The association between trade, institutions and wage determination is not straightforward. Starting with the considerations of Milberg and Houston (2005) on the linkages between bargaining and international competitiveness the stronger institutional arrangements may be associated with better inter- national economic performance. That is to say that the authors claim a hump- shaped relationship (following the findings from Calmfors and Driffill (1988) between the wage bargaining coverage and international competitiveness. On the other hand international trade involvement and the related increased competition may cause a downward pressure on wages while strong unions may mitigate this ee ff ct. As Schulten (2016) argues the high rate of bargaining coverage may ensure sustainable and inclusive growth. However, it has to be taken into account that GVC involvement may be associated with decreased market power and therefore the extent to which the wages may be negotiat- ed through collective bargaining is limited (Nickell & Layard, 1999). Ramirez and Rainbird (2010) discuss a relationship between GVC and institutions one element of which is the above-mentioned pressure caused by international competition. They note that the institutions have an impact on the process of skill formation among firms participating in GVC and the skill structure de - termines the wage structure. Importantly, the impact of bargaining power on wages may be dependent on the level at which the bargaining is coordinated (Nunziata, 2005). In turn the existing evidence for developing countries shows that through introducing collective pay bargaining it is possible to achieve an improvement of working conditions (e.g. a rise in pay levels) and therefore a minimalization of the negative implications of GVC participation (Selwyn, 2013). Moreover, as Selwyn (2013) argues since greater involvement in GVC may be associated with a downgrade of working conditions it may be mitigated by the proper in- stitutional interventions such as collective bargaining. In the case of Europe the 92 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 situation regarding the collective bargaining structures is varied. In European countries collective pay agreements are predominantly set as wage floors for die ff rent occupation groups (Card & Cardoso, 2021). Moreover, in several European countries (Portugal, Spain, Italy, Belgium, the Netherlands, France) the system of wage bargaining is based on sectoral schemes in which the wage o fl or is established. This results in considerable flexibility and latitude in wage determination even in the same sector. Going further a shift towards decen - tralisation is visible in the form of the two-tier structure of collective bargain- ing. The two-tier structure is based on the assumption that the negations which take place at the plant level have a complementary role in relation to the mul- ti-employer wage agreements which take place at the national, industry or re- gional level (Boeri, 2014). As the post-communist countries have a die ff rent institutional background from the Western countries the economic ee ff cts of the collective bargaining may also be die ff rent for the Central and Eastern economies (Stockhammer & Onaran, 2009). Following the hypothesis proposed by Calmfors and Driffill (1988) the best labour market outcomes are obtained for industrial relations which are highly organised or highly disorganised while the worst outcomes are recorded for the intermediate level of industrial organisation. As Kohl and Platzer (2007) argue in the case of Central and Eastern European countries it is possible to identify the transitional model of industrial relations according to which in the private sector and multinational companies “union-free” zones may be distinguished. This results in low bargaining coverage. Consequently the existing evidence assessing the linkages between wage determination, labour market institutions and trade involvement is mainly focused on the Western European countries. Summing up the existing evidence on the wage bargaining schemes nexus from European countries gives contrasting results: on the one hand see the re- search of Schäfer and Gottschall (2015) who find a positive relationship be - tween the wage bargaining centralisation degree and the wage level and on the other hand—the review by the European Commission (2015) which argues that for decentralised bargaining schemes the wages are higher. What is more once the impact of international production fragmentation is covered the existing evidence is much more scarce (Guschanski & Onaran, 2021). Based on the literature review the following research questions are formu- lated: 1. What is the association between wage bargaining scheme and wages? 2. Is the relationship between GVC and wages dependent on the type of col- lective pay agreement? An up-do-date compilation of industrial relations and wages across Europe is presented in Brandl and others (2021). D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 93 2. Empirical analysis 2.1. Data In order to answer the research question formulated above micro-level data for the Polish economy is used. The core database is derived from Eurostat (the European Structure of Earnings Survey: SES) for the year 2014 and contains information about over 700,000 Polish representative workers. The access to this micro-level data was granted based on an individual research proposal. The SES is a cyclical survey conducted in EU Member States as well as EU candidate countries and European Free Trade Association (EFTA) countries. The cross- sectional data covers information on the level of pay and individual character- istics of employees (sex, age, occupation, length of service, highest educational level attained, etc.) and their employers (economic activity, size and location of the enterprise). The descriptive statistics of the variables used are presented in Table A2 in the Appendix. The micro-level data are merged with the sec - toral data derived from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD) (Timmer, Dietzenbacher, Los, Stehrer, & de Vries, 2015) based on which die ff rent meas - ures of GVC involvement are calculated. Table A1 in the Appendix provides information on the distribution of the collective bargaining coverage in Poland across die ff rent industries. Detailed description of the variables is presented in the next section of this paper. 2.2. Model e m Th ain aim of this study is to check whether wages of individual workers are associated with GVC involvement and collective agreements. In order to verify these propositions the following form of augmented Mincerian wage regres- sion (reviewed in Heckman, Lochner, & Todd, 2006) is proposed: lnw = α + β GVC + β Agreement + β Pers + β Firm + β Sec + ε (1) ifs 1 s 2 i 3 i 4 f 5 s ifs where: i – worker; f – company, s – sector of employment. The log of worker’s wage (lnw) on set of personal variables (Pers) and firm’s characteristics ( Firm) was regressed. Personal variables include: sex (sex, male = 1); age of the work- ers (expressed via three binary variables: [ageyoung] which takes the value 1 A longer description of the SES database as well as the detailed description of the variables is available on the Eurostat web page https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/microdata/structure-of- earnings-survey. Specic fi ally the decomposition is done with the usage of R package decompr (Quast & Kummritz, 2015). See also: (Szymczak, Parteka, & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2022). e h Th ourly average wage was used. 94 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 for workers classie fi d as under 30 years old, [ ageaverage] with the value 1 for workers between 30–49 years old and [ageold] indicating workers over 50 years old); educational level (grouped into 3 categories: low education which includes less than primary, primary and lower secondary levels [loweduc = 1], medium education covering upper secondary and post-secondary levels [mededuc = 1] and higher education which denotes tertiary education up to and above 4 years [higheduc = 1]); skills levels (four skill categories based on occupation classification: skill_1 [elementary occupations], skill_2 [clerical support work- ers, service and sales workers, skilled agricultural, forestry and fishery workers, craft and related trades workers, plant and machine operators, and assemblers], skill_3 [technicians and associate professionals], skill_4 [managers and profes- sionals]); and type of employment (full time versus part time [full time = 1]). Among the set of firm characteristics ( Firm), there is information about the duration of employee’s experience working within a given unit (split into bi- nary variables: less than 1 year [shordur = 1], between 1–4 years [meddur = 1] and more than 4 years [longdur = 1]), size of the company (described by the number of employees (binary variables: between 1–49 employees [small = 1], between 50-249 [medium = 1] and above 250 employees [large = 1]), informa- tion on the form of economic and financial control (classie fi d into public and private [public = 1]) and the type of the contract (permanent versus temporal [temp = 1]). Moreover, the information about sector productivity calculated as value added per number of hours worked (WIOD) was included. e Th re are two variables of major interest. Firstly, the type of a collective pay agreement (Agreement) which equals 1 if a worker is covered by a collective pay agreement regardless of its level and 0 otherwise. According to the data derived from the SES it is possible to distinguish four levels at which collective bargaining takes place: (1) the national level (Agreement_nat) if the negotia- tions take place at the national or interconfederal level, (2) the industry level if the negotiations are held for a given industry, economic sector or individual industries in individual regions, (3) the enterprise level (Agreement_enter) if the negotiations cover only the employees of the same employer and (4) no agreement (Eurostat, 2014). Secondly, the variables related to the measures of GVC involvement. For this study two measures were calculated: (1) the share of foreign value added (FVA) to export (as presented by Wang, Wei, & Zhu, 2013) which measures the backward linkages in the international production pro- cesses and (2) the measure of traditional os ff horing calculated as the share of intermediate inputs to the value added (as in Feenstra & Hanson, 1999). As the impact of traditional trade and GVC may be die ff rent depending on the type of product traded (final vs. intermediate) (Szymczak & Wolszczak-Derlacz, 2022) In the case of Poland this level of collective bargaining is not observed and not included in the empirical analysis. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 95 both of the measures in order to examine the possible die ff rence in the impact are employed. These variables are represented by the term GVC in the models. In the next step the baseline model (Equation 1) is augmented to include the interaction term between variables Agreement and GVC: lnw = α + β GVC + β Agreement + β Agreement × GVC + ifs 1 s 2 i 3 i s + β Pers + β Firm + β Sec + ε (2) 4 i 5 f 6 s ifs According to Equation (2), the association between GVC and wages varies with the type of collective pay agreement, e.g. for workers without pay agree- ment for whom Agreement = 0, the marginal ee ff ct of GVC on wages ( ceteris paribus) corresponds to β , while in the case of workers with pay agreement (Agreement = 1), the marginal ee ff ct equals β + β . 1 3 Finally, the analogous analysis is repeated but replacing the variable Agreement with binary variables describing the exact level of collective pay agreement: en- terprise agreement (Agreement_enter), national agreement (Agreement_nat) or no agreement (Agreement_no) which is the default/missing category. lnw = α + β GVC + β Agreement_enter + β Agreement_nat + β Pers + ifs 1 s 2 i 3 i 4 i + β Firm + β Sec + ε (3) 5 f 6 s ifs lnw = α + β GVC + β Agreement_enter + β Agreement_nat + ifs 1 s 2 i 3 i + β Agreement_enter × GVC + β Agreement_nat × GVC + β Pers + 4 i s 5 i s 6 i + β Firm + β Sec + ε (4) 7 f 8 s ifs e m Th arginal ee ff ct of GVC on wages depends on the exact level of collec - tive bargaining: for enterprise agreement: δlnw/δGVC = β + β , whereas for 1 4 national agreement: δlnw/δGVC = β + β . Estimations are carried out using 1 5 the OLS method, applying the weights obtained from SES corresponding to grossing-up factor for employees and with robust standard errors clustered at the level of sectors. 2.3. Results Table 1 presents the results of Equation 1 (columns 1 and 2) and Equation 2 (col- umns 3 and 4). Based on the results presented in Table 1 the variable Agreement is positive and statistically signic fi ant for the first model (Equation 1). Therefore it indicates that on average workers with a collective pay agreement earn more compared to those who are not covered by any agreement. These results are in line with the view postulated that more organised industrial relations should bring better economic performance (for review, see Eurofound, 2015). However, 96 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 if the interactions between collective bargaining schemes and GVC involve- ment are added to the consideration (according to Equation 2), the story will change: interaction terms turn to be statistically insignic fi ant regardless the GVC measure used. To some extent these results are not surprising: as Rodrik and others (2004) argue if both the institutional environment and the trade- related variables are taken into account the conclusions may be diversie fi d and even the impact of trade may be negligible. Table 1. Estimation of wage regression, illustrating Equations 1 and 2 GVC measure FVA OFF FVA OFF (1) (2) (3) (4) GVC –0.003 0.015 –0.009 0.007 [0.020] [0.012] [0.018] [0.013] Agreement 0.037** 0.034** 0.016 0.011 [0.018] [0.016] [0.050] [0.027] GVCxAgreement 0.015 0.02 [0.027] [0.016] sex 0.172*** 0.168*** 0.172*** 0.168*** [0.029] [0.027] [0.029] [0.027] ageyoung –0.127*** –0.127*** –0.127*** –0.126*** [0.032] [0.032] [0.032] [0.032] ageaverage –0.012 –0.012 –0.011 –0.011 [0.020] [0.020] [0.020] [0.020] loweduc –0.316*** –0.318*** –0.315*** –0.318*** [0.032] [0.033] [0.032] [0.032] mededuc –0.277*** –0.280*** –0.276*** –0.279*** [0.034] [0.034] [0.033] [0.033] full time –0.026 –0.029 –0.026 –0.028 [0.022] [0.022] [0.022] [0.021] skill_1 –0.586*** –0.587*** –0.585*** –0.586*** [0.071] [0.070] [0.071] [0.070] However, one should also take into account the specic v fi alues of GVC e.g. based on the values of coeci ffi ents from column 3 of Table 1 the marginal ee ff ct of Agreement equals to 0.016 + 0.015 × FVA and 0.011 + 0.02 × OFF (column 4). For high values of FVA and OFF the final effect can be different from zero. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 97 skill_2 –0.461*** –0.465*** –0.461*** –0.464*** [0.050] [0.050] [0.050] [0.050] skill_3 –0.315*** –0.316*** –0.315*** –0.317*** [0.055] [0.055] [0.055] [0.055] shortdur –0.109*** –0.106*** –0.109*** –0.106*** [0.017] [0.016] [0.017] [0.016] meddur –0.092*** –0.091*** –0.092*** –0.090*** [0.016] [0.015] [0.015] [0.015] small –0.211*** –0.205*** –0.211*** –0.205*** [0.062] [0.061] [0.062] [0.061] medium –0.070* –0.068 –0.070* –0.068 [0.041] [0.040] [0.041] [0.041] public 0.099 0.110* 0.098 0.109* [0.063] [0.062] [0.063] [0.062] temp –0.154*** –0.155*** –0.154*** –0.155*** [0.026] [0.026] [0.026] [0.026] ln_prod 0.053*** 0.051*** 0.053*** 0.051*** [0.015] [0.016] [0.015] [0.016] R 0.51 0.51 0.51 0.51 N 723706 723706 723706 723706 Notes: sex (male = 1), full time (full-time employed = 1), public (public unit = 1), temp (temporary contract = 1), ln_prod (log of productivity: sector value added to the number of hours worked). Default/omitted categories: ageold, higheduc, skill_4, longdur and large. Regression with weights and robust standard errors clustered at the sector level (in parentheses); *p ≤ 0.10, **p ≤ 0.05, *** p ≤ 0.01. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. Additionally, it is conr fi med that personal and firm characteristics are impor - tant in the wage determination of individual workers. In particular, higher aver- age wages are recorded for men, older and better educated workers. Moreover, people performing high-skill occupations (managers and professionals) earn more compared to people in other occupations. Similarly, the seniority in indi- vidual companies is positively related to the wage: employees who work longer in a given company are usually characterised by a higher wage. Moving onto the characteristics of the company the results are in line with expectations: higher wages are observed in larger, public enterprises and for workers with inden fi ite contracts. Moreover, it is meaningful to consider an alternative cod - ing of the variables related to wage bargaining: when the collective pay agree- 98 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 ment scheme is divided into specic l fi evels (enterprise and national pay agree - ments) the obtained results prove to be interesting. Table 2 presents the results of Equation 3 (columns 1 and 2) and Equation 4 (columns 3 and 4). Table 2. Estimation of wage regression, illustrating Equations 3 and 4 GVC measure FVA OFF FVA OFF (1) (2) (3) (4) GVC –0.003 0.015 –0.01 0.006 [0.021] [0.012] [0.018] [0.013] Agreement_enter 0.034* 0.031* 0.003 0.002 [0.019] [0.017] [0.054] [0.029] Agreement_nat 0.058*** 0.058*** 0.126*** 0.085*** [0.019] [0.018] [0.032] [0.021] GVCxAgreement_enter 0.022 0.025 [0.029] [0.017] GVCxAgreement_nat –0.061*** –0.031** [0.022] [0.014] R 0.51 0.51 0.51 0.51 N 723706 723706 723706 723706 Notes: All RHS variables (personal, firm and sector characteristics) included as in Table 1. Default (missing) category: no agreement. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. In the case of Equation 3 the results show that agreements (of any kind) are associated with higher wages. Additionally, the ee ff ct of national agreements is both statistically more robust and larger in terms of its size ee ff ct than for en - terprise-level agreements. When the interactions are added the statistical sig- nic fi ance is sustained in the case of national agreements (positive coeci ffi ent in front of Agreement_nat) but the coeci ffi ent is negative in front of its inter - action with GVC (GVCxAgreement_nat). The figures (Figure 1 and Figure 2) showing the association between GVC and wages depending on the level of agreement are compiled to better illustrate the results. Following the relationships presented in Figures 1 and 2, in the case of en- terprise agreements the association between GVC and wages is positive. This may be interpreted that when the involvement in GVC increases the wages of individual workers also increase. Conversely, in the case of national agree- ments wages decrease with the increase in GVC involvement. Please note that only 3.7% of workers in the sample is characterised by a national wage agree- D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 99 Figure 1. Predicted wages due to the changes in GVC across different categories of collective pay agreements (illustrating the results from Table 2, column 3). GVC measured as FVA to export, FVA in range (0–40%), rescaled (0–4) Notes: predicted wage expressed as ln wages; FVA: the higher the index the greater involvement in GVC. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. Figure 2. Predicted wages due to the changes in GVC across different categories of collective pay agreements (illustrating the results from Table 2, column 4). GVC measured as OFF, OFF in range (0–40%), rescaled (0–4) Notes: predicted wage expressed as ln wages; OFF: the higher the index the greater involvement in GVC. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. ment. This trend is common for two distinct measures of GVC: FVA to export (Figure 1) and OFF (Figure 2). Taking into account the statistical signic fi ance of the estimations in this study (the cond fi ence intervals intersect) the result should be interpreted with caution. The positive ee ff ct of national agreements is reduced with the level of GVC participation. In fact, the ee ff ct is such that the positive wage ee ff ct from national agreements is eliminated for a certain range of GVC intensity. It is also important to differentiate the between statistical and economical significance of the results. Although the results for national agreements are statistically sig- nic fi ant (Table 2) their economic signic fi ance is marginal (Figures 1 and 2). 100 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 In the case of less centralised agreements (e.g. enterprise wage bargaining schemes) the workers have more power to negotiate their wages (Felbermayr, Hauptmann, & Schmerer, 2014). This is especially true for GVC-involved sectors where the integration with global links may enhance the firms’ productivity and competitiveness. The wages under less centralised bargaining may be more flex - ible and therefore related more strongly to productivity gains. At the same time for centralised bargaining schemes the workers have less bargaining power and the wages are more dependent on the macro situation of the whole economy. As Boeri, Brugiavini and Calmfors (2001) assert for decentralised bargaining schemes the linkages between productivity gains (here induced by GVC involve- ment) and wages are tighter. In this way enterprise-based wage negotiations may overcome the negative impact from greater GVC participation. However, given the fact that the information about GVC involvement is only available on the sectoral level a further discussion of this relationship remains open. One should also take into consideration the fact that when looking at Figures 1 and 2 there are no statistically signic fi ant die ff rences between a na - tional agreement and no agreement however, in Table 2 (column 3 and 4), na- tional agreements and interaction between GVC and national agreement are statistically significant. Moreover, despite the lack of statistical significance of some results the diverse trends within enterprise agreement/no agreement and GVC, and national agreement/no agreement and GVC are meaningful and worth future closer investigation. 3. Extension e a Th bove analysis is based on two die ff rent measures of GVC, however, both of them are calculated on the basis of trade statistics: trade in intermediate goods and input-output tables (Timmer et al., 2015). In the next step sector specic e fi xport to value added (Export) instead of GVC is employed in order to check whether the above analysis gauges the ee ff ct of GVC involvement rather than simply the ee ff ct of openness of a given sector. e Th results are presented in Table 3. Based on the results presented in Table 3 and Figure 3 the follow- ing can be concluded for an enterprise agreement: firstly, the predicted wages are rather stable with the increase in export penetration secondly, there is no distinct difference in wages of the workers covered by an enterprise agree - ment and those without any agreement. e Th trend in wages of workers with a national agreement (right hand graph) is similar to the trends shown by the GVC measures, However, the wide statistical cond fi ence intervals causes the die ff rences between national agreement and no agreement to be less obvious. In this way the results indicate that the specic t fi rends for wage determination and specic fi levels of collective pay agreements are indeed characterised for Global Value Chains (not for general trade). D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 101 Table 3. Estimation of wage regression, with variable Export GVC measure FVA OFF FVA OFF (1) (2) (3) (4) Export –0.001 0.002 –0.001 0.001 [0.011] [0.009] [0.011] [0.009] Agreement 0.036** 0.045 [0.017] [0.035] Agreement_enter 0.034* 0.039 [0.018] [0.038] Agreement_nat 0.058*** 0.099*** [0.019] [0.024] ExportxAgreement –0.006 [0.013] ExportxAgreement_enter –0.003 [0.014] ExportxAgreement_nat –0.037*** [0.013] R 0.51 0.51 0.51 0.51 N 723706 723706 723706 723706 Notes: All RHS variables (personal, firm and sector characteristics) included as in Table 1. Default (missing): no agreement. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. Figure 3. Predicted wages due to the changes in Export across different categories of collective pay agreements (illustrating the results from Table 3, column 4) Notes: Predicted wage expressed as ln wages. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. 102 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 Finally, the estimations with more disaggregated classic fi ation of workers’ oc - cupation are conducted. Instead of four different skill levels, nine different occupa - tions (ISCO 1 digit level) are introduced. In this way it is possible to better account for the occupational variation. The results are presented in Table 4 and Figure 4. Table 4. Estimation of wage regression, with detailed occupation classification GVC measure FVA OFF FVA OFF (1) (2) (3) (4) GVC –0.029 0.001 –0.037* –0.01 [0.024] [0.012] [0.022] [0.014] Agreement_enter 0.032* 0.028* –0.005 –0.005 [0.018] [0.017] [0.051] [0.028] Agreement_nat 0.065*** 0.065*** 0.139*** 0.094*** [0.019] [0.019] [0.038] [0.023] GVCxAgreement_enter 0.026 0.029* [0.027] [0.017] GVCxAgreement_nat –0.066** –0.033** [0.025] [0.015] R 0.52 0.52 0.52 N 723706 723706 723706 723706 Notes: All RHS variables (personal, firm and sector characteristics) included as in Table 1. Instead of skill levels, there are 9 die ff rent occupations. Default (missing): no agreement. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. Figure 4. Predicted wages due to the changes in GVC across different categories of collective pay agreements (illustrating the results from Table 4, column 3) Notes: Predicted wage expressed as ln wages. Source: Based on data from the SES and WIOD. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 103 Regardless of the level of occupational aggregation (four skill levels vs. nine occupation levels) the main conclusion considering the die ff rence between the association between GVC and wages depending on enterprise and national collective agreements is conr fi med. The overall association between collective pay agreements and wages is positive. However, the greater intensification of GVC links may contribute to weakness of the positive impact from national pay agreements. Conclusions e m Th ain objective of this paper was to examine the wage determination in Poland focusing on the role played by GVC involvement and wage bargaining schemes. As the existing evidence mainly considers the role of collective bar- gaining in wage determination in Western Europe where the industrial rela- tions are more developed this study is devoted to Poland a country in which industrial relations may be described as fragmented. In other words the aim of this paper was to investigate the linkages between institutions, wages and GVC in a post-communist economy which has a relatively short history of in- dustrial relations. e r Th esults show that controlling for a varied range of personal, company and sectoral characteristics the role played by the labour market institutions might be signic fi ant. In particular the existence of the collective bargaining schemes may have a positive impact on individual wage determination. On average workers who are covered by any type of collective pay agreement (ne- gotiated at company or national level) earn more compared to those who are not covered by collective bargaining. This is in line with the previous empirical evidence (European Commission, 2015; Schäfer & Gottschall, 2015). However, if the interactions between the level of wage bargaining and GVC involvement are considered the association turns to be less obvious. Although the predicted wages are growing along with the GVC intensic fi ation for workers covered by enterprise agreement, this ee ff ct is rather negligible in economic terms. More large and robust is the evidence for national level agreements: the initially posi- tive impact on wage growth is weakened by the growing involvement in GVC. However, it is claimed that workers whose pay is agreed during the negotia- tions at company level are less ae ff cted by the negative impact resulting from the greater links with global production fragmentation processes (due to greater negotiation power and closer links between the productivity gains and wages: Boeri et al., 2001; Felbermayr et al., 2014), was not conr fi med using Polish data. Among the limitations of this research it may be mentioned that the GVC involvement measures are available on the sectoral and not on the company level. Secondly, the focus was only on the impact of GVC and institutions on wages while other aspects of labour market performance may be also be af- 104 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 fected (Calmfors & Driffill, 1988). Thirdly, the GVC-wage nexus was observed only in the static framework while a dynamic analysis would allow for a deep- er explanation of these associations. However, with the given dataset, such an exercise was impossible to implement. Fourthly, only one measure of labour market institutions related to the wage bargaining level was included. Finally, not all results are statistically signic fi ant. As Kohl and Platzer (2007) argue various forms of government activities may be important in the determination of individual renumeration especially when taking into account the low bargaining coverage and weak unions. Therefore the wider institutional background might give more insight into the aspects of wage determination and provide a direction for further research in this context. Appendix Table A1. Collective bargaining coverage and GVC measures in Poland across different industries na­ Code of enter­ Name of industry noagr tio­ FVA OFF industry pagr nagr TOTAL 0.591 0.372 0.037 1.298 1.077 B Mining and quarrying 0.203 0.762 0.034 0.718 1.113 Manufacture of food products, bever- C10-C12 0.524 0.461 0.014 2.409 1.112 ages and tobacco products Manufacture of textiles, wearing ap- C13-C15 0.628 0.354 0.018 2.993 2.972 parel and leather products Manufacture of wood and of products of wood and cork. except furniture; C16_C17 0.568 0.414 0.018 1.919 1.812 manufacture of articles of str.; manu- facture of paper and paper products Printing and reproduction of recorded C18 0.679 0.303 0.018 1.828 1.818 media Manufacture of coke and refined petro - C19_C20_ leum products; manufacture of chemi- 0.47 0.494 0.036 2.531 3.409 C22 cals and chemical products; manufac- ture of rubber and plastic products Manufacture of basic pharmaceutical C21 products and pharmaceutical prepara- 0.333 0.617 0.049 2.100 1.405 tions Manufacture of other non-metallic C23 0.607 0.383 0.010 2.078 1.571 mineral products Manufacture of basic metals; manu- C24_C25 facture of fabricated metal products, 0.471 0.500 0.030 1.854 2.725 except machinery and equipment D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 105 Manufacture of computer. electronic C26_C27_ and optical products; manufacture of 0.454 0.530 0.017 3.294 3.601 C33 electrical equipment; repair and instal- lation of machinery and equipment Manufacture of machinery and equip- C28 0.389 0.583 0.028 2.511 2.726 ment n.e.c Manufacture of motor vehicles, trail- C29_C30 ers and semi-trailers; manufacture of 0.472 0.489 0.038 2.584 2.828 other transport equipment Manufacture of furniture; other manu- C31_C32 0.512 0.484 0.004 2.669 1.815 facturing Electricity, gas, steam and air condi- D35 0.072 0.831 0.097 1.512 1.740 tioning supply E36 Water collection, treatment and supply 0.256 0.739 0.005 0.700 0.561 Sewerage; waste collection, treatment E37-E39 and disposal activities; materials recov- 0.436 0.562 0.002 1.213 1.213 ery; remediation activities F Construction 0.503 0.473 0.025 2.048 1.168 Wholesale and retail trade and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles; G45_G46 0.709 0.278 0.014 0.822 0.564 wholesale trade. except of motor ve- hicles and motorcycles Retail trade. except of motor vehicles G47 0.695 0.243 0.062 0.772 0.473 and motorcycles Land transport and transport via pipe- H49_H50_ lines; water transport; air transport; 0.317 0.644 0.038 1.433 0.868 H51_H52 warehousing and support activities for transportation H53 Postal and courier activities 0.073 0.927 0.000 0.901 0.527 Accommodation and food service ac- I 0.675 0.226 0.099 1.188 0.558 tivities Publishing activities; motion picture, J58_J59_ video and television programme pro- 0.744 0.256 0.000 1.236 0.790 J60 duction, sound recording and music publishing activities Telecommunications; computer pro- J61_J62_ gramming, consultancy and related 0.605 0.31 0.084 1.419 1.290 J63 activities; information service activities Financial service activities. except in- surance and pension funding; insur- K64_K65_ ance, reinsurance and pension fund- 0.609 0.359 0.031 0.924 0.531 K66 ing except compulsory social security; activities auxiliary to financial services and insurance activities 106 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 L68 Real estate activities 0.448 0.484 0.068 0.925 0.324 Legal and accounting activities; activi- M69_M70 ties of head offices; management con - 0.772 0.228 0.00 0.633 0.505 sultancy activities Legal and accounting activities; activi- ties of head offices; management con - M69_ sultancy activities; architectural and 0.662 0.300 0.038 0.840 0.561 M70_M71 engineering activities; technical testing and analysis Scientific research and development; M72_M73_ advertising and market research; other 0.516 0.474 0.010 0.828 0.662 M74_M75 professional, scientific and technical activities; veterinary activities Other professional, scientific and tech - M74_M75 0.592 0.308 0.100 0.655 0.568 nical activities; veterinary activities Administrative and support service N 0.672 0.269 0.059 1.120 0.773 activities Public administration and defense; O84 0.965 0.033 0.002 0.524 0.280 compulsory social security P85 Education 0.745 0.184 0.071 0.485 0.232 Human health and social work activi- Q 0.567 0.403 0.030 0.861 0.621 ties R_S Other service activities 0.682 0.274 0.044 1.070 0.701 Notes: Industry-level GVC indicators calculated from WIOD are matched with SES data using classic fi ation NACE Rev. 2. In some cases, however, the sectors provided in SES cover broader categories. In order to assure the correspondence between SES and WIOD we calculated an average of industry indexes (e.g. FVA) for the non-standard industry classic fi ations e.g. C16_ C17, C26_C27_C33, J61_J62_J63. Source: SES and WIOD. Table A2. Descriptive statistics Obser­ Standard Variable Mean Min Max vations deviation wage 723706 24.422 15.815 9.13 95.11 sex 723706 0.497 0.500 0 1 ageyoung 723706 0.16 0.367 0 1 ageaverage 723706 0.554 0.497 0 1 loweduc 723706 0.055 0.228 0 1 mededuc 723706 0.528 0.499 0 1 FT 723706 0.923 0.266 0 1 skill 1 723706 0.078 0.268 0 1 D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 107 skill 2 723706 0.434 0.496 0 1 skill 3 723706 0.121 0.326 0 1 shortdur 723706 0.097 0.296 0 1 meddur 723706 0.268 0.443 0 1 small 723706 0.234 0.423 0 1 medium 723706 0.285 0.452 0 1 nationagr 723706 0.037 0.189 0 1 industagr 723706 0.000 0.000 0 0 enterpagr 723706 0.372 0.483 0 1 ln Prod 723706 3.135 0.874 1.242 5.133 FVA 723706 1.298 0.795 0.485 3.294 OFF 723706 1.077 0.960 0.232 3.601 Source: SES and WIOD. References Acemoglu, D., & Autor, D. (2011). Skills, tasks and technologies: Implications for em- ployment and earnings. In D. Card & O. Ashenfelter (Eds.), Handbook of labor eco- nomics (vol. 4, part B, pp. 1043–1171). Elsevier. Acemoglu, D., & Restrepo, P. (2018). The race between man and machine: Implications of technology for growth, factor shares, and employment. American Economic Review, 108(6), 1488–1542. Aringa, C. D., & Pagani, L. (2007). Collective bargaining and wage dispersion. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 45(1), 29–54. Autor, D. H., Dorn, D., & Hanson, G. H. (2016). The China shock: Learning from labor- market adjustment to large changes in trade. Annual Reviews, 8, 205–240. https:// doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-080315-015041 Avouyi-Dovi, S., Fougére, D., & Gautier, E. (2013). Wage rigidity, collective bargaining, and the minimum wage: Evidence from French agreement data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(4), 1337–1351. https://doi.org/10.1162/REST_a_00329 Basu, S., Estrin, S., & Svejnar, J. (2004). Wage determination under communism and in transition: Evidence from Central Europe. (IZA Discussion Papers No. 1276, pp. 1–20). Retrieved from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=586065 Baumgarten, D., Geishecker, I., & Görg, H. (2013). Os ff horing, tasks, and the skill-wage pattern. European Economic Review, 61, 132–152. Bernaciak, M. (2015). All roads lead to decentralization? Collective bargaining trends and prospects in Central and Eastern Europe. Transfer: European Review of Labour and Research, 21(3), 373–381. https://doi.org/10.1177/1024258915585947 Boeri, T. (2014). Two-tier bargaining. (IZA Discussion Paper No. 8358). Bonn. 108 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 Boeri, T., Brugiavini, A., & Calmfors, L. (Eds.). (2001). The role of unions in the twenty-first century: A report for the Fondazione Rodolfo Debenedetti . Oxford: Oxford University Press. Retrieved from https://econpapers.repec.org/ RePEc:oxp:obooks:9780199246588 Brandl, B., Bechter, B., Czarzasty, J., Lehr, A., Molina, O., Nordin, P, ..., Toa, A. (2021). European, national and transnational industrial relations: Visible and invisible hands in European and national wage setting. Durham. Calmfors, L., & Driffill, J. (1988). Bargaining structure, corporatism and macroeco - nomic performance. Economic Policy, 3(6), 13–61. https://doi.org/10.2307/1344503 Card, D., & Cardoso, A. R. (2021). Wage flexibility under sectoral bargaining . (NBER Working Paper Series No. 28695). Cardoso, M., Neves, P. C., Afonso, O., & Sochirca, E. (2021). The ee ff cts of os ff horing on wages: A meta-analysis. Review of World Economics, 157, 149‒179. https://doi. org/10.1007/s10290-020-00385-z Ebenstein, A., Harrison A., McMillan, M., & Phillips, S. (2014). Estimating the impact of trade and os ff horing on American workers using the current population sur - veys. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(4), 581–595. https://doi.org/10.1162/ REST_a_00400 Eurofound. (2015). Collective bargaining in Europe in the 21st century. Luxembourg. European Commission. (2015). Developments in European industrial relations. In Industrial Relations in Europe 2014 (pp. 41–66). Luxembourg: Publications Oc ffi e of the European Union. Eurostat. (2014). Structure of Earnings Survey 2014 Eurostat ’s arrangements for imple- menting the Council Regulation 530/1999, the Commission Regulations 1916/2000 and 1738/2005. Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1999). e i Th mpact of outsourcing and high-technol - ogy capital on wages: Estimates for the United States, 1979‒1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 907–940. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355399556179 Felbermayr, G., Hauptmann, A., & Schmerer, H. J. (2014). International trade and col- lective bargaining outcomes: Evidence from German employer–employee data. e Th Scandinavian Journal of Economics , 116(3), 820–837. https://doi.org/10.1111/ SJOE.12067 Geishecker, I., Görg, H., & Munch, J. R. (2010). Do labour market institutions matter? Micro-level wage ee ff cts of international outsourcing in three European countries. Review of World Economics, 146(1), 179–198. Gere, ffi G., & Fernandez-Stark, K. (2016). Global Value Chain analysis: A primer. Duke CGGC (Center on Globalization, Governance & Competitiveness). Gerlach, K., & Stephan, G. (2006). Pay policies of firms and collective wage contracts— An uneasy partnership?. Industrial Relations, 45(1), 47–67. https://doi.org/10.1111/ j.1468-232X.2006.00413.x Goos, M., Manning, A., & Salomons, A. (2014). Explaining job polarization: Routine- biased technological change and os ff horing. American Economic Review, 104(8), 2509–2526. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.8.2509 Grossman, G. M., & Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2008). Trading tasks: A simple theory of off - shoring. American Economic Review, 98(5), 1978–1997. D. Nikulin, J. Wolszczak-Derlacz, Wage determination, Global Value Chains 109 Gruetzemacher, R. , Dorner, F. E., Bernaola-Alvarez, N., Giattino, C., & Manheim, D. (2021). Forecasting AI progress: A research agenda. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 170, 120909. Guschanski, A., & Onaran, Ö. (2021). The decline in the wage share: falling bargaining power of labour or technological progress? Industry-level evidence from the OECD. Socio-Economic Review, 20(3), 1091–1124. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwaa031 Heckman, J. J., Lochner, L. J., Todd, P. E. (2006). Earnings functions, rates of return and treatment ee ff cts: The Mincer equation and beyond. In E. A. Hanushek & F. Welch (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of education (pp. 307–458). Elsevier. Hummels, B. D., Jørgensen, R., Munch, J., & Xiang, C. (2014). The wage ee ff cts of off - shoring: Evidence from Danish matched worker-firm data. American Economic Review, 104(6), 1597–1629. Kohl, H., & Platzer, H. (2007). The role of the state in Central and Eastern European industrial relations: The case of minimum wages. Industrial Relations Journal, 38(6), 614–635. Las Heras, J. (2018). International political economy of labour and collective bargain- ing in the automotive industry. Competition & Change, 22(3), 313–331. https://doi. org/10.1177/1024529418764350 Luo, S., & Yang, T. (2020). Why worker-supported collective bargaining may still fail: Union strategies and supply chain structure in South China. Employee Relations: e Th International Journal , 42(2), 471–491. https://doi.org/10.1108/ER-06-2019-0250 Milberg, W., & Houston, E. (2005). The high road and the low road to international competitiveness: Extending the neo-Schumpeterian trade model beyond tech- nology. International Review of Applied Economics, 19(2), 137–162. https://doi. org/10.1080/02692170500031646 Milberg, W., & Winkler, D. (2013). Outsourcing economics: Global value chains in capi- talist development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Müller, T., Vandaele, K., & Waddington, J. (2019a). Collective bargaining in Europe: Towards an endgame (vol. 1). Brussels: European Trade Union Institute. Müller, T., Vandaele, K., & Waddington, J. (2019b). Collective bargaining in Europe: Towards an endgame (vol. 2). Brussels: European Trade Union Institute. Müller, T., Vandaele, K., & Waddington, J. (2019c). Collective bargaining in Europe: Towards an endgame (vol. 4, Source materials). Brussels: European Trade Union Institute. Ndubuisi, G., & Owusu, S. (2022). Wage ee ff cts of global value chains participation and position: An industry-level analysis. e Th Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 1086‒1107. https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2022.2058068 Nickell, S., & Layard, R. (1999). Labor market institutions and economic performance. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (vol. 3, pp. 3029– 3084). Elsevier. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4463(99)30037-7 Nunziata, L. (2005). Institutions and wage determination: A multi-country approach. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 67(4), 435–466. https://doi.org/10.1111/ j.1468-0084.2005.00127.x Parteka, A., & Wolszczak-Derlacz, J. (2019). Global value chains and wages: International evidence from linked worker-industry data. Open Economies Review, 30(3), 505–539. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-018-9518-8 110 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 8 (22), No. 4, 2022 Parteka, A., & Wolszczak-Derlacz, J. (2020, April). Wage response to global production links: Evidence for workers from 28 European countries (2005–2014). Review of World Economics, 156, 769‒801. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-020-00380-4 Quast, B., & Kummritz, V. (2015). decompr: Global Value Chain decomposition in R. The Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies. Ramirez, P., & Rainbird, H. (2010). Making the connections: bringing skill formation into global value chain analysis. Work, Employment and Society, 24(4), 699–710. https://doi.org/10.1177/0950017010380641 Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institu - tions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2), 131–165. https://doi.org/10.1023/B:JOEG.0000031425.72248.85 Schäfer, A., & Gottschall, K. (2015). From wage regulation to wage gap: How wage-setting institutions and structures shape the gender wage gap across three industries in 24 European countries and Germany. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 39(2), 467‒496. Schulten, T. (2016). e m Th eaning of extension for the stability of collective bargaining in Europe. (ETUI Research Paper—Policy Brief 3/2016). Selwyn, B. (2013). Social upgrading and labour in global production networks: A cri- tique and an alternative conception. Competition and Change, 17(1), 75–90. https:// doi.org/10.1179/1024529412Z.00000000026 Stockhammer, E., & Onaran, Ö. (2009). National and sectoral inu fl ences on wage deter - mination in Central and Eastern Europe. European Journal of Industrial Relations, 15(3), 317–338. https://doi.org/10.1177/0959680109339417 Szymczak, S., Parteka, A., Wolszczak-Derlacz, J. (2022). Position in global value chains: e i Th mpact on wages in Central and Eastern European Countries. European Journal of Industrial Relations, 28(2), 211–230. Szymczak, S., & Wolszczak-Derlacz, J. (2022). Global value chains and labour mar- kets—simultaneous analysis of wages and employment. Economic Systems Research, 34(1), 69‒96. Timmer, M. P., Dietzenbacher, E., Los, B., Stehrer, R., & de Vries, G. J. (2015). An illus- trated user guide to the World Input–Output Database: The case of global automo - tive production. Review of International Economics, 23, 575–605. Wang, Z., Wei, S. J., & Zhu, K. (2013). Quantifying international production sharing at the bilateral and sector levels. Revised version 2018. (NBER Working Papers No. 19677). https://doi.org/10.3386/w19677

Journal

Economics and Business Reviewde Gruyter

Published: Dec 1, 2022

Keywords: wages; Global Value Chains; wage bargaining; F16; F66; J81

There are no references for this article.