Get 20M+ Full-Text Papers For Less Than $1.50/day. Start a 14-Day Trial for You or Your Team.

Learn More →

Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood configuration matter?

Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood configuration matter? This paper measures the extent to which effects of foreclosures vary across neighbor - hoods. It offers a simple empirical framework for decomposing the spillover effects on neighboring property prices. Data from Orange County, Florida, reveal that the effects systematically vary across neighborhoods by morphology. The results indi- cate that older, homogeneous age structure, and non-gated neighborhoods with high vacancy rates are most in jeopardy when foreclosures are present, as these neighbor- hoods show the greatest neighborhood house price effects. JEL Classification R31 1 Introduction Some neighborhoods in the USA were hit hard, but unevenly, by foreclosures in the aftermath of the 2008 housing market crash. The prevailing view has been that the uneven distribution of foreclosures is largely responsible for the uneven price effects observed across neighborhoods, as greater concentrations of foreclosures increase marginal price effects of additional foreclosures. But this perspective ignores the possibility that foreclosure price effects on surrounding properties may depend not only on the localized concentration of foreclosures, but also on the physical and Campbell et al. (2011) report for Massachusetts that 92 percent of the sellers do not observe foreclo- sures within one-tenth mile, while 81 percent within a quarter of a mile do not observe foreclosures dur- ing the year before sale. Data for Orange County, FL, the subject of this study, shows similar patterns. * Arno J. van der Vlist a.j.van.der.vlist@rug.nl Geoffrey K. Turnbull geoffrey.turnbull@ucf.edu Department of Finance. Dr. P. Phillips School of Real Estate, University of Central Florida, P.O. 161991, Orlando, FL 32816-1991, USA Real Estate Centre, Department of Economic Geography, University of Groningen, Postbox 800, 9700 AV Groningen, The Netherlands Vol.:(0123456789) 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist structural characteristics of neighborhoods. The nature of the built environment may matter; the age and uniformity of the neighborhood and the physical proximity to neglected or vacant foreclosed properties are determined by structural density and street configuration. The questions addressed here are straightforward: Does the sur - rounding built environment influence foreclosure price effects? And, if so, to what extent? Most reviews of empirical studies on foreclosure effects suggest that neighboring property prices tend to be anywhere between one to two percent lower in neighbor- hoods with foreclosures. The literature recognizes two mechanisms driving neigh- boring property prices lower. One is the negative foreclosure externality arising from poorly maintained or vacant foreclosed property. The second is the supply effect arising from the fact that foreclosures increase the supply of housing for sale (Anenberg and Kung 2014; Hartley 2014; Mian et  al. 2015; Gerardi et  al. 2015). Both mechanisms lead to lower neighborhood property values, the source of distress to residents and local governments. The prevailing focus on foreclosure externality and supply effects on prices of surrounding houses overlooks a possibly mediating influence within the neighbor - hood. For instance, supply of new construction provides positive physical externali- ties to the neighborhood (Ioannides 2002; Rosenthal 2008; Helms 2012; Zahirovic- Herbert and Gibler 2014; Coulson et  al. 2019; Gonzalez-Pampillon 2022). Buyers may interpret new construction as a signal of improved neighborhood quality, or the arrival of more affluent residents (Gonzalez-Pampillon 2022). In any case, new con- struction, whether rebuilding teardowns or new infill development, occurs unevenly in the interior of the urban area. We empirically control for differences in the sup- ply of new construction as a source of systematic variation in observed foreclosure price effects across neighborhoods. It is worth emphasizing at this point that the foreclosure externality argument itself also suggests possible variation in foreclosure effects across neighborhoods. The negative externality arises because foreclosures induce vacancy and underin- vestment in maintenance, creating negative physical externalities that reduce neigh- borhood attractiveness (Harding et al. 2009, 2012; Daneshvary and Clauretie 2012) For examples, see Clauretie and Daneshvary (2009), Lin et  al. (2009), Rogers and Winter (2009), Campbell et  al. (2011), Daneshvary and Clauretie (2012), Anenberg and Kung (2014), Gerardi et  al. (2015), Chinloy et al. (2017). The literature also refers to foreclosure externality as contagion effect (Harding et al. 2009) disamen- ity effect (Anenberg and Kung 2014), physical externality (Fisher et al. 2015) and investment externality (Cheung et al. 2014). The literature also refers to supply effect as competition effect (Anenberg and Kung 2014) or pecuniary externality (Gerardi et al. 2015). While it may seem odd to observe new construction in neighborhoods with foreclosures, the lead time required to obtain land, permits and complete new construction explains some of the new units being sold during the latest market downturn despite nearby foreclosures. Regardless, new construction contin- ued, although at a much lower rate, throughout the market crash and slow subsequent recovery in hard- hit Orange County, Florida, even in neighborhoods with foreclosures. For Orange County, Florida, new construction of single family residential homes dropped from 6,124 in 2007, to 2,039 in 2009, and 2,620 in 2012 (OCPA 2017). 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… as well as external social costs in the form of reduced social interaction and commu- nity involvement (Harding et  al. 2009) or increased crime (Immergluck and Smith 2006). Foreclosures may be the source of negative shopping externalities as well; potential buyers may interpret the presence of foreclosures as a signal of a greater risk of neighborhood instability or secular decline, which prompts them to focus their search efforts elsewhere. All of these factors reduce property values of sur - rounding non-distressed property. Not all neighborhoods, however, are equally vul- nerable to these risks (Anenberg and Kung 2014; Ihlanfeldt and Mayock 2016). This study focuses on how foreclosure price effects vary by neighborhood configuration. To do so, we use geocoded administrative data to allow more explicit models of how foreclosure effects vary across neighborhoods. This paper makes two contributions to the empirical housing market literature. First, we propose a simple framework for sorting neighborhood property price effects into foreclosure externality, new construction externality, and supply or pecu- niary externality effects. Most previous work struggles with how to empirically sep- arate these externality and supply effects and so tends to avoid distinguishing them explicitly. Studies that do distinguish externality and supply effects use supply meas- ures that count numbers of foreclosures at greater distance (Harding et  al. 2009), nearby foreclosures of different property types (Hartley 2014; Fisher et  al. 2015), or precise timing of distressed and non-distressed properties listings (Anenberg and Kung 2014). It seems appropriate to identify supply effects using measures of com- peting or substitute properties that are on the market at the same time as the subject property. To that end, we incorporate measures of both foreclosed and similar open market (non-foreclosed) properties for sale in the surrounding neighborhood at the same time as the subject property. Second, we examine whether foreclosure price effects vary with neighborhood configuration. Foreclosure effects may vary across neighborhoods due to differ - ences in underlying economic vitality (Rosenthal 2008), housing market segmenta- tion (Gerardi et al. 2015; Cheung et al. 2014; Zhang and Leonard 2014) as well as the neighborhood structure (Schuetz et  al. 2008). Ellen and O’Regan (2010) argue that neighborhood configuration matters for market outcomes in general. Applying that notion to this case, a foreclosure may be more visible or physically closer to more surrounding properties in some neighborhoods than in other neighborhoods, and as a result, generate stronger price responses. To take these neighborhood differ - ences into account, we also investigate foreclosure effects across built environments in terms of their urban density, neighborhood mix of homes, development period, vacancy rate, and whether the subdivision is gated or non-gated. The geographic concentration of foreclosures in certain neighborhoods suggests that, for some neighborhood configurations, the foreclosure effect might be nonlin- ear in the number of foreclosures (e.g., in the case of rather uniform neighborhoods with many similar properties). If so, even a few neighboring foreclosures relative to non-distressed sales will have significant value effects on surrounding non-dis- tressed transactions. Hanson et al. (2012) show that households tend to spatially sort by credit quality, creating conditions ripe for geographic concentration of foreclo- sures. The question remains whether the resultant concentrations of foreclosures in certain neighborhoods lead to increasing marginal price effects, exhibiting deeper 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist and more enduring neighborhood price effects than would otherwise be expected if foreclosures were instead more evenly distributed across the market area. Schuetz et  al. (2008) and Harding et  al. (2009) both find no evidence of nonlinear foreclo- sure effects. In contrast with the samples used in those studies, our sample covers a period of intense foreclosure activity in one of the most active foreclosure markets in the US, which allows us to probe more deeply into how an unprecedented level of foreclosures affects property prices. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains the empiri- cal framework to sort out the channels through which foreclosures may influence surrounding property values. Section  3 describes the data. Section  4 reports the empirical results. We first report on foreclosure spillover effects and then consider whether these spillover effects vary with neighborhood configuration. Section  5 concludes. 2 Empirical framework The empirical framework maps local foreclosures, open market sales and new con- struction onto neighboring house prices. In estimating these local effects we face the following challenge. Neighborhood effects such as foreclosure externalities (Camp- bell et  al. 2011; Towe and Lawley 2013), crime risk (Linden and Rockoff 2008) or externalities associated with new construction (Ioannides 2002; Helms 2012) may be associated with endogenous social effects (Manski 1993; Rossi-Hansberg et  al. 2010; Ross 2011; Ioannides 2011). These social effects arise when a house- hold’s foreclosure or new construction decision spillover to neighbors. Ideally, one would like to control for these effects using instrumental variables that are corre- lated with the local measure but not with price. We take the alternative approach used by Linden and Rockoff (2008) and Campbell et al. (2011), which relies on the impact of extremely local neighborhood measures and very small time windows, and compares the relevant coefficients pertaining to neighborhood measures before and after each property sale to control for the state of the local economy in the micro-neighborhood. We estimate separate localized externality effects of foreclosures, supply or pecu- niary externality effects, and new housing construction on other non-distressed property sales. We control for neighborhood market externalities by including Harding et al. (2009) proposed instruments such as mean loan originating credit score and mean loan originating loan-to-value at the neighborhood level. We applied the AHS data and, like Campbell et al. (2011), find no feasible instruments. In measuring neighborhood effects of housing renovation, Helms (2012) reports similar difficulty in alleviating the identification issue. Helms then proposes a spatial lag model in which all time-varying data are collapsed into one cross-section. Given the importance of timing in foreclosure effects, we follow Campbell et  al. (2011) by comparing the effect of foreclosures before and after each property sale. It is possible that we miss some of the neighborhood effects as major home improvements are not reg- istered consistently by our data source. While we do not have information on renovation, existing evi- dence implies that the positive externality effect of new construction is stronger than those from renova- tions (Helms 2012). 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… number of foreclosures, number of open market sales and, number of newly con- structed houses that are on the market at the same time as the subject property. The model we estimate specifies the log of price of house transaction i in neigh- borhood r and year t as a linear function of property characteristics and neighbor- hood market conditions: before before after after before before after after lnP =  X +  FS +  FS +  MS +  MS irt X it FS it FS it MS it MS it (1) before before after after +  NC +  NC +  +  +  , t r irt NC it NC it where P is the selling price; X the vector of house characteristics; FS the number irt it it of nearby foreclosures, MS the number of nearby open market sales, and NC is the it it number of nearby newly constructed houses, all within distance d and within time- frame τ before or after the subject property transaction. Equation (1) also includes location and (interaction) time fixed effects to reduce unobserved heterogeneity and omitted variable bias. Further,  is the error term clustered at the location fixed irt effects-level. Davis (2004) argues that using location fixed effects and clustered errors together also serves as nonparametric spatial correlation control. Cast this way, the FS, MS, and NC variables control for nearby foreclosed houses, open market (non-foreclosure) houses, and new construction in the neighborhood at the same time the subject property is for sale. The timeframe windows before and after are included to capture other properties on the market at the same time as the subject property, some of which sell before and some after the subject sells. The estimated coefficients for local market conditions variables provide important infor - mation regarding the extent of possible foreclosure and new construction externali- ties. FS captures the effect of foreclosures increasing the supply of existing houses on the market plus the negative foreclosure externality. MS captures the increasing supply associated with open (non-foreclosure) market sales of new construction and existing houses. The coefficient on the NC variable measures any externality associ- ated with new construction (holding the total supply of houses constant). These variables may include endogenous responses to neighborhood market con- ditions. Our identification strategy hinges on comparing short-run changes in values within very small areas arising from changes in the local or neighborhood housing market context. Following the procedure in Campbell et  al. (2011), the externality effect estimate is the difference between the coefficient for foreclosures before the subject property transaction and the coefficient for foreclosures after the transaction, before af ter [ −  ] . The standard error of the estimate can be calculated using the delta FS FS method. If foreclosure spillovers are present, then we should observe a negative impact as the largest negative impacts of foreclosure on property values are prior to the sale. The same identification strategy applies to the new construction and We use several location (zip code, census tract and census block group) and time fixed effect-levels (year, year-month). In the case of foreclosures, the lead window also picks up properties in the foreclosure process before they are formally put on the market. Harding et  al. (2009), Campbell et  al. (2011) and Gerardi et  al. (2015) note that what we identify as the foreclosure externality effect may begin early in the foreclosure process. 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist open market sales variables. To the extent that local economic shocks impact house prices, we include in one of the models also past and future foreclosures slightly farther away (between one-tenth and a quarter of a mile) as controls (Linden and Rockoff 2008; Campbell et al. 2011). Second, because foreclosures generate both negative externality and supply effects (or pecuniary externality), we follow Anenberg and Kung (2014) and Hartley (2014), and use the difference in estimates relative to market sales to remove the supply effects of foreclosures on price, which in our application reduces to before after before after Foreclosure externality = [ −  ]− [ −  ]. (2) FS FS MS MS The above calculation measures the combined effect of increasing nearby fore- closures by one, while decreasing the number of non-distressed properties on the market by one, to arrive at the net externality effect of an additional foreclosure. Finally, to the extent that new construction creates a positive spillover in the neighborhood, the difference in the before and after coefficient estimates for the new construction variables should reflect the new construction externality: before after New construction externality = [ −  ]. (3) NC NC In this case, there is no need to remove a supply effect because the number of non-distressed properties for sale (which includes new houses) is already being cap- tured by the market sales variables (which includes new houses). The estimated new construction effect reflects the effect of increasing the number of new houses for sale by one, while simultaneously decreasing the number of existing houses for sale by one. If the (negative) FS coefficient is algebraically less than the MS coefficient, then increasing the number of foreclosures while holding neighborhood supply constant reduces the prices of surrounding properties. This result is consistent with a negative real externality effect from neighboring foreclosures. If, on the other hand, the FS and MS coefficients are not significantly different, neighboring foreclosures have no real externality effect on surrounding properties. Finally, if the (negative) MS coeffi- cient is less than the FS coefficient, then increasing the number of foreclosures while holding neighborhood market supply constant increases the prices of surrounding properties. Although it may seem counter-intuitive at first blush, this outcome is nonetheless consistent with foreclosed properties generating a stronger shopping externality for the neighborhood than open market properties. In this case, the pres- ence of nearby foreclosures for sale is a stronger draw for potential buyers than open market properties; the resultant increases in buyer arrival rates increase the prob- abilities of higher priced matches for nearby sellers, including sellers of open market properties. It is important to remember that the coefficients on the new construction variables (NC) do not capture supply effects and instead solely pick up the neighbor - hood quality signaling or the housing investment externality effect arising from new construction. This assumes foreclosures and market sales have identical supply effects on the subject property price. 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… To provide evidence on the extent of variation in foreclosure effects by neigh- borhood configuration, we estimate separate models by the built structure of the neighborhood. The neighborhood configuration is often defined in terms of streets, lots, and buildings. Along with physical elements, the social aspects of urban mor- phology have also been deemed important (Nedovic-Budic et  al. 2016). We sum- marize neighborhood configuration using a set of simple dimensions of urban form: urban density, neighborhood mix of homes, development period, vacancy rate, and whether the property is in a gated or non-gated neighborhood subdivision. 3 Data The data are drawn from property assessment records of Orange County, Florida, covering all of the 426,021 parcels in the county as of August 24, 2012. Orange County is part of the Orlando-Kissimmee-Sanford Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA), and has been experiencing long-term population growth from 896,344 (2000 Census) to 1,145,956 (2010 Census). Orange County is an interesting case study to explore whether foreclosure price effects vary across neighborhoods. Orange County is one of the epicenters of the foreclosure crisis. While so, foreclo- sures were not evenly distributed across neighborhoods. We focus on how foreclo- sure price effects vary by neighborhood configuration. Local assessor records in Florida have been used as the primary data source in a number of studies and have several advantages (Ihlanfeldt and Mayock 2012; Turn- bull and Van der Vlist 2023). One advantage of local assessor records over multiple listing service (MLS) data for broker-assisted transactions is that tax records pro- vide information on the entire stock of existing properties, not just those that sell. Another is that MLS data do not cover all public transactions and, most important for the question addressed here, likely underreport foreclosure transactions (Danesh- vary and Clauretie 2012; Chinloy et al. 2017)—which may be critically important in this sample, as increasing numbers of foreclosed properties in Orange County were sold directly to investment firms and other organized investors without first being offered to individual buyers through traditional channels like the MLS. Conversely, a disadvantage of tax assessment records is that they provide no direct information about liquidity or time-on-the market for sold properties (although most existing foreclosure studies using MLS data also have not exploited liquidity data). Krainer (2001) shows that changes in buyer willingness-to-pay is reflected in both selling price and liquidity in search markets; recent empirical studies provide evidence of price-liquidity capitalization for both individual property and neighbor- hood characteristics (Turnbull et  al. 2013; Turnbull and Zahirovic-Herbert 2011). Therefore, the absence of marketing time measures in this study means that the price effects of foreclosures identified here, as well as in most of the foreclosure literature, may reflect only one dimension of the possible capitalization effects. Measuring urban form remains an important topic in the field of urban studies, as we refer to White- hand (1992), Anas et al. (1998), Song and Knaap (2003; 2004; 2007), and Nedovic-Budic et al. (2016). 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist The tax records yield detailed information on property characteristics as well as addresses, transaction prices, transaction dates, and deed types (which allows us to identify foreclosed properties). We focus on built-up areas of the county, exclud- ing the sparsely settled northwestern and eastern parts of the jurisdiction. The sin- gle family detached house (SFD) data cover 266,897 separate properties during the sample period of January 2007 through August 2012. The data include transaction price, transaction date, and deed type. The struc- ture of the data source allows us to observe the transaction history over 2007-to mid-2012. This sample period captures the declining market over 2008–2010 and the weak recovery starting in early 2012. The dependent variable is the transaction price. The control variables measure property characteristics and location and time fixed effects. The analysis focuses on single family detached houses (SFD). Living area indicates the square feet of air-conditioned/heated area. Other property charac- teristics include number of bedrooms and bathrooms, presence of a private swim- ming pool, house age, and type of exterior walls. Total land acreage is the measure of parcel size and encompasses both upland and any submerged area lying within the parcel legal boundary. The data allow us to construct GIS-based neighborhood housing market conditions indicators based on the number of FS, MS, and NC in the neighborhood within distance d (one-tenth, a quarter of a mile) taking place within time frame τ before and after transaction time t (90, 180 days) of each subject property. We define neighborhood configuration using a set of simple dimensions of urban form. First, we measure urban density, development period, and vacancy at the neighborhood census blockgroup-level, using the 2000 American Community Sur- vey (ACS). Next, at a more granular level, we measure neighborhood mix of homes (variation in development period, and size of living area) at the census block-level, using the administrative parcel-level data for the year 2000. Last, we identify for each transaction whether a property lies within a private gated or publicly acces- sible non-gated subdivision, using administrative information on subdivisions. We use these measures to examine how foreclosure effects vary with neighborhood configuration. The sample consists of  open market transactions transferring warranty deeds, and excludes all legal administrator’s deed, tax deed, and quit claim deeds (all for administrative non-arm’s length transaction purposes), including all transactions for $100, the usual indicator of a non-market transfer of property interest. Following Daneshvary et al. (2011), we trim the lower and upper 1 percent of the distribution of price and living area to control for outliers. Furthermore, we define the maximum spatial extent of the surrounding neighborhood for each property as one mile, so We use deed information to identify foreclosed properties as follows: Florida is a judicial foreclosure state which means that the clerk of court must file a Certificate of Title after a foreclosure auction takes place. The Certificate of Title instrument allows lenders to take back their properties and subsequently sell it either through auction or listing. We use Certificate of Titles to identify (the flow of new) foreclo- sures. A Warranty deed instrument refers to open market sales. New construction refers to open market sales of new properties (for a discussion, see Turnbull and Van der Vlist 2023). Note that membership of a subdivision association is mandatory in the case of a gated subdivision. 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… while observations within one mile of the county boundary are used to construct instruments for total number of properties, foreclosed sales, market sales, and new construction, they are not otherwise included in the price equation sample. Simi- larly, observations in the first six-month time frame are excluded from the model estimation to construct the proper burn-in period for our instruments. The number of observations in the sample for estimating the price equation is 39,913 open market transactions. Variable definitions are given in Appendix 1. Table  1 reports the descriptive statistics. The table indicates a mean price of almost $235,000 and a median of $185,000, thus reflecting a distribution skewed to the right. We therefore use the natural logarithm of transaction price in the empirical analysis. Structural property characteristics indicate the type of building construc- tion material (63% have walls made of stucco covered concrete block versus wood frame construction), number of bedrooms (3.45 average), living area (2,040 square feet average), number of bathrooms (2.32 average), presence of a private pool (27%), lot size (40,079 square feet average), and actual age of the house (22.6 years). Loca- tion controls include the (quadratic) distance to the Orlando CBD (8.98 miles linear distance average) and zip code fixed effects. Over 70 percent of the transactions lie within the City of Orlando, the largest and most populous municipality in Orange County. A further decomposition of descriptive statistics by neighborhood configuration is found in Appendix 2. The descriptive statistics report some structural differences in average property characteristics across type of neighborhood. Low density neigh- borhoods have lower mean house prices ($206,809) than high density neighbor- hoods ($281,254). Also, older neighborhoods (in terms of mean building age) have lower mean house prices ($165,234) relative to newer neighborhoods ($311,275). The typical property in these older neighborhoods is smaller in terms of living area, and of less quality in terms of construction materials, but they generally have larger parcels. Note further that house prices are higher in neighborhoods with more het- erogeneous housing stock measured in terms of property age or property size. The lower panel of Table 1 provides summary statistics for the constructed vari- ables measuring neighborhood market conditions including the number of fore- closures (FS), the number of market transactions (MS), and the number of newly constructed properties (NC). The data reveal that a large majority of sales occur in areas with no surrounding foreclosures. This is consistent with Campbell et  al. (2011) although the overall incidence of foreclosures in Orange County is greater. In total, 82.6 percent of sellers do not have any foreclosure within one-tenth mile and 180 days. Multiple nearby foreclosures are even less frequent. The data reveal that 95.7 percent of the sellers do not observe two or more foreclosures, while 98.8 The original data cover 54,553 open market sales of which 7,542 are administrative warranty deeds with a price of $100 which we remove from the sample. We then trim the lower and upper 1% of living area (removing 581 observations), transaction price (removing 91 observations), and properties whose construction date is listed as occurring after the transaction date (removing 604 observations). We also lose 5,802 observations for the burn-in space and time period when constructing the FS, MS, and NC variables. The resultant data set has 39,913 observations. 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist percent of the sellers do not observe three or more foreclosures, all within one-tenth mile and 180 days. The mean number of nearby foreclosures is 0.235 but varies across neighbor- hood types. Likewise, one observes differences in the number of market sales and in the number of newly constructed properties. Looking at the number of newly con- structed properties within the indicated geographic area and time frame, the aver- age new construction (0.542 for the pooled sample) varies between 0.117 and 4.522 across neighborhood types. These transactions can be interpreted relative to the den- sity or mean total property which varies across neighborhood types between 19.59 and 36.76. Overall, the FS, MS, and NC measures all show substantial variation across neighborhood configuration. 4 Empirical results 4.1 Foreclosure spillover effects Table  2 reports the results for the pooled models of Eq.  (1). The models indicate joint significance of the specification. The estimates for the structural characteristics of the property are as expected. Property value decreases with distance to the CBD and the effect becomes less pronounced at greater distances. House structure quality and exterior construction matter. Concrete block construction covered with stucco exhibits higher market value relative to wood frame construction. In addition, larger houses in terms of number of bedrooms, living area and number of bathrooms are associated with higher property values. A pool has a significant positive effect on property value in this market, as does parcel size. The lower panel in Table  2 reports associated estimates for the price effects of surrounding foreclosures on property prices based on Eqs.  (2) and (3). The esti- mates reveal that foreclosures within one-tenth mile and 180 days before the sale of a given subject property have significant negative effects on surrounding open mar - ket sales. The marginal effect of a foreclosure before a sale is significantly stronger than the coefficient of a foreclosure after a sale, a result consistent with Campbell et al. (2011). Note that sales of some properties occurring after the subject property sells are also on the market before the subject sells. Also observe that the foreclosure coefficient is stronger than the coefficient on open market or non-distressed sales, which implies that the negative foreclosure externality effect dominates its associ- ated supply effect. In our model 1, the foreclosure externality effect calculated using Eq. (2) is − 0.0152 with a standard error of 0.005 and is significant at the 1 percent For a wider time window of 360 days before sale, the statistic is 72.27 percent within 1/10 mile. For multiple foreclosures the statistic is 89.54 percent within 1/10 mile for two or more foreclosures, or 95.70 percent for three or more. We also test whether these effects are driven by structural density using auxiliary regressions that con- trol for total number of properties within one tenth of a mile. These results confirm that our effects are not driven by density. 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… Table 1 Descriptive statistics Mean St. dev Property controls Price 234,425 176,698 CBD distance (miles) 8.979 4.207 Walls concrete stucco (1 = yes) 0.632 Number of bedrooms 3.448 0.790 Living area (in sq. ft.) 2,040 830.2 Age of property (in years) 22.61 20.50 Number of bathrooms 231.6 79.05 Pool (1 = yes) 0.265 Parcel size (in sq. ft.) 40,079 39,637 Neighborhood configuration Low density 0.258 High density 0.274 Low vacancy 0.231 High vacancy 0.283 Old neighborhood 0.251 New neighborhood 0.235 Homogeneous in age SFD 0.244 Homogeneous in age SFD 0.239 Heterogeneous in living area SFD 0.253 Homogeneous in living area SFD 0.247 Local housing market controls Number of foreclosure sales (near, before) 0.235 0.595 Number of foreclosure sales (near, after) 0.205 0.543 Number of foreclosure sales (far, before) 0.626 1.183 Number of foreclosure sales (far, after) 0.628 1.144 Number of foreclosure sales = 1 (near, before) 0.131 Number of foreclosure sales = 2 (near, before) 0.031 Number of foreclosure sales > 2 (near, before) 0.012 Number of market sales (near, before) 1.633 2.474 Number of market sales (near, after) 1.096 1.410 Number of market sales (far, before) 3.915 4.373 Number of market sales (far, after) 2.971 2.910 Number of new construction (near, before) 0.542 2.428 Number of new construction (near, after) 0.806 3.650 Number of new construction (far, before) 0.273 1.325 Number of new construction (far, after) 0.441 1.902 See Appendix 1 for variable definitions. N is 39,913 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist Table 2 Estimation results pooled model (1) (2) Coefficient Std. error Coefficient Std. error Property controls CBD distance (miles) − 0.0279 *** (0.0079) − 0.0276 *** (0.0078) CBD distance squared 0.0013 *** (0.0003) 0.0013 *** (0.0003) Walls concrete stucco 0.0692 *** (0.0062) 0.0672 *** (0.0061) Number of bedrooms less than 3 − 0.0274 *** (0.0103) − 0.0256 ** (0.0104) Number of bedrooms more than 3 − 0.0233 *** (0.0052) − 0.0233 *** (0.0052) Log living area 0.6620 *** (0.0121) 0.6670 *** (0.0121) Log age − 0.0457 *** (0.0024) − 0.0475 *** (0.0024) Number of bathrooms is 1 − 0.1630 *** (0.0116) − 0.1620 *** (0.0116) Number of bathrooms is 1.50 − 0.1320 *** (0.0152) − 0.1310 *** (0.0149) Number of bathrooms is 2.50 0.0058 (0.0058) 0.0069 (0.0059) Number of bathrooms more than 2.5 0.0689 *** (0.0071) 0.0691 *** (0.0071) Pool 0.1290 *** (0.0047) 0.1280 *** (0.0047) Log parcel size 0.3160 *** (0.0066) 0.3120 *** (0.0065) Local housing market controls Number of foreclosure sales (near, before) − 0.0206 *** (0.0032) − 0.0143 *** (0.0030) Number of foreclosure sales (near, after) − 0.0042 (0.0033) 0.0007 (0.0033) Number of foreclosure sales (far, before) − 0.0183 *** (0.0022) Number of foreclosure sales (far, after) − 0.0051 *** (0.0017) Number of market sales (near, before) − 0.0013 (0.0012) − 0.0019 * (0.0012) Number of market sales (near, after) − 0.00002 (0.0015) 0.0004 (0.0015) Number of market sales (far, before) 0.0034 *** (0.0007) Number of market sales (far, after) 0.0004 (0.0009) Number of new construction (near, before) − 0.0076 *** (0.0013) − 0.0029 ** (0.0014) Number of new construction (near, after) − 0.0122 *** (0.0016) − 0.0084 *** (0.0015) Number of new construction (far, before) − 0.0061 *** (0.0009) Number of new construction (far, after) − 0.0071 *** (0.0013) Number of observations 39,913 39,913 R-squared 0.807 0.808 Spillover effects Foreclosure externality − 0.0152 *** (0.0049) − 0.0127 *** (0.0048) New construction externality 0.0046 ** (0.0019) 0.0054 *** (0.0019) The dependent variable is log transaction value. The reference category include Number of Bedrooms equals 3, Number of Bathrooms equals 2.00. All models include location fixed effects for ZIP code, and time fixed effects for year and quarter. Clustered standard errors at Census block level are in parentheses with ***, **, * indicating significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Spillover effects are determined using Eqs. (2) and (3) with implied standard errors using delta method. N is 39,913 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… level. For model 2, where we control for local housing market conditions by add- ing local housing market measures of number of foreclosure sales, market sales, and new construction within one-tenth and a quarter of a mile, the foreclosure effect on surrounding property remains economically significant and, not surprisingly, nega- tive. Note further that the foreclosure externality effect within one-tenth and one quarter of a mile (denoted with ‘far’) is − 0.0162 and statistically not significantly different from the obtained foreclosure externality effect nearby. The new construction coefficient before a sale relative to the coefficient after a sale indicates that new construction has a positive externality effect on neighbor - hood housing. This finding is consistent with the notion that potential buyers regard new construction as a positive signal of neighborhood stability or growth (Ioannides 2002; Helms 2012; Zahirovic-Herbert and Gibler 2014; Gonzalez-Pampillon 2022) or that new construction generates positive shopping externalities for surrounding existing properties. The associated new construction externality effect calculated using Eq. (3) is 0.005, with a standard error of 0.002 and is significant at the 2 per - cent significance level. It is interesting to compare the negative foreclosure externality and the positive new construction externality in detail. Our estimates indicate that the negative exter- nality effect of a foreclosure outweighs the positive externality effect of new con- struction. A linear test on equality of the parameters of Eqs.  (2) and (3) gives an F value of 14.0 and is beyond the critical value at the 1 percent significance level. Hence, while new construction provides a positive signal to the neighborhood, the marginal effect of the (negative) foreclosure externality dominates. Table  3 reports key estimates for various location and time (interaction) fixed effects. Pulling these results together we find foreclosure externality effects any - where between − 0.0156 and − 0.0096. These estimates are similar to our main results. For new construction externality effects we find estimates between 0.001 and 0.0055, which for some fixed effects specifications are not significantly different from zero. 4.2 F oreclosure spillover effects and neighborhood configuration We turn now to the variation in foreclosure effect by neighborhood configuration. What we have obtained thus far is an average effect of foreclosure on property prices. But we have argued that foreclosure effects may vary across neighborhoods. We probe more deeply into urban morphology and how foreclosure effects vary with a set of simple dimensions of urban structure, viz. urban density, neighborhood mix The foreclosure externality calculated using (2) equals ((− 0.0206–− 0.0042)—(− 0.0013–0.00002)) or − 0.0152. The foreclosure externality calculated using (2) equals ((− 0.0143—0.0007)—(− 0.0019–0.0004)) or − 0.0127. The foreclosure externality far calculated using (2) equals ((− 0.0183–0.0051)—(0.0034–0.0004)) or − 0.0163. The F-test on equal foreclosure externality effects near equals far yields a statistic of 0.48 and does not favor the alternative hypothesis of unequal foreclosure effects. 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Table 3 Summary of results for models with varying fixed effects (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Local housing market controls Number of foreclo- − 0.0213 *** − 0.0214 *** − 0.0135 *** − 0.0125 *** − 0.0202 *** − 0.0099 *** − 0.0082 ** sure sales (near, (0.0038) (0.0035) (0.0029) (0.0032) (0.0034) (0.0029) (0.0036) before) Number of foreclo- − 0.0057 * − 0.0063 * 0.0007 0.0014 − 0.0066 ** 6.50e-05 − 0.0012 sure sales (near, (0.0031) (0.0032) (0.0036) (0.0043) (0.0032) (0.0036) (0.0044) after) Number of market − 0.0014 − 0.0008 0.0006 0.0011 − 0.0014 − 0.0004 0.0004 sales (near, (0.0022) (0.0017) (0.0014) (0.0017) (0.0015) (0.0012) (0.0015) before) Number of market 0.0011 0.0009 0.00071 − 0.0006 0.0001 − 0.0005 − 0.0022 sales (near, after) (0.0023) (0.0019) (0.0016) (0.0021) (0.0017) (0.0015) (0.0020) Number of new − 0.0070 *** − 0.0076 *** − 0.0052 *** − 0.0062 *** − 0.0064 *** − 0.0035 ** − 0.0046 ** construction (near, (0.0024) (0.0022) (0.0019) (0.0022) (0.0018) (0.0016) (0.0019) before) Number of new − 0.0121 *** − 0.0127 *** − 0.0108 *** − 0.0085 *** − 0.0111 *** − 0.0086 *** − 0.0056 *** construction (near, (0.0036) (0.0035) (0.0031) (0.0032) (0.0033) (0.0027) (0.0027) after) Fixed effect Zip + Year Tract + Year Tract × Year Tract × Month-Year Block group + Year Block group Block group × Month- × Year Year Observations 39,913 39,913 39,913 39,913 39,913 39,913 39,913 R-squared 0.804 0.810 0.837 0.88 0.816 0.849 0.915 Spillover effects Foreclosure exter- − 0.0131 *** − 0.0134 *** − 0.0139 *** − 0.0156 *** − 0.0121 ** − 0.0101 ** − 0.0096 * nality (0.0050) (0.0057) (0.0052) (0.0060) (0.0050) (0.0048) (0.0054) New construction 0.0050 0.0051 0.0055 * 0.0023 0.0047 0.0051 * 0.0010 externality (0.0051) (0.0033) (0.0030) (0.0031) (0.0030) (0.0030) (0.0029) The dependent variable is log transaction value. The reference category include Number of Bedrooms equals 3, Number of Bathrooms equals 2.00. Clustered standard errors at respective location fixed effect-level are in parentheses with ***, **, * indicating significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Spillover effects are determined using Eqs. (2) and (3) with implied standard errors using delta method. N is 39,913 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… of homes, and development period, vacancy rate, and whether the property is in a gated or non-gated neighborhood subdivision. First we consider urban density based on the premise that foreclosures in low density neighborhoods may have stronger price effects because they are more vis- ible than in high density neighborhoods. We test for this effect by examining fore- closure price effects for subsamples partitioned by density. We partition the data into low density and high density and re-estimate the basic model on the resultant subsamples. In order to probe more deeply into how foreclosures may depend more subtly on the neighborhood mix, we use a variety of ways to measure differences between neighborhoods. One way to control for type of neighborhood is to segment by mean vacancy rate (low and high vacancy rates ) or mean age of the neighborhood (new and old neighborhoods ). We use these measures of between-neighborhood vari- ation to identify the extent to which differences in the foreclosure externality arise across neighborhoods. Table 4 reports the key estimates. Looking at the results summarized in Table 4, the point estimates of the foreclo- sure externality effect, as measured by the difference in before and after FS and MS coefficients, indicate a somewhat stronger impact in the lowest density neighbor - hoods. The implied pattern of the foreclosure signaling/density relationship is con- sistent with that suggested by Schuetz et al. (2008). Another way to control for type of neighborhood is to use the coefficient of var - iation to measure within-neighborhood variation in terms of age or size of house (homogeneous versus heterogeneous neighborhoods ). Overall, the results indicate strongest effects for homogeneous neighborhoods, both in terms of age or size of the housing units. We interpret this as strong evidence of a signaling effect of neigh- borhood stability. The estimates suggest two factors at work. First, the foreclosure externality varies with the physical structure of the neighborhood as measured by density and (variation in) age and size of houses. Second, the foreclosure external- ity varies with the specific neighborhood housing market conditions as measured by vacancy rate. We next turn to the possibility that the main effect of foreclosures on prices might be nonlinear. Figure 1 depicts the structure by mapping the parameter estimates for the various neighborhood types. These results are based on models that employ a set of foreclosure dummy variables as a flexible structure to capture any nonlinear effects associated with the number of foreclosures. The effects are consistent with Low and high density refers to p(25) and p(75) of the probability density function of number of units per census block group, or 1117 and 3613 units, respectively. Low and high vacancy refers to p(25) and p(75) of the probability density function of vacancy rate per census block group, or 8.5 and 17.4) percent, respectively. New and old neighborhood refers to p(25) and p(75) of the probability density function of age per census block group, or 6 and 36 years, respectively. Homogeneity and heterogeneity are based on the within census-block neighborhood coefficient of var - iation of, for example, age or size of house. Homogeneity refers to a low coefficient of variation (p(25) of the probability density function across all neighborhoods), whereas heterogeneity refers to a high coef- ficient of variation (p(75) of the probability density function across all neighborhoods). 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist the basic models examined earlier. There appears to be a cumulative negative real externality from additional foreclosures varying by neighborhood configuration. Summarizing the results, we find that older, homogeneous neighborhoods with high vacancy rates are most in jeopardy when foreclosures are present. Table  4 also reports the key estimates when comparing neighborhoods in gated versus non-gated subdivisions. Gated subdivisions in this market are private com- munities that offer their residents amenities which are unavailable to the general public. Properties in gated communities are also typically subject to stricter controls regarding maintenance and use than are properties in non-gated neighborhoods. The community associations governing gated neighborhoods often have legal powers to compel maintenance or undertake actions to maintain the neighborhood character. It is therefore not surprising that results reported in Table 4 show that foreclosure and new construction externalities vary significantly across gated and non-gated neigh- borhood types. Legal governing powers used by community associations in gated Table 4 Summary of results for models by neighborhood type Neighborhood type Spillover effects N F—statistic Foreclosure externality New construction externality Density Low number of units − 0.0428 *** (0.0151) 0.0268 *** (0.0092) 10,284 15.02 *** High number of units − 0.0047 (0.0047) 0.0013 (0.0021) 10,943 1.60 Vacancy rate Low vacancy rate − 0.0139 (0.0094) 0.0050 (0.0041) 9,216 3.58 * High vacancy rate − 0.0177 ** (0.0081) 0.0111 *** (0.0038) 11,282 10.30 *** Neighborhood age New neighborhood − 0.0038 (0.0054) 0.0054 *** (0.0018) 9,361 3.04 * Old neighborhood − 0.0359 ** (0.0177) 0.0046 (0.0701) 9,999 0.30 Within neighborhood variation in age of houses Homogeneous in age of SFD − 0.0229 * (0.0121) 0.1214 * (0.0642) 9,719 4.70 ** Heterogeneous in age of SFD − 0.0150 * (0.0082) 0.0066 *** (0.0019) 9,522 6.67 ** Within neighborhood variation in size of houses Homogeneous in living area − 0.0308 *** (0.0089) 0.0110 * (0.0058) 10,103 15.00 *** of SFD Heterogeneous in living area − 0.0197 (0.0119) 0.0054 * (0.0039) 9,855 4.05 ** of SFD Subdivision Gated − 0.0070 (0.0067) 0.0026 (0.0030) 6,445 2.30 Non-gated − 0.0170 *** (0.0056) 0.0062 ** (0.0024) 33,468 13.90 *** Table summarizes the results for the spillover effects, based on model specification (1) in Table  2. The dependent variable is log transaction value. The reference category include Number of Bedrooms equals 3, Number of Bathrooms equals 2,00. All models include location fixed effects for ZIP code, and time fixed effects for year and month. Clustered standard errors at Census block level are in parentheses with ***, **, * indicating significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The last column gives the F—statis- tic of a linear test on foreclosure externality equals new construction externality 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… neighborhoods appear to obviate both types of externalities, in contrast to the sig- nificant effects observed for non-gated neighborhoods. 5 Conclusion Foreclosures influence nearby property values, but the marginal effects vary signifi- cantly across neighborhoods. Our approach estimates the foreclosure effects across neighborhoods while controlling for the increasing supply of housing for sale as erstwhile foreclosed owners are removed from the market. We also introduce new construction into the empirical framework to control for possible externality effects arising when buyers interpret new construction as a signal of neighborhood stability or future growth, removing these possibly confounding influences on the estimated foreclosure externality effects across neighborhood types. Data from an epicenter of the US foreclosure experience, Orange County, Flor- ida, reveal that nearby foreclosures appear to reduce property prices by 1.43 percent overall. Removing the supply effect, these estimates imply a foreclosure externality of − 1.27 percent. The new construction externality is 0.5 percent. Turning to the main point of this paper, we find that foreclosure spillover effects systematically vary across types of neighborhoods, exhibiting almost tenfold varia- tion in some cases. For example, the marginal foreclosure externality ranges from −  0.38 percent for newer neighborhoods to − 3.59 percent for older ones. Overall, the strongest foreclosure effects are found in low density neighborhoods, structurally homogeneous neighborhoods, and non-gated subdivisions. We also find that non- linear foreclosure effects vary across types of neighborhoods, with older, structur - ally homogeneous neighborhoods with high vacancy rates most in jeopardy in this regard. Admittedly, urban morphology includes more dimensions than the ones we have considered, including street connectivity and accessibility. Likewise, as foreclosures force affected households to move, foreclosures may well have long-term implica- tions for the composition and social stability of urban neighborhoods. Hawley and Turnbull (2019) show that the built environment affects household behavior, but at the same time households choose neighborhoods with built environments conducive to pursuing lifestyles they prefer. Taking this type of endogenous household sort- ing into account, while we find that neighborhood built environment does matter for foreclosure price effects on surrounding properties, the Hawley and Turnbull (2019) conclusions suggest a need for future work to identify the extent to which these effects are specifically related to the built environment or to the mix of residents attracted to neighborhoods with those characteristics. 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Fig. 1 Nonlinear foreclosure effects across neighborhood types, number of foreclosures FS (near, before). Note Graphs plot coefficient for I1 (FS = 1), I2 (FS = 2), and I3 (FS = 3 or more), based on model specification (1) in Table  2. The dependent variable is log transaction value. The reference category includes Number of Bedrooms equals 3, Number of Bathrooms equals 2.00. All models include location fixed effects for ZIP code, and time fixed effects for year and month Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… Appendix 1: Data appendix Variables Definition Price Sales price property i at time t Number of foreclosures (near, before) Number of foreclosures within 1/10 mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of foreclosures (near, after) Number of foreclosures within 1/10 mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of foreclosures (far, before) Number of foreclosures within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of foreclosures (far, after) Number of foreclosures within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of market sales (near, before) Number of warranty deeds within 1/10 mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of market sales (near, after) Number of warranty deeds within 1/10 mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of market sales (far, before) Number of warranty deeds within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of market sales (far, after) Number of warranty deeds within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of new construction (near, Number of new constructed properties—based on building before) date—within 1/10 mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of new construction (near, after) Number of new constructed properties—based on building date—within 1/10 mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of new construction (far, before) Number of new constructed properties—based on building date—within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of new construction (far, after) Number of new constructed properties—based on building date—within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Living area Living area in sq. ft Bedrooms Number of bedrooms Baths Number of bathroons Walls of concrete stucco Dummy 1 if made of concrete stucco, 0 otherwise Pool Dummy 1 if private pool, 0 otherwise Age Age of property in years Parcel size Parcel size in acres CBD distance CBD distance relates to distance to Intersection of Central Blvd. and Orange Ave. Orlando, Fl 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Appendix 2: Descriptive statistics by neighborhood type Low density High density New Old Low vacancy High vacancy Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Property controls Price 206,809 186,390 281,254 157,962 311,275 182,766 165,234 139,648 247,824 185,193 252,909 200,570 CBD distance 5.631 3.999 12.04 2.272 12.26 3.138 4.694 3.055 7.979 3.433 9.008 4.253 Living area 1,695 732.3 2,496 773.5 2,655 737.1 1,490 567.5 2,060 847.5 2,089 876.8 Bedrooms 3.112 0.784 3.832 0.770 3.895 0.728 3.024 0.749 3.476 0.792 3.458 0.777 Baths 199.4 77.48 266.9 74.21 280.1 76.99 177.6 65.73 235.1 81.35 236.7 81.01 Walls concrete 0.352 0.478 0.933 0.251 0.965 0.183 0.169 0.375 0.602 0.490 0.646 0.478 Pool 0.202 0.402 0.329 0.470 0.226 0.419 0.174 0.379 0.304 0.460 0.248 0.432 Age 41.15 22.78 8.27 8.44 3.21 3.30 51.04 14.57 24.07 20.05 20.74 20.86 Parcel size 51,883 51,925 35,871 29,446 37,592 35,383 45,431 43,734 45,410 41,312 43,489 43,869 Local housing market controls Number of 0.175 0.485 0.275 0.688 0.282 0.716 0.185 0.484 0.200 0.524 0.262 0.654 foreclosure sales (near, before) Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… 1 3 Low density High density New Old Low vacancy High vacancy Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Number of 0.142 0.426 0.249 0.638 0.255 0.665 0.146 0.421 0.179 0.487 0.227 0.592 foreclosure sales (near, after) Number of 0.480 1.009 0.695 1.291 0.669 1.346 0.565 1.089 0.587 1.073 0.645 1.235 foreclosure sales (far, before) Number of 0.467 0.966 0.709 1.276 0.688 1.321 0.553 1.049 0.590 1.045 0.644 1.217 foreclosure sales (far, after) Number of 0.112 0.133 0.126 0.123 0.123 0.132 foreclosures = 1 (near, before) Number of 0.023 0.036 0.039 0.023 0.027 0.036 foreclosures = 2 (near, before) Number of 0.005 0.019 0.021 0.005 0.007 0.017 foreclosures > 2 (near, before) Number of market 1.145 1.500 2.262 3.493 2.963 4.080 1.165 1.400 1.326 1.805 1.918 2.837 sales (near, before) Number of market 0.887 1.218 1.243 1.555 1.356 1.690 0.963 1.287 0.995 1.281 1.228 1.548 sales (near, after) G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Low density High density New Old Low vacancy High vacancy Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Number of market 3.102 3.144 4.839 5.796 5.540 6.598 3.497 3.374 3.591 3.636 4.150 4.643 sales (far, before) Number of market 2.674 2.857 3.059 2.834 2.955 2.947 3.070 3.144 2.924 2.740 3.036 3.000 sales (far, after) Number of new 0.117 0.866 1.326 3.883 2.123 4.522 0.012 0.127 0.272 1.532 0.748 2.915 construction (near, before) Number of new 0.131 0.797 1.999 5.981 3.067 6.829 0.038 0.298 0.458 2.536 1.029 4.257 construction (near, after) Number of new 0.091 0.785 0.621 2.011 1.049 2.427 0.007 0.096 0.136 0.925 0.367 1.451 construction (far, before) Number of new 0.114 0.751 1.006 2.978 1.622 3.450 0.029 0.274 0.264 1.488 0.567 2.044 construction (far, after) Number of obser- 10,284 10,983 9,361 9,999 9,216 11,282 vations Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… 1 3 Appendix 2: Descriptive statistics by neighborhood type (continued) Homogeneous in age Heterogeneous in age Homogeneous in living Homogeneous in living Gated Non-gated area area Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Property Price 153,791 106,952 301,148 206,164 219,248 153,210 281,933 239,797 368,293 232,058 208,646 150,832 CBD distance 6.174 3.202 10.87 4.241 8.803 4.154 9.742 4.390 11.6 2.657 8.472 4.260 Living area 1,527 503.3 2,439 873.1 1,977 781.4 2,242 972.2 2,849 794.8 1,884 741.7 Bedrooms 3.090 0.690 3.723 0.831 3.425 0.774 3.507 0.840 4.021 0.727 3.338 0.753 Baths 187.2 56.72 264.3 86.70 226.8 74.81 245.9 91.13 299.7 84.34 218.5 70.84 Walls concrete 0.287 0.822 0.617 0.667 0.981 0.565 Pool 0.212 0.231 0.248 0.320 0.451 0.229 Age 41.18 15.08 10.62 17.93 23.38 20.33 20.77 20.79 6.53  5.39 25.71  20.89 Parcel size 35,937 33,550 43,267 45,253 36,581 33,106 49,141 55,508 52,986 48,884 37,594 37,084 Local housing market controls Number of fore- 0.241 0.565 0.166 0.528 0.287 0.667 0.158 0.466 0.230 0.605 0.236 0.593 closure sales (near, before) Number of fore- 0.200 0.496 0.155 0.498 0.259 0.605 0.142 0.429 0.211 0.591 0.204 0.534 closure sales (near, after) G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Homogeneous in age Heterogeneous in age Homogeneous in living Homogeneous in living Gated Non-gated area area Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Number of fore- 0.712 1.213 0.450 1.036 0.708 1.275 0.459 0.939 0.584 1.174 0.634 1.185 closure sales (far, before) Number of fore- 0.698 1.166 0.470 1.030 0.736 1.233 0.453 0.924 0.604 1.172 0.632 1.139 closure sales (far, after) Number of 0.146 0.088 0.148 0.102 0.125 0.132 foreclosures = 1 (near, before) Number of 0.033 0.021 0.040 0.018 0.028 0.032 foreclosures = 2 (near, before) Number of 0.009 0.010 0.017 0.006 0.015 0.012 foreclosures > 2 (near, before) Number of mar- 1.341 1.460 2.644 4.041 1.674 2.043 1.284 2.327 1.870 2.871 1.587 2.388 ket sales (near, before) Number of mar- 1.121 1.340 1.120 1.587 1.303 1.498 0.834 1.243 1.131 1.419 1.089 1.408 ket sales (near, after) Number of mar- 3.989 3.464 4.810 6.402 4.012 3.637 3.144 4.128 4.027 4.526 3.894 4.342 ket sales (far, before) Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… 1 3 Homogeneous in age Heterogeneous in age Homogeneous in living Homogeneous in living Gated Non-gated area area Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Number of mar- 3.546 3.231 2.491 2.690 3.400 3.110 2.290 2.450 2.757 2.635 3.012 2.959 ket sales (far, after) Number of new 0.003 0.057 2.108 4.477 0.237 1.588 0.563 2.476 0.913 2.979 0.470 2.299 construction (near, before) Number of new 0.028 0.308 2.870 6.610 0.339 1.934 0.840 3.674 1.407 4.248 0.690 3.512 construction (near, after) Number of new 0.003 0.072 1.088 2.501 0.156 1.088 0.259 1.292 0.474 1.653 0.235 1.249 construction (far, before) Number of new 0.019 0.196 1.619 3.489 0.251 1.483 0.414 1.767 0.806 2.476 0.371 1.761 construction (far, after) Number of obser- 9,719 9,522 10,103 9,855 6,445 33,468 vations G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist Acknowledgements We gratefully acknowledge the Orange County, Florida residential tax assessment office for assistance in obtaining data. Thanks also to Fokke Dijkstra, Centre for Information Technol- ogy, University of Groningen, for computational assistance. We are grateful to seminar participants at the North American Regional Science Conference, KTH Sweden, and the University of Connecticut, USA, for comments on earlier versions of this work. The authors are responsible for any errors. Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Com- mons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http:// creat iveco mmons. org/ licen ses/ by/4. 0/. References Anas A, Arnott R, Small K (1998) Urban spatial structure. Journal of Economic Literature 36:1426–1464 Anenberg E, Kung E (2014) Estimates of the size and source of price declines due to nearby foreclosures. Am Econ Rev 104:2527–2551 Campbell J, Giglio S, Pathak P (2011) Forced sales and house prices. Am Econ Rev 101:2108–2131 Cheung R, Cunningham C, Meltzer R (2014) Do homeowners associations mitigate or aggravate negative spillovers from neighboring homeowner distress? J Hous Econ 24:75–88 Chinloy P, Hardin W, Zhnonghua W (2017) Foreclosure, REO, and market sales in residential real estate. J Real Estate Financ Econ 54:188–215 Clauretie T, Daneshvary N (2009) Estimating the house foreclosure discount corrected for spatial price interdependence and endogeneity of marketing time. Real Estate Econ 37:43–67 Coulson NE, Morris AC, Neil HR (2019) Are new homes special? Real Estate Econ 47:784–806 Daneshvary N, Clauretie TM (2012) Toxic neighbors: foreclosures and short-sales spillover effects from the current housing-market crash. Econ Inq 50:217–231 Daneshvary N, Clauretie TM, Kader A (2011) Short-term own-price and spillover effects of distressed residential properties: the case of a housing crash. J Real Estate Res 33:179–207 Davis L (2004) The effect of health risk on house values: evidence from a cancer cluster. Am Econ Rev 94:1693–1704 Ellen IG, O’Regan K (2010) Welcome to the neighborhood: how can regional science contribute to the study of neighborhoods? J Reg Sci 50:363–379 Fisher L, Lambie L, Willen P (2015) The role of proximity in foreclosure externalities: evidence from condominiums. Am Econ J Econ Policy 7:119–140 Gerardi K, Rosenblatt E, Willen P, Yao V (2015) Foreclosure externalities: new evidence. J Urban Econ 87:42–56 Gonzalez-Pampillon N (2022) Spillover effects from new housing supply. Reg Sci Urban Econ 92:103759 Hanson A, Schnier K, Turnbull GK (2012) Drive ‘til you qualify: credit quality and household location. Reg Sci Urban Econ 42:63–77 Harding JP, Rosenblatt E, Yao VW (2009) The contagion effect of foreclosed properties. J Urban Econ 66:167–178 Harding JP, Rosenblatt E, Yao VW (2012) The foreclosure discount: myth or reality. J Urban Econ 71:204–218 Hartley D (2014) The effect of foreclosures on nearby housing prices: supply or dis-amenity? Reg Sci Urban Econ 49:108–117 Hawley ZB, Turnbull GK (2019) Social interaction and urban household location. J Real Estate Financ Econ 59:1–26 Helms A (2012) Keeping up with the Joneses: neighborhood effects in housing renovation. Reg Sci Urban Econ 42:303–313 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… Ihlanfeldt K, Mayock T (2012) Information, search, and house prices: revisited. J Real Estate Financ Econ 44:90–115 Ihlanfeldt K, Mayock T (2016) The variance in foreclosure spillovers across neighborhood types. Public Financ Rev 44:80–108 Immergluck D, Smith G (2006) The external costs of foreclosure: the impact of single-family mortgage foreclosures on property values. Hous Policy Debate 17:57–79 Ioannides Y (2002) Residential neighborhood effects. Reg Sci Urban Econ 32:145–165 Ioannides Y (2011) Neighborhood effects and housing. In: Benhabib J, Bisin A, Jackson M (eds) Hand- book of social economics, vol 1. Chapter 25, pp 1281–1340 Krainer J (2001) A theory of liquidity in residential real estate markets. J Urban Econ 49:32–53 Lin Z, Rosenblatt E, Yao V (2009) Spillover effects of foreclosures on neighborhood property values. J Real Estate Financ Econ 38:387–407 Linden L, Rockoff J (2008) Estimates of the impact of crime risk on property values from Megan’s laws. Am Econ Rev 98:1103–1127 Manski C (1993) Identification of endogenous social effects: the reflection problem. Rev Econ Stud 60:531–542 Mian A, Sufi A, Trebbi F (2015) Foreclosures, house prices, and the real economy. J Financ 70:2587–2633 Nedovic-Budic Z, Knaap G, Shahumyan H, Williams B, Slaev A (2016) Measuring urban form at com- munity scale: case study of Dublin, Ireland. Cities 55:148–164 OCPA (2017) Annual reports. 2010–2014. Orange County Property Appraisers, Florida Rogers W, Winter W (2009) The impact of foreclosures on neighboring housing sales. J Real Estate Res 31:455–479 Rosenthal S (2008) Homes, externalities and poor neighborhoods. J Urban Econ 63:816–840 Ross S (2011) Social interactions within cities: neighborhood environments and peer relationships. In: Brooks N, Donaphy K, Knaap G (eds) The oxford handbook of urban economics and planning. Oxford Publishers, Oxford Rossi-Hansberg E, Sarte P, Owens R (2010) Housing externalities. J Polit Econ 188:485–535 Schuetz J, Been V, Ellen I (2008) Neighborhood effects of concentrated mortgage foreclosures. J Hous Econ 17:306–319 Song Y, Knaap G (2003) New urbanism and housing values: a disaggregate assessment. J Urban Econ 54:218–238 Song Y, Knaap G (2004) Measuring the effects of mixed land uses on housing values. Reg Sci Urban Econ 34:663–680 Song Y, Knaap G (2007) Quantitative classification of neighbourhoods: the neighbourhoods of new sin- gle-family homes in the Portland metropolitan area. J Urban Des 12:1–24 Towe C, Lawley C (2013) The contagion effect of neighboring foreclosures. Am Econ J Econ Pol 5:313–335 Turnbull GK, Zahirovic-Herbert V (2011) Why do vacant houses sell for less: bargaining power, holding cost or stigma? Real Estate Econ 39:19–43 Turnbull GK, Zahirovic-Herbert V, Mothorpe C (2013) Flooding and liquidity on the bayou: the capitali- zation of flood risk into house value and ease-of-sale. Real Estate Econ 41:103–129 Turnbull GK, van der Vlist AJ (2023) After the boom: transitory and legacy effects of foreclosures. J Real Estate Financ Econ 66:422–442. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1007/ s11146- 021- 09882-w Whitehand J (1992) Recent advances in urban morphology. Urban Stud 29:619–636 Zahirovic-Herbert V, Gibler KM (2014) The effect of new residential construction on housing prices. J Hous Econ 26:1–18 Zhang L, Leonard T (2014) Neighborhood impact of foreclosure: a quantile regression. Reg Sci Urban Econ 48:133–143 Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. 1 3 http://www.deepdyve.com/assets/images/DeepDyve-Logo-lg.png The Annals of Regional Science Springer Journals

Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood configuration matter?

Loading next page...
 
/lp/springer-journals/foreclosures-and-housing-prices-does-neighborhood-configuration-matter-0G0XFcYOXC

References (88)

Publisher
Springer Journals
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2023
ISSN
0570-1864
eISSN
1432-0592
DOI
10.1007/s00168-023-01206-5
Publisher site
See Article on Publisher Site

Abstract

This paper measures the extent to which effects of foreclosures vary across neighbor - hoods. It offers a simple empirical framework for decomposing the spillover effects on neighboring property prices. Data from Orange County, Florida, reveal that the effects systematically vary across neighborhoods by morphology. The results indi- cate that older, homogeneous age structure, and non-gated neighborhoods with high vacancy rates are most in jeopardy when foreclosures are present, as these neighbor- hoods show the greatest neighborhood house price effects. JEL Classification R31 1 Introduction Some neighborhoods in the USA were hit hard, but unevenly, by foreclosures in the aftermath of the 2008 housing market crash. The prevailing view has been that the uneven distribution of foreclosures is largely responsible for the uneven price effects observed across neighborhoods, as greater concentrations of foreclosures increase marginal price effects of additional foreclosures. But this perspective ignores the possibility that foreclosure price effects on surrounding properties may depend not only on the localized concentration of foreclosures, but also on the physical and Campbell et al. (2011) report for Massachusetts that 92 percent of the sellers do not observe foreclo- sures within one-tenth mile, while 81 percent within a quarter of a mile do not observe foreclosures dur- ing the year before sale. Data for Orange County, FL, the subject of this study, shows similar patterns. * Arno J. van der Vlist a.j.van.der.vlist@rug.nl Geoffrey K. Turnbull geoffrey.turnbull@ucf.edu Department of Finance. Dr. P. Phillips School of Real Estate, University of Central Florida, P.O. 161991, Orlando, FL 32816-1991, USA Real Estate Centre, Department of Economic Geography, University of Groningen, Postbox 800, 9700 AV Groningen, The Netherlands Vol.:(0123456789) 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist structural characteristics of neighborhoods. The nature of the built environment may matter; the age and uniformity of the neighborhood and the physical proximity to neglected or vacant foreclosed properties are determined by structural density and street configuration. The questions addressed here are straightforward: Does the sur - rounding built environment influence foreclosure price effects? And, if so, to what extent? Most reviews of empirical studies on foreclosure effects suggest that neighboring property prices tend to be anywhere between one to two percent lower in neighbor- hoods with foreclosures. The literature recognizes two mechanisms driving neigh- boring property prices lower. One is the negative foreclosure externality arising from poorly maintained or vacant foreclosed property. The second is the supply effect arising from the fact that foreclosures increase the supply of housing for sale (Anenberg and Kung 2014; Hartley 2014; Mian et  al. 2015; Gerardi et  al. 2015). Both mechanisms lead to lower neighborhood property values, the source of distress to residents and local governments. The prevailing focus on foreclosure externality and supply effects on prices of surrounding houses overlooks a possibly mediating influence within the neighbor - hood. For instance, supply of new construction provides positive physical externali- ties to the neighborhood (Ioannides 2002; Rosenthal 2008; Helms 2012; Zahirovic- Herbert and Gibler 2014; Coulson et  al. 2019; Gonzalez-Pampillon 2022). Buyers may interpret new construction as a signal of improved neighborhood quality, or the arrival of more affluent residents (Gonzalez-Pampillon 2022). In any case, new con- struction, whether rebuilding teardowns or new infill development, occurs unevenly in the interior of the urban area. We empirically control for differences in the sup- ply of new construction as a source of systematic variation in observed foreclosure price effects across neighborhoods. It is worth emphasizing at this point that the foreclosure externality argument itself also suggests possible variation in foreclosure effects across neighborhoods. The negative externality arises because foreclosures induce vacancy and underin- vestment in maintenance, creating negative physical externalities that reduce neigh- borhood attractiveness (Harding et al. 2009, 2012; Daneshvary and Clauretie 2012) For examples, see Clauretie and Daneshvary (2009), Lin et  al. (2009), Rogers and Winter (2009), Campbell et  al. (2011), Daneshvary and Clauretie (2012), Anenberg and Kung (2014), Gerardi et  al. (2015), Chinloy et al. (2017). The literature also refers to foreclosure externality as contagion effect (Harding et al. 2009) disamen- ity effect (Anenberg and Kung 2014), physical externality (Fisher et al. 2015) and investment externality (Cheung et al. 2014). The literature also refers to supply effect as competition effect (Anenberg and Kung 2014) or pecuniary externality (Gerardi et al. 2015). While it may seem odd to observe new construction in neighborhoods with foreclosures, the lead time required to obtain land, permits and complete new construction explains some of the new units being sold during the latest market downturn despite nearby foreclosures. Regardless, new construction contin- ued, although at a much lower rate, throughout the market crash and slow subsequent recovery in hard- hit Orange County, Florida, even in neighborhoods with foreclosures. For Orange County, Florida, new construction of single family residential homes dropped from 6,124 in 2007, to 2,039 in 2009, and 2,620 in 2012 (OCPA 2017). 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… as well as external social costs in the form of reduced social interaction and commu- nity involvement (Harding et  al. 2009) or increased crime (Immergluck and Smith 2006). Foreclosures may be the source of negative shopping externalities as well; potential buyers may interpret the presence of foreclosures as a signal of a greater risk of neighborhood instability or secular decline, which prompts them to focus their search efforts elsewhere. All of these factors reduce property values of sur - rounding non-distressed property. Not all neighborhoods, however, are equally vul- nerable to these risks (Anenberg and Kung 2014; Ihlanfeldt and Mayock 2016). This study focuses on how foreclosure price effects vary by neighborhood configuration. To do so, we use geocoded administrative data to allow more explicit models of how foreclosure effects vary across neighborhoods. This paper makes two contributions to the empirical housing market literature. First, we propose a simple framework for sorting neighborhood property price effects into foreclosure externality, new construction externality, and supply or pecu- niary externality effects. Most previous work struggles with how to empirically sep- arate these externality and supply effects and so tends to avoid distinguishing them explicitly. Studies that do distinguish externality and supply effects use supply meas- ures that count numbers of foreclosures at greater distance (Harding et  al. 2009), nearby foreclosures of different property types (Hartley 2014; Fisher et  al. 2015), or precise timing of distressed and non-distressed properties listings (Anenberg and Kung 2014). It seems appropriate to identify supply effects using measures of com- peting or substitute properties that are on the market at the same time as the subject property. To that end, we incorporate measures of both foreclosed and similar open market (non-foreclosed) properties for sale in the surrounding neighborhood at the same time as the subject property. Second, we examine whether foreclosure price effects vary with neighborhood configuration. Foreclosure effects may vary across neighborhoods due to differ - ences in underlying economic vitality (Rosenthal 2008), housing market segmenta- tion (Gerardi et al. 2015; Cheung et al. 2014; Zhang and Leonard 2014) as well as the neighborhood structure (Schuetz et  al. 2008). Ellen and O’Regan (2010) argue that neighborhood configuration matters for market outcomes in general. Applying that notion to this case, a foreclosure may be more visible or physically closer to more surrounding properties in some neighborhoods than in other neighborhoods, and as a result, generate stronger price responses. To take these neighborhood differ - ences into account, we also investigate foreclosure effects across built environments in terms of their urban density, neighborhood mix of homes, development period, vacancy rate, and whether the subdivision is gated or non-gated. The geographic concentration of foreclosures in certain neighborhoods suggests that, for some neighborhood configurations, the foreclosure effect might be nonlin- ear in the number of foreclosures (e.g., in the case of rather uniform neighborhoods with many similar properties). If so, even a few neighboring foreclosures relative to non-distressed sales will have significant value effects on surrounding non-dis- tressed transactions. Hanson et al. (2012) show that households tend to spatially sort by credit quality, creating conditions ripe for geographic concentration of foreclo- sures. The question remains whether the resultant concentrations of foreclosures in certain neighborhoods lead to increasing marginal price effects, exhibiting deeper 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist and more enduring neighborhood price effects than would otherwise be expected if foreclosures were instead more evenly distributed across the market area. Schuetz et  al. (2008) and Harding et  al. (2009) both find no evidence of nonlinear foreclo- sure effects. In contrast with the samples used in those studies, our sample covers a period of intense foreclosure activity in one of the most active foreclosure markets in the US, which allows us to probe more deeply into how an unprecedented level of foreclosures affects property prices. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains the empiri- cal framework to sort out the channels through which foreclosures may influence surrounding property values. Section  3 describes the data. Section  4 reports the empirical results. We first report on foreclosure spillover effects and then consider whether these spillover effects vary with neighborhood configuration. Section  5 concludes. 2 Empirical framework The empirical framework maps local foreclosures, open market sales and new con- struction onto neighboring house prices. In estimating these local effects we face the following challenge. Neighborhood effects such as foreclosure externalities (Camp- bell et  al. 2011; Towe and Lawley 2013), crime risk (Linden and Rockoff 2008) or externalities associated with new construction (Ioannides 2002; Helms 2012) may be associated with endogenous social effects (Manski 1993; Rossi-Hansberg et  al. 2010; Ross 2011; Ioannides 2011). These social effects arise when a house- hold’s foreclosure or new construction decision spillover to neighbors. Ideally, one would like to control for these effects using instrumental variables that are corre- lated with the local measure but not with price. We take the alternative approach used by Linden and Rockoff (2008) and Campbell et al. (2011), which relies on the impact of extremely local neighborhood measures and very small time windows, and compares the relevant coefficients pertaining to neighborhood measures before and after each property sale to control for the state of the local economy in the micro-neighborhood. We estimate separate localized externality effects of foreclosures, supply or pecu- niary externality effects, and new housing construction on other non-distressed property sales. We control for neighborhood market externalities by including Harding et al. (2009) proposed instruments such as mean loan originating credit score and mean loan originating loan-to-value at the neighborhood level. We applied the AHS data and, like Campbell et al. (2011), find no feasible instruments. In measuring neighborhood effects of housing renovation, Helms (2012) reports similar difficulty in alleviating the identification issue. Helms then proposes a spatial lag model in which all time-varying data are collapsed into one cross-section. Given the importance of timing in foreclosure effects, we follow Campbell et  al. (2011) by comparing the effect of foreclosures before and after each property sale. It is possible that we miss some of the neighborhood effects as major home improvements are not reg- istered consistently by our data source. While we do not have information on renovation, existing evi- dence implies that the positive externality effect of new construction is stronger than those from renova- tions (Helms 2012). 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… number of foreclosures, number of open market sales and, number of newly con- structed houses that are on the market at the same time as the subject property. The model we estimate specifies the log of price of house transaction i in neigh- borhood r and year t as a linear function of property characteristics and neighbor- hood market conditions: before before after after before before after after lnP =  X +  FS +  FS +  MS +  MS irt X it FS it FS it MS it MS it (1) before before after after +  NC +  NC +  +  +  , t r irt NC it NC it where P is the selling price; X the vector of house characteristics; FS the number irt it it of nearby foreclosures, MS the number of nearby open market sales, and NC is the it it number of nearby newly constructed houses, all within distance d and within time- frame τ before or after the subject property transaction. Equation (1) also includes location and (interaction) time fixed effects to reduce unobserved heterogeneity and omitted variable bias. Further,  is the error term clustered at the location fixed irt effects-level. Davis (2004) argues that using location fixed effects and clustered errors together also serves as nonparametric spatial correlation control. Cast this way, the FS, MS, and NC variables control for nearby foreclosed houses, open market (non-foreclosure) houses, and new construction in the neighborhood at the same time the subject property is for sale. The timeframe windows before and after are included to capture other properties on the market at the same time as the subject property, some of which sell before and some after the subject sells. The estimated coefficients for local market conditions variables provide important infor - mation regarding the extent of possible foreclosure and new construction externali- ties. FS captures the effect of foreclosures increasing the supply of existing houses on the market plus the negative foreclosure externality. MS captures the increasing supply associated with open (non-foreclosure) market sales of new construction and existing houses. The coefficient on the NC variable measures any externality associ- ated with new construction (holding the total supply of houses constant). These variables may include endogenous responses to neighborhood market con- ditions. Our identification strategy hinges on comparing short-run changes in values within very small areas arising from changes in the local or neighborhood housing market context. Following the procedure in Campbell et  al. (2011), the externality effect estimate is the difference between the coefficient for foreclosures before the subject property transaction and the coefficient for foreclosures after the transaction, before af ter [ −  ] . The standard error of the estimate can be calculated using the delta FS FS method. If foreclosure spillovers are present, then we should observe a negative impact as the largest negative impacts of foreclosure on property values are prior to the sale. The same identification strategy applies to the new construction and We use several location (zip code, census tract and census block group) and time fixed effect-levels (year, year-month). In the case of foreclosures, the lead window also picks up properties in the foreclosure process before they are formally put on the market. Harding et  al. (2009), Campbell et  al. (2011) and Gerardi et  al. (2015) note that what we identify as the foreclosure externality effect may begin early in the foreclosure process. 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist open market sales variables. To the extent that local economic shocks impact house prices, we include in one of the models also past and future foreclosures slightly farther away (between one-tenth and a quarter of a mile) as controls (Linden and Rockoff 2008; Campbell et al. 2011). Second, because foreclosures generate both negative externality and supply effects (or pecuniary externality), we follow Anenberg and Kung (2014) and Hartley (2014), and use the difference in estimates relative to market sales to remove the supply effects of foreclosures on price, which in our application reduces to before after before after Foreclosure externality = [ −  ]− [ −  ]. (2) FS FS MS MS The above calculation measures the combined effect of increasing nearby fore- closures by one, while decreasing the number of non-distressed properties on the market by one, to arrive at the net externality effect of an additional foreclosure. Finally, to the extent that new construction creates a positive spillover in the neighborhood, the difference in the before and after coefficient estimates for the new construction variables should reflect the new construction externality: before after New construction externality = [ −  ]. (3) NC NC In this case, there is no need to remove a supply effect because the number of non-distressed properties for sale (which includes new houses) is already being cap- tured by the market sales variables (which includes new houses). The estimated new construction effect reflects the effect of increasing the number of new houses for sale by one, while simultaneously decreasing the number of existing houses for sale by one. If the (negative) FS coefficient is algebraically less than the MS coefficient, then increasing the number of foreclosures while holding neighborhood supply constant reduces the prices of surrounding properties. This result is consistent with a negative real externality effect from neighboring foreclosures. If, on the other hand, the FS and MS coefficients are not significantly different, neighboring foreclosures have no real externality effect on surrounding properties. Finally, if the (negative) MS coeffi- cient is less than the FS coefficient, then increasing the number of foreclosures while holding neighborhood market supply constant increases the prices of surrounding properties. Although it may seem counter-intuitive at first blush, this outcome is nonetheless consistent with foreclosed properties generating a stronger shopping externality for the neighborhood than open market properties. In this case, the pres- ence of nearby foreclosures for sale is a stronger draw for potential buyers than open market properties; the resultant increases in buyer arrival rates increase the prob- abilities of higher priced matches for nearby sellers, including sellers of open market properties. It is important to remember that the coefficients on the new construction variables (NC) do not capture supply effects and instead solely pick up the neighbor - hood quality signaling or the housing investment externality effect arising from new construction. This assumes foreclosures and market sales have identical supply effects on the subject property price. 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… To provide evidence on the extent of variation in foreclosure effects by neigh- borhood configuration, we estimate separate models by the built structure of the neighborhood. The neighborhood configuration is often defined in terms of streets, lots, and buildings. Along with physical elements, the social aspects of urban mor- phology have also been deemed important (Nedovic-Budic et  al. 2016). We sum- marize neighborhood configuration using a set of simple dimensions of urban form: urban density, neighborhood mix of homes, development period, vacancy rate, and whether the property is in a gated or non-gated neighborhood subdivision. 3 Data The data are drawn from property assessment records of Orange County, Florida, covering all of the 426,021 parcels in the county as of August 24, 2012. Orange County is part of the Orlando-Kissimmee-Sanford Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA), and has been experiencing long-term population growth from 896,344 (2000 Census) to 1,145,956 (2010 Census). Orange County is an interesting case study to explore whether foreclosure price effects vary across neighborhoods. Orange County is one of the epicenters of the foreclosure crisis. While so, foreclo- sures were not evenly distributed across neighborhoods. We focus on how foreclo- sure price effects vary by neighborhood configuration. Local assessor records in Florida have been used as the primary data source in a number of studies and have several advantages (Ihlanfeldt and Mayock 2012; Turn- bull and Van der Vlist 2023). One advantage of local assessor records over multiple listing service (MLS) data for broker-assisted transactions is that tax records pro- vide information on the entire stock of existing properties, not just those that sell. Another is that MLS data do not cover all public transactions and, most important for the question addressed here, likely underreport foreclosure transactions (Danesh- vary and Clauretie 2012; Chinloy et al. 2017)—which may be critically important in this sample, as increasing numbers of foreclosed properties in Orange County were sold directly to investment firms and other organized investors without first being offered to individual buyers through traditional channels like the MLS. Conversely, a disadvantage of tax assessment records is that they provide no direct information about liquidity or time-on-the market for sold properties (although most existing foreclosure studies using MLS data also have not exploited liquidity data). Krainer (2001) shows that changes in buyer willingness-to-pay is reflected in both selling price and liquidity in search markets; recent empirical studies provide evidence of price-liquidity capitalization for both individual property and neighbor- hood characteristics (Turnbull et  al. 2013; Turnbull and Zahirovic-Herbert 2011). Therefore, the absence of marketing time measures in this study means that the price effects of foreclosures identified here, as well as in most of the foreclosure literature, may reflect only one dimension of the possible capitalization effects. Measuring urban form remains an important topic in the field of urban studies, as we refer to White- hand (1992), Anas et al. (1998), Song and Knaap (2003; 2004; 2007), and Nedovic-Budic et al. (2016). 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist The tax records yield detailed information on property characteristics as well as addresses, transaction prices, transaction dates, and deed types (which allows us to identify foreclosed properties). We focus on built-up areas of the county, exclud- ing the sparsely settled northwestern and eastern parts of the jurisdiction. The sin- gle family detached house (SFD) data cover 266,897 separate properties during the sample period of January 2007 through August 2012. The data include transaction price, transaction date, and deed type. The struc- ture of the data source allows us to observe the transaction history over 2007-to mid-2012. This sample period captures the declining market over 2008–2010 and the weak recovery starting in early 2012. The dependent variable is the transaction price. The control variables measure property characteristics and location and time fixed effects. The analysis focuses on single family detached houses (SFD). Living area indicates the square feet of air-conditioned/heated area. Other property charac- teristics include number of bedrooms and bathrooms, presence of a private swim- ming pool, house age, and type of exterior walls. Total land acreage is the measure of parcel size and encompasses both upland and any submerged area lying within the parcel legal boundary. The data allow us to construct GIS-based neighborhood housing market conditions indicators based on the number of FS, MS, and NC in the neighborhood within distance d (one-tenth, a quarter of a mile) taking place within time frame τ before and after transaction time t (90, 180 days) of each subject property. We define neighborhood configuration using a set of simple dimensions of urban form. First, we measure urban density, development period, and vacancy at the neighborhood census blockgroup-level, using the 2000 American Community Sur- vey (ACS). Next, at a more granular level, we measure neighborhood mix of homes (variation in development period, and size of living area) at the census block-level, using the administrative parcel-level data for the year 2000. Last, we identify for each transaction whether a property lies within a private gated or publicly acces- sible non-gated subdivision, using administrative information on subdivisions. We use these measures to examine how foreclosure effects vary with neighborhood configuration. The sample consists of  open market transactions transferring warranty deeds, and excludes all legal administrator’s deed, tax deed, and quit claim deeds (all for administrative non-arm’s length transaction purposes), including all transactions for $100, the usual indicator of a non-market transfer of property interest. Following Daneshvary et al. (2011), we trim the lower and upper 1 percent of the distribution of price and living area to control for outliers. Furthermore, we define the maximum spatial extent of the surrounding neighborhood for each property as one mile, so We use deed information to identify foreclosed properties as follows: Florida is a judicial foreclosure state which means that the clerk of court must file a Certificate of Title after a foreclosure auction takes place. The Certificate of Title instrument allows lenders to take back their properties and subsequently sell it either through auction or listing. We use Certificate of Titles to identify (the flow of new) foreclo- sures. A Warranty deed instrument refers to open market sales. New construction refers to open market sales of new properties (for a discussion, see Turnbull and Van der Vlist 2023). Note that membership of a subdivision association is mandatory in the case of a gated subdivision. 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… while observations within one mile of the county boundary are used to construct instruments for total number of properties, foreclosed sales, market sales, and new construction, they are not otherwise included in the price equation sample. Simi- larly, observations in the first six-month time frame are excluded from the model estimation to construct the proper burn-in period for our instruments. The number of observations in the sample for estimating the price equation is 39,913 open market transactions. Variable definitions are given in Appendix 1. Table  1 reports the descriptive statistics. The table indicates a mean price of almost $235,000 and a median of $185,000, thus reflecting a distribution skewed to the right. We therefore use the natural logarithm of transaction price in the empirical analysis. Structural property characteristics indicate the type of building construc- tion material (63% have walls made of stucco covered concrete block versus wood frame construction), number of bedrooms (3.45 average), living area (2,040 square feet average), number of bathrooms (2.32 average), presence of a private pool (27%), lot size (40,079 square feet average), and actual age of the house (22.6 years). Loca- tion controls include the (quadratic) distance to the Orlando CBD (8.98 miles linear distance average) and zip code fixed effects. Over 70 percent of the transactions lie within the City of Orlando, the largest and most populous municipality in Orange County. A further decomposition of descriptive statistics by neighborhood configuration is found in Appendix 2. The descriptive statistics report some structural differences in average property characteristics across type of neighborhood. Low density neigh- borhoods have lower mean house prices ($206,809) than high density neighbor- hoods ($281,254). Also, older neighborhoods (in terms of mean building age) have lower mean house prices ($165,234) relative to newer neighborhoods ($311,275). The typical property in these older neighborhoods is smaller in terms of living area, and of less quality in terms of construction materials, but they generally have larger parcels. Note further that house prices are higher in neighborhoods with more het- erogeneous housing stock measured in terms of property age or property size. The lower panel of Table 1 provides summary statistics for the constructed vari- ables measuring neighborhood market conditions including the number of fore- closures (FS), the number of market transactions (MS), and the number of newly constructed properties (NC). The data reveal that a large majority of sales occur in areas with no surrounding foreclosures. This is consistent with Campbell et  al. (2011) although the overall incidence of foreclosures in Orange County is greater. In total, 82.6 percent of sellers do not have any foreclosure within one-tenth mile and 180 days. Multiple nearby foreclosures are even less frequent. The data reveal that 95.7 percent of the sellers do not observe two or more foreclosures, while 98.8 The original data cover 54,553 open market sales of which 7,542 are administrative warranty deeds with a price of $100 which we remove from the sample. We then trim the lower and upper 1% of living area (removing 581 observations), transaction price (removing 91 observations), and properties whose construction date is listed as occurring after the transaction date (removing 604 observations). We also lose 5,802 observations for the burn-in space and time period when constructing the FS, MS, and NC variables. The resultant data set has 39,913 observations. 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist percent of the sellers do not observe three or more foreclosures, all within one-tenth mile and 180 days. The mean number of nearby foreclosures is 0.235 but varies across neighbor- hood types. Likewise, one observes differences in the number of market sales and in the number of newly constructed properties. Looking at the number of newly con- structed properties within the indicated geographic area and time frame, the aver- age new construction (0.542 for the pooled sample) varies between 0.117 and 4.522 across neighborhood types. These transactions can be interpreted relative to the den- sity or mean total property which varies across neighborhood types between 19.59 and 36.76. Overall, the FS, MS, and NC measures all show substantial variation across neighborhood configuration. 4 Empirical results 4.1 Foreclosure spillover effects Table  2 reports the results for the pooled models of Eq.  (1). The models indicate joint significance of the specification. The estimates for the structural characteristics of the property are as expected. Property value decreases with distance to the CBD and the effect becomes less pronounced at greater distances. House structure quality and exterior construction matter. Concrete block construction covered with stucco exhibits higher market value relative to wood frame construction. In addition, larger houses in terms of number of bedrooms, living area and number of bathrooms are associated with higher property values. A pool has a significant positive effect on property value in this market, as does parcel size. The lower panel in Table  2 reports associated estimates for the price effects of surrounding foreclosures on property prices based on Eqs.  (2) and (3). The esti- mates reveal that foreclosures within one-tenth mile and 180 days before the sale of a given subject property have significant negative effects on surrounding open mar - ket sales. The marginal effect of a foreclosure before a sale is significantly stronger than the coefficient of a foreclosure after a sale, a result consistent with Campbell et al. (2011). Note that sales of some properties occurring after the subject property sells are also on the market before the subject sells. Also observe that the foreclosure coefficient is stronger than the coefficient on open market or non-distressed sales, which implies that the negative foreclosure externality effect dominates its associ- ated supply effect. In our model 1, the foreclosure externality effect calculated using Eq. (2) is − 0.0152 with a standard error of 0.005 and is significant at the 1 percent For a wider time window of 360 days before sale, the statistic is 72.27 percent within 1/10 mile. For multiple foreclosures the statistic is 89.54 percent within 1/10 mile for two or more foreclosures, or 95.70 percent for three or more. We also test whether these effects are driven by structural density using auxiliary regressions that con- trol for total number of properties within one tenth of a mile. These results confirm that our effects are not driven by density. 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… Table 1 Descriptive statistics Mean St. dev Property controls Price 234,425 176,698 CBD distance (miles) 8.979 4.207 Walls concrete stucco (1 = yes) 0.632 Number of bedrooms 3.448 0.790 Living area (in sq. ft.) 2,040 830.2 Age of property (in years) 22.61 20.50 Number of bathrooms 231.6 79.05 Pool (1 = yes) 0.265 Parcel size (in sq. ft.) 40,079 39,637 Neighborhood configuration Low density 0.258 High density 0.274 Low vacancy 0.231 High vacancy 0.283 Old neighborhood 0.251 New neighborhood 0.235 Homogeneous in age SFD 0.244 Homogeneous in age SFD 0.239 Heterogeneous in living area SFD 0.253 Homogeneous in living area SFD 0.247 Local housing market controls Number of foreclosure sales (near, before) 0.235 0.595 Number of foreclosure sales (near, after) 0.205 0.543 Number of foreclosure sales (far, before) 0.626 1.183 Number of foreclosure sales (far, after) 0.628 1.144 Number of foreclosure sales = 1 (near, before) 0.131 Number of foreclosure sales = 2 (near, before) 0.031 Number of foreclosure sales > 2 (near, before) 0.012 Number of market sales (near, before) 1.633 2.474 Number of market sales (near, after) 1.096 1.410 Number of market sales (far, before) 3.915 4.373 Number of market sales (far, after) 2.971 2.910 Number of new construction (near, before) 0.542 2.428 Number of new construction (near, after) 0.806 3.650 Number of new construction (far, before) 0.273 1.325 Number of new construction (far, after) 0.441 1.902 See Appendix 1 for variable definitions. N is 39,913 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist Table 2 Estimation results pooled model (1) (2) Coefficient Std. error Coefficient Std. error Property controls CBD distance (miles) − 0.0279 *** (0.0079) − 0.0276 *** (0.0078) CBD distance squared 0.0013 *** (0.0003) 0.0013 *** (0.0003) Walls concrete stucco 0.0692 *** (0.0062) 0.0672 *** (0.0061) Number of bedrooms less than 3 − 0.0274 *** (0.0103) − 0.0256 ** (0.0104) Number of bedrooms more than 3 − 0.0233 *** (0.0052) − 0.0233 *** (0.0052) Log living area 0.6620 *** (0.0121) 0.6670 *** (0.0121) Log age − 0.0457 *** (0.0024) − 0.0475 *** (0.0024) Number of bathrooms is 1 − 0.1630 *** (0.0116) − 0.1620 *** (0.0116) Number of bathrooms is 1.50 − 0.1320 *** (0.0152) − 0.1310 *** (0.0149) Number of bathrooms is 2.50 0.0058 (0.0058) 0.0069 (0.0059) Number of bathrooms more than 2.5 0.0689 *** (0.0071) 0.0691 *** (0.0071) Pool 0.1290 *** (0.0047) 0.1280 *** (0.0047) Log parcel size 0.3160 *** (0.0066) 0.3120 *** (0.0065) Local housing market controls Number of foreclosure sales (near, before) − 0.0206 *** (0.0032) − 0.0143 *** (0.0030) Number of foreclosure sales (near, after) − 0.0042 (0.0033) 0.0007 (0.0033) Number of foreclosure sales (far, before) − 0.0183 *** (0.0022) Number of foreclosure sales (far, after) − 0.0051 *** (0.0017) Number of market sales (near, before) − 0.0013 (0.0012) − 0.0019 * (0.0012) Number of market sales (near, after) − 0.00002 (0.0015) 0.0004 (0.0015) Number of market sales (far, before) 0.0034 *** (0.0007) Number of market sales (far, after) 0.0004 (0.0009) Number of new construction (near, before) − 0.0076 *** (0.0013) − 0.0029 ** (0.0014) Number of new construction (near, after) − 0.0122 *** (0.0016) − 0.0084 *** (0.0015) Number of new construction (far, before) − 0.0061 *** (0.0009) Number of new construction (far, after) − 0.0071 *** (0.0013) Number of observations 39,913 39,913 R-squared 0.807 0.808 Spillover effects Foreclosure externality − 0.0152 *** (0.0049) − 0.0127 *** (0.0048) New construction externality 0.0046 ** (0.0019) 0.0054 *** (0.0019) The dependent variable is log transaction value. The reference category include Number of Bedrooms equals 3, Number of Bathrooms equals 2.00. All models include location fixed effects for ZIP code, and time fixed effects for year and quarter. Clustered standard errors at Census block level are in parentheses with ***, **, * indicating significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Spillover effects are determined using Eqs. (2) and (3) with implied standard errors using delta method. N is 39,913 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… level. For model 2, where we control for local housing market conditions by add- ing local housing market measures of number of foreclosure sales, market sales, and new construction within one-tenth and a quarter of a mile, the foreclosure effect on surrounding property remains economically significant and, not surprisingly, nega- tive. Note further that the foreclosure externality effect within one-tenth and one quarter of a mile (denoted with ‘far’) is − 0.0162 and statistically not significantly different from the obtained foreclosure externality effect nearby. The new construction coefficient before a sale relative to the coefficient after a sale indicates that new construction has a positive externality effect on neighbor - hood housing. This finding is consistent with the notion that potential buyers regard new construction as a positive signal of neighborhood stability or growth (Ioannides 2002; Helms 2012; Zahirovic-Herbert and Gibler 2014; Gonzalez-Pampillon 2022) or that new construction generates positive shopping externalities for surrounding existing properties. The associated new construction externality effect calculated using Eq. (3) is 0.005, with a standard error of 0.002 and is significant at the 2 per - cent significance level. It is interesting to compare the negative foreclosure externality and the positive new construction externality in detail. Our estimates indicate that the negative exter- nality effect of a foreclosure outweighs the positive externality effect of new con- struction. A linear test on equality of the parameters of Eqs.  (2) and (3) gives an F value of 14.0 and is beyond the critical value at the 1 percent significance level. Hence, while new construction provides a positive signal to the neighborhood, the marginal effect of the (negative) foreclosure externality dominates. Table  3 reports key estimates for various location and time (interaction) fixed effects. Pulling these results together we find foreclosure externality effects any - where between − 0.0156 and − 0.0096. These estimates are similar to our main results. For new construction externality effects we find estimates between 0.001 and 0.0055, which for some fixed effects specifications are not significantly different from zero. 4.2 F oreclosure spillover effects and neighborhood configuration We turn now to the variation in foreclosure effect by neighborhood configuration. What we have obtained thus far is an average effect of foreclosure on property prices. But we have argued that foreclosure effects may vary across neighborhoods. We probe more deeply into urban morphology and how foreclosure effects vary with a set of simple dimensions of urban structure, viz. urban density, neighborhood mix The foreclosure externality calculated using (2) equals ((− 0.0206–− 0.0042)—(− 0.0013–0.00002)) or − 0.0152. The foreclosure externality calculated using (2) equals ((− 0.0143—0.0007)—(− 0.0019–0.0004)) or − 0.0127. The foreclosure externality far calculated using (2) equals ((− 0.0183–0.0051)—(0.0034–0.0004)) or − 0.0163. The F-test on equal foreclosure externality effects near equals far yields a statistic of 0.48 and does not favor the alternative hypothesis of unequal foreclosure effects. 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Table 3 Summary of results for models with varying fixed effects (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Local housing market controls Number of foreclo- − 0.0213 *** − 0.0214 *** − 0.0135 *** − 0.0125 *** − 0.0202 *** − 0.0099 *** − 0.0082 ** sure sales (near, (0.0038) (0.0035) (0.0029) (0.0032) (0.0034) (0.0029) (0.0036) before) Number of foreclo- − 0.0057 * − 0.0063 * 0.0007 0.0014 − 0.0066 ** 6.50e-05 − 0.0012 sure sales (near, (0.0031) (0.0032) (0.0036) (0.0043) (0.0032) (0.0036) (0.0044) after) Number of market − 0.0014 − 0.0008 0.0006 0.0011 − 0.0014 − 0.0004 0.0004 sales (near, (0.0022) (0.0017) (0.0014) (0.0017) (0.0015) (0.0012) (0.0015) before) Number of market 0.0011 0.0009 0.00071 − 0.0006 0.0001 − 0.0005 − 0.0022 sales (near, after) (0.0023) (0.0019) (0.0016) (0.0021) (0.0017) (0.0015) (0.0020) Number of new − 0.0070 *** − 0.0076 *** − 0.0052 *** − 0.0062 *** − 0.0064 *** − 0.0035 ** − 0.0046 ** construction (near, (0.0024) (0.0022) (0.0019) (0.0022) (0.0018) (0.0016) (0.0019) before) Number of new − 0.0121 *** − 0.0127 *** − 0.0108 *** − 0.0085 *** − 0.0111 *** − 0.0086 *** − 0.0056 *** construction (near, (0.0036) (0.0035) (0.0031) (0.0032) (0.0033) (0.0027) (0.0027) after) Fixed effect Zip + Year Tract + Year Tract × Year Tract × Month-Year Block group + Year Block group Block group × Month- × Year Year Observations 39,913 39,913 39,913 39,913 39,913 39,913 39,913 R-squared 0.804 0.810 0.837 0.88 0.816 0.849 0.915 Spillover effects Foreclosure exter- − 0.0131 *** − 0.0134 *** − 0.0139 *** − 0.0156 *** − 0.0121 ** − 0.0101 ** − 0.0096 * nality (0.0050) (0.0057) (0.0052) (0.0060) (0.0050) (0.0048) (0.0054) New construction 0.0050 0.0051 0.0055 * 0.0023 0.0047 0.0051 * 0.0010 externality (0.0051) (0.0033) (0.0030) (0.0031) (0.0030) (0.0030) (0.0029) The dependent variable is log transaction value. The reference category include Number of Bedrooms equals 3, Number of Bathrooms equals 2.00. Clustered standard errors at respective location fixed effect-level are in parentheses with ***, **, * indicating significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Spillover effects are determined using Eqs. (2) and (3) with implied standard errors using delta method. N is 39,913 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… of homes, and development period, vacancy rate, and whether the property is in a gated or non-gated neighborhood subdivision. First we consider urban density based on the premise that foreclosures in low density neighborhoods may have stronger price effects because they are more vis- ible than in high density neighborhoods. We test for this effect by examining fore- closure price effects for subsamples partitioned by density. We partition the data into low density and high density and re-estimate the basic model on the resultant subsamples. In order to probe more deeply into how foreclosures may depend more subtly on the neighborhood mix, we use a variety of ways to measure differences between neighborhoods. One way to control for type of neighborhood is to segment by mean vacancy rate (low and high vacancy rates ) or mean age of the neighborhood (new and old neighborhoods ). We use these measures of between-neighborhood vari- ation to identify the extent to which differences in the foreclosure externality arise across neighborhoods. Table 4 reports the key estimates. Looking at the results summarized in Table 4, the point estimates of the foreclo- sure externality effect, as measured by the difference in before and after FS and MS coefficients, indicate a somewhat stronger impact in the lowest density neighbor - hoods. The implied pattern of the foreclosure signaling/density relationship is con- sistent with that suggested by Schuetz et al. (2008). Another way to control for type of neighborhood is to use the coefficient of var - iation to measure within-neighborhood variation in terms of age or size of house (homogeneous versus heterogeneous neighborhoods ). Overall, the results indicate strongest effects for homogeneous neighborhoods, both in terms of age or size of the housing units. We interpret this as strong evidence of a signaling effect of neigh- borhood stability. The estimates suggest two factors at work. First, the foreclosure externality varies with the physical structure of the neighborhood as measured by density and (variation in) age and size of houses. Second, the foreclosure external- ity varies with the specific neighborhood housing market conditions as measured by vacancy rate. We next turn to the possibility that the main effect of foreclosures on prices might be nonlinear. Figure 1 depicts the structure by mapping the parameter estimates for the various neighborhood types. These results are based on models that employ a set of foreclosure dummy variables as a flexible structure to capture any nonlinear effects associated with the number of foreclosures. The effects are consistent with Low and high density refers to p(25) and p(75) of the probability density function of number of units per census block group, or 1117 and 3613 units, respectively. Low and high vacancy refers to p(25) and p(75) of the probability density function of vacancy rate per census block group, or 8.5 and 17.4) percent, respectively. New and old neighborhood refers to p(25) and p(75) of the probability density function of age per census block group, or 6 and 36 years, respectively. Homogeneity and heterogeneity are based on the within census-block neighborhood coefficient of var - iation of, for example, age or size of house. Homogeneity refers to a low coefficient of variation (p(25) of the probability density function across all neighborhoods), whereas heterogeneity refers to a high coef- ficient of variation (p(75) of the probability density function across all neighborhoods). 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist the basic models examined earlier. There appears to be a cumulative negative real externality from additional foreclosures varying by neighborhood configuration. Summarizing the results, we find that older, homogeneous neighborhoods with high vacancy rates are most in jeopardy when foreclosures are present. Table  4 also reports the key estimates when comparing neighborhoods in gated versus non-gated subdivisions. Gated subdivisions in this market are private com- munities that offer their residents amenities which are unavailable to the general public. Properties in gated communities are also typically subject to stricter controls regarding maintenance and use than are properties in non-gated neighborhoods. The community associations governing gated neighborhoods often have legal powers to compel maintenance or undertake actions to maintain the neighborhood character. It is therefore not surprising that results reported in Table 4 show that foreclosure and new construction externalities vary significantly across gated and non-gated neigh- borhood types. Legal governing powers used by community associations in gated Table 4 Summary of results for models by neighborhood type Neighborhood type Spillover effects N F—statistic Foreclosure externality New construction externality Density Low number of units − 0.0428 *** (0.0151) 0.0268 *** (0.0092) 10,284 15.02 *** High number of units − 0.0047 (0.0047) 0.0013 (0.0021) 10,943 1.60 Vacancy rate Low vacancy rate − 0.0139 (0.0094) 0.0050 (0.0041) 9,216 3.58 * High vacancy rate − 0.0177 ** (0.0081) 0.0111 *** (0.0038) 11,282 10.30 *** Neighborhood age New neighborhood − 0.0038 (0.0054) 0.0054 *** (0.0018) 9,361 3.04 * Old neighborhood − 0.0359 ** (0.0177) 0.0046 (0.0701) 9,999 0.30 Within neighborhood variation in age of houses Homogeneous in age of SFD − 0.0229 * (0.0121) 0.1214 * (0.0642) 9,719 4.70 ** Heterogeneous in age of SFD − 0.0150 * (0.0082) 0.0066 *** (0.0019) 9,522 6.67 ** Within neighborhood variation in size of houses Homogeneous in living area − 0.0308 *** (0.0089) 0.0110 * (0.0058) 10,103 15.00 *** of SFD Heterogeneous in living area − 0.0197 (0.0119) 0.0054 * (0.0039) 9,855 4.05 ** of SFD Subdivision Gated − 0.0070 (0.0067) 0.0026 (0.0030) 6,445 2.30 Non-gated − 0.0170 *** (0.0056) 0.0062 ** (0.0024) 33,468 13.90 *** Table summarizes the results for the spillover effects, based on model specification (1) in Table  2. The dependent variable is log transaction value. The reference category include Number of Bedrooms equals 3, Number of Bathrooms equals 2,00. All models include location fixed effects for ZIP code, and time fixed effects for year and month. Clustered standard errors at Census block level are in parentheses with ***, **, * indicating significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. The last column gives the F—statis- tic of a linear test on foreclosure externality equals new construction externality 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… neighborhoods appear to obviate both types of externalities, in contrast to the sig- nificant effects observed for non-gated neighborhoods. 5 Conclusion Foreclosures influence nearby property values, but the marginal effects vary signifi- cantly across neighborhoods. Our approach estimates the foreclosure effects across neighborhoods while controlling for the increasing supply of housing for sale as erstwhile foreclosed owners are removed from the market. We also introduce new construction into the empirical framework to control for possible externality effects arising when buyers interpret new construction as a signal of neighborhood stability or future growth, removing these possibly confounding influences on the estimated foreclosure externality effects across neighborhood types. Data from an epicenter of the US foreclosure experience, Orange County, Flor- ida, reveal that nearby foreclosures appear to reduce property prices by 1.43 percent overall. Removing the supply effect, these estimates imply a foreclosure externality of − 1.27 percent. The new construction externality is 0.5 percent. Turning to the main point of this paper, we find that foreclosure spillover effects systematically vary across types of neighborhoods, exhibiting almost tenfold varia- tion in some cases. For example, the marginal foreclosure externality ranges from −  0.38 percent for newer neighborhoods to − 3.59 percent for older ones. Overall, the strongest foreclosure effects are found in low density neighborhoods, structurally homogeneous neighborhoods, and non-gated subdivisions. We also find that non- linear foreclosure effects vary across types of neighborhoods, with older, structur - ally homogeneous neighborhoods with high vacancy rates most in jeopardy in this regard. Admittedly, urban morphology includes more dimensions than the ones we have considered, including street connectivity and accessibility. Likewise, as foreclosures force affected households to move, foreclosures may well have long-term implica- tions for the composition and social stability of urban neighborhoods. Hawley and Turnbull (2019) show that the built environment affects household behavior, but at the same time households choose neighborhoods with built environments conducive to pursuing lifestyles they prefer. Taking this type of endogenous household sort- ing into account, while we find that neighborhood built environment does matter for foreclosure price effects on surrounding properties, the Hawley and Turnbull (2019) conclusions suggest a need for future work to identify the extent to which these effects are specifically related to the built environment or to the mix of residents attracted to neighborhoods with those characteristics. 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Fig. 1 Nonlinear foreclosure effects across neighborhood types, number of foreclosures FS (near, before). Note Graphs plot coefficient for I1 (FS = 1), I2 (FS = 2), and I3 (FS = 3 or more), based on model specification (1) in Table  2. The dependent variable is log transaction value. The reference category includes Number of Bedrooms equals 3, Number of Bathrooms equals 2.00. All models include location fixed effects for ZIP code, and time fixed effects for year and month Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… Appendix 1: Data appendix Variables Definition Price Sales price property i at time t Number of foreclosures (near, before) Number of foreclosures within 1/10 mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of foreclosures (near, after) Number of foreclosures within 1/10 mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of foreclosures (far, before) Number of foreclosures within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of foreclosures (far, after) Number of foreclosures within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of market sales (near, before) Number of warranty deeds within 1/10 mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of market sales (near, after) Number of warranty deeds within 1/10 mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of market sales (far, before) Number of warranty deeds within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of market sales (far, after) Number of warranty deeds within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of new construction (near, Number of new constructed properties—based on building before) date—within 1/10 mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of new construction (near, after) Number of new constructed properties—based on building date—within 1/10 mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Number of new construction (far, before) Number of new constructed properties—based on building date—within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days before the sale of property i Number of new construction (far, after) Number of new constructed properties—based on building date—within (1/10–1/4) mile and 180 days after the sale of property i Living area Living area in sq. ft Bedrooms Number of bedrooms Baths Number of bathroons Walls of concrete stucco Dummy 1 if made of concrete stucco, 0 otherwise Pool Dummy 1 if private pool, 0 otherwise Age Age of property in years Parcel size Parcel size in acres CBD distance CBD distance relates to distance to Intersection of Central Blvd. and Orange Ave. Orlando, Fl 1 3 G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Appendix 2: Descriptive statistics by neighborhood type Low density High density New Old Low vacancy High vacancy Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Property controls Price 206,809 186,390 281,254 157,962 311,275 182,766 165,234 139,648 247,824 185,193 252,909 200,570 CBD distance 5.631 3.999 12.04 2.272 12.26 3.138 4.694 3.055 7.979 3.433 9.008 4.253 Living area 1,695 732.3 2,496 773.5 2,655 737.1 1,490 567.5 2,060 847.5 2,089 876.8 Bedrooms 3.112 0.784 3.832 0.770 3.895 0.728 3.024 0.749 3.476 0.792 3.458 0.777 Baths 199.4 77.48 266.9 74.21 280.1 76.99 177.6 65.73 235.1 81.35 236.7 81.01 Walls concrete 0.352 0.478 0.933 0.251 0.965 0.183 0.169 0.375 0.602 0.490 0.646 0.478 Pool 0.202 0.402 0.329 0.470 0.226 0.419 0.174 0.379 0.304 0.460 0.248 0.432 Age 41.15 22.78 8.27 8.44 3.21 3.30 51.04 14.57 24.07 20.05 20.74 20.86 Parcel size 51,883 51,925 35,871 29,446 37,592 35,383 45,431 43,734 45,410 41,312 43,489 43,869 Local housing market controls Number of 0.175 0.485 0.275 0.688 0.282 0.716 0.185 0.484 0.200 0.524 0.262 0.654 foreclosure sales (near, before) Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… 1 3 Low density High density New Old Low vacancy High vacancy Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Number of 0.142 0.426 0.249 0.638 0.255 0.665 0.146 0.421 0.179 0.487 0.227 0.592 foreclosure sales (near, after) Number of 0.480 1.009 0.695 1.291 0.669 1.346 0.565 1.089 0.587 1.073 0.645 1.235 foreclosure sales (far, before) Number of 0.467 0.966 0.709 1.276 0.688 1.321 0.553 1.049 0.590 1.045 0.644 1.217 foreclosure sales (far, after) Number of 0.112 0.133 0.126 0.123 0.123 0.132 foreclosures = 1 (near, before) Number of 0.023 0.036 0.039 0.023 0.027 0.036 foreclosures = 2 (near, before) Number of 0.005 0.019 0.021 0.005 0.007 0.017 foreclosures > 2 (near, before) Number of market 1.145 1.500 2.262 3.493 2.963 4.080 1.165 1.400 1.326 1.805 1.918 2.837 sales (near, before) Number of market 0.887 1.218 1.243 1.555 1.356 1.690 0.963 1.287 0.995 1.281 1.228 1.548 sales (near, after) G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Low density High density New Old Low vacancy High vacancy Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Number of market 3.102 3.144 4.839 5.796 5.540 6.598 3.497 3.374 3.591 3.636 4.150 4.643 sales (far, before) Number of market 2.674 2.857 3.059 2.834 2.955 2.947 3.070 3.144 2.924 2.740 3.036 3.000 sales (far, after) Number of new 0.117 0.866 1.326 3.883 2.123 4.522 0.012 0.127 0.272 1.532 0.748 2.915 construction (near, before) Number of new 0.131 0.797 1.999 5.981 3.067 6.829 0.038 0.298 0.458 2.536 1.029 4.257 construction (near, after) Number of new 0.091 0.785 0.621 2.011 1.049 2.427 0.007 0.096 0.136 0.925 0.367 1.451 construction (far, before) Number of new 0.114 0.751 1.006 2.978 1.622 3.450 0.029 0.274 0.264 1.488 0.567 2.044 construction (far, after) Number of obser- 10,284 10,983 9,361 9,999 9,216 11,282 vations Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… 1 3 Appendix 2: Descriptive statistics by neighborhood type (continued) Homogeneous in age Heterogeneous in age Homogeneous in living Homogeneous in living Gated Non-gated area area Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Property Price 153,791 106,952 301,148 206,164 219,248 153,210 281,933 239,797 368,293 232,058 208,646 150,832 CBD distance 6.174 3.202 10.87 4.241 8.803 4.154 9.742 4.390 11.6 2.657 8.472 4.260 Living area 1,527 503.3 2,439 873.1 1,977 781.4 2,242 972.2 2,849 794.8 1,884 741.7 Bedrooms 3.090 0.690 3.723 0.831 3.425 0.774 3.507 0.840 4.021 0.727 3.338 0.753 Baths 187.2 56.72 264.3 86.70 226.8 74.81 245.9 91.13 299.7 84.34 218.5 70.84 Walls concrete 0.287 0.822 0.617 0.667 0.981 0.565 Pool 0.212 0.231 0.248 0.320 0.451 0.229 Age 41.18 15.08 10.62 17.93 23.38 20.33 20.77 20.79 6.53  5.39 25.71  20.89 Parcel size 35,937 33,550 43,267 45,253 36,581 33,106 49,141 55,508 52,986 48,884 37,594 37,084 Local housing market controls Number of fore- 0.241 0.565 0.166 0.528 0.287 0.667 0.158 0.466 0.230 0.605 0.236 0.593 closure sales (near, before) Number of fore- 0.200 0.496 0.155 0.498 0.259 0.605 0.142 0.429 0.211 0.591 0.204 0.534 closure sales (near, after) G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist 1 3 Homogeneous in age Heterogeneous in age Homogeneous in living Homogeneous in living Gated Non-gated area area Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Number of fore- 0.712 1.213 0.450 1.036 0.708 1.275 0.459 0.939 0.584 1.174 0.634 1.185 closure sales (far, before) Number of fore- 0.698 1.166 0.470 1.030 0.736 1.233 0.453 0.924 0.604 1.172 0.632 1.139 closure sales (far, after) Number of 0.146 0.088 0.148 0.102 0.125 0.132 foreclosures = 1 (near, before) Number of 0.033 0.021 0.040 0.018 0.028 0.032 foreclosures = 2 (near, before) Number of 0.009 0.010 0.017 0.006 0.015 0.012 foreclosures > 2 (near, before) Number of mar- 1.341 1.460 2.644 4.041 1.674 2.043 1.284 2.327 1.870 2.871 1.587 2.388 ket sales (near, before) Number of mar- 1.121 1.340 1.120 1.587 1.303 1.498 0.834 1.243 1.131 1.419 1.089 1.408 ket sales (near, after) Number of mar- 3.989 3.464 4.810 6.402 4.012 3.637 3.144 4.128 4.027 4.526 3.894 4.342 ket sales (far, before) Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… 1 3 Homogeneous in age Heterogeneous in age Homogeneous in living Homogeneous in living Gated Non-gated area area Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Mean sd Number of mar- 3.546 3.231 2.491 2.690 3.400 3.110 2.290 2.450 2.757 2.635 3.012 2.959 ket sales (far, after) Number of new 0.003 0.057 2.108 4.477 0.237 1.588 0.563 2.476 0.913 2.979 0.470 2.299 construction (near, before) Number of new 0.028 0.308 2.870 6.610 0.339 1.934 0.840 3.674 1.407 4.248 0.690 3.512 construction (near, after) Number of new 0.003 0.072 1.088 2.501 0.156 1.088 0.259 1.292 0.474 1.653 0.235 1.249 construction (far, before) Number of new 0.019 0.196 1.619 3.489 0.251 1.483 0.414 1.767 0.806 2.476 0.371 1.761 construction (far, after) Number of obser- 9,719 9,522 10,103 9,855 6,445 33,468 vations G. K. Turnbull, A. J. van der Vlist Acknowledgements We gratefully acknowledge the Orange County, Florida residential tax assessment office for assistance in obtaining data. Thanks also to Fokke Dijkstra, Centre for Information Technol- ogy, University of Groningen, for computational assistance. We are grateful to seminar participants at the North American Regional Science Conference, KTH Sweden, and the University of Connecticut, USA, for comments on earlier versions of this work. The authors are responsible for any errors. Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Com- mons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http:// creat iveco mmons. org/ licen ses/ by/4. 0/. References Anas A, Arnott R, Small K (1998) Urban spatial structure. Journal of Economic Literature 36:1426–1464 Anenberg E, Kung E (2014) Estimates of the size and source of price declines due to nearby foreclosures. Am Econ Rev 104:2527–2551 Campbell J, Giglio S, Pathak P (2011) Forced sales and house prices. Am Econ Rev 101:2108–2131 Cheung R, Cunningham C, Meltzer R (2014) Do homeowners associations mitigate or aggravate negative spillovers from neighboring homeowner distress? J Hous Econ 24:75–88 Chinloy P, Hardin W, Zhnonghua W (2017) Foreclosure, REO, and market sales in residential real estate. J Real Estate Financ Econ 54:188–215 Clauretie T, Daneshvary N (2009) Estimating the house foreclosure discount corrected for spatial price interdependence and endogeneity of marketing time. Real Estate Econ 37:43–67 Coulson NE, Morris AC, Neil HR (2019) Are new homes special? Real Estate Econ 47:784–806 Daneshvary N, Clauretie TM (2012) Toxic neighbors: foreclosures and short-sales spillover effects from the current housing-market crash. Econ Inq 50:217–231 Daneshvary N, Clauretie TM, Kader A (2011) Short-term own-price and spillover effects of distressed residential properties: the case of a housing crash. J Real Estate Res 33:179–207 Davis L (2004) The effect of health risk on house values: evidence from a cancer cluster. Am Econ Rev 94:1693–1704 Ellen IG, O’Regan K (2010) Welcome to the neighborhood: how can regional science contribute to the study of neighborhoods? J Reg Sci 50:363–379 Fisher L, Lambie L, Willen P (2015) The role of proximity in foreclosure externalities: evidence from condominiums. Am Econ J Econ Policy 7:119–140 Gerardi K, Rosenblatt E, Willen P, Yao V (2015) Foreclosure externalities: new evidence. J Urban Econ 87:42–56 Gonzalez-Pampillon N (2022) Spillover effects from new housing supply. Reg Sci Urban Econ 92:103759 Hanson A, Schnier K, Turnbull GK (2012) Drive ‘til you qualify: credit quality and household location. Reg Sci Urban Econ 42:63–77 Harding JP, Rosenblatt E, Yao VW (2009) The contagion effect of foreclosed properties. J Urban Econ 66:167–178 Harding JP, Rosenblatt E, Yao VW (2012) The foreclosure discount: myth or reality. J Urban Econ 71:204–218 Hartley D (2014) The effect of foreclosures on nearby housing prices: supply or dis-amenity? Reg Sci Urban Econ 49:108–117 Hawley ZB, Turnbull GK (2019) Social interaction and urban household location. J Real Estate Financ Econ 59:1–26 Helms A (2012) Keeping up with the Joneses: neighborhood effects in housing renovation. Reg Sci Urban Econ 42:303–313 1 3 Foreclosures and housing prices: does neighborhood… Ihlanfeldt K, Mayock T (2012) Information, search, and house prices: revisited. J Real Estate Financ Econ 44:90–115 Ihlanfeldt K, Mayock T (2016) The variance in foreclosure spillovers across neighborhood types. Public Financ Rev 44:80–108 Immergluck D, Smith G (2006) The external costs of foreclosure: the impact of single-family mortgage foreclosures on property values. Hous Policy Debate 17:57–79 Ioannides Y (2002) Residential neighborhood effects. Reg Sci Urban Econ 32:145–165 Ioannides Y (2011) Neighborhood effects and housing. In: Benhabib J, Bisin A, Jackson M (eds) Hand- book of social economics, vol 1. Chapter 25, pp 1281–1340 Krainer J (2001) A theory of liquidity in residential real estate markets. J Urban Econ 49:32–53 Lin Z, Rosenblatt E, Yao V (2009) Spillover effects of foreclosures on neighborhood property values. J Real Estate Financ Econ 38:387–407 Linden L, Rockoff J (2008) Estimates of the impact of crime risk on property values from Megan’s laws. Am Econ Rev 98:1103–1127 Manski C (1993) Identification of endogenous social effects: the reflection problem. Rev Econ Stud 60:531–542 Mian A, Sufi A, Trebbi F (2015) Foreclosures, house prices, and the real economy. J Financ 70:2587–2633 Nedovic-Budic Z, Knaap G, Shahumyan H, Williams B, Slaev A (2016) Measuring urban form at com- munity scale: case study of Dublin, Ireland. Cities 55:148–164 OCPA (2017) Annual reports. 2010–2014. Orange County Property Appraisers, Florida Rogers W, Winter W (2009) The impact of foreclosures on neighboring housing sales. J Real Estate Res 31:455–479 Rosenthal S (2008) Homes, externalities and poor neighborhoods. J Urban Econ 63:816–840 Ross S (2011) Social interactions within cities: neighborhood environments and peer relationships. In: Brooks N, Donaphy K, Knaap G (eds) The oxford handbook of urban economics and planning. Oxford Publishers, Oxford Rossi-Hansberg E, Sarte P, Owens R (2010) Housing externalities. J Polit Econ 188:485–535 Schuetz J, Been V, Ellen I (2008) Neighborhood effects of concentrated mortgage foreclosures. J Hous Econ 17:306–319 Song Y, Knaap G (2003) New urbanism and housing values: a disaggregate assessment. J Urban Econ 54:218–238 Song Y, Knaap G (2004) Measuring the effects of mixed land uses on housing values. Reg Sci Urban Econ 34:663–680 Song Y, Knaap G (2007) Quantitative classification of neighbourhoods: the neighbourhoods of new sin- gle-family homes in the Portland metropolitan area. J Urban Des 12:1–24 Towe C, Lawley C (2013) The contagion effect of neighboring foreclosures. Am Econ J Econ Pol 5:313–335 Turnbull GK, Zahirovic-Herbert V (2011) Why do vacant houses sell for less: bargaining power, holding cost or stigma? Real Estate Econ 39:19–43 Turnbull GK, Zahirovic-Herbert V, Mothorpe C (2013) Flooding and liquidity on the bayou: the capitali- zation of flood risk into house value and ease-of-sale. Real Estate Econ 41:103–129 Turnbull GK, van der Vlist AJ (2023) After the boom: transitory and legacy effects of foreclosures. J Real Estate Financ Econ 66:422–442. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1007/ s11146- 021- 09882-w Whitehand J (1992) Recent advances in urban morphology. Urban Stud 29:619–636 Zahirovic-Herbert V, Gibler KM (2014) The effect of new residential construction on housing prices. J Hous Econ 26:1–18 Zhang L, Leonard T (2014) Neighborhood impact of foreclosure: a quantile regression. Reg Sci Urban Econ 48:133–143 Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. 1 3

Journal

The Annals of Regional ScienceSpringer Journals

Published: Apr 6, 2023

Keywords: R31

There are no references for this article.