Get 20M+ Full-Text Papers For Less Than $1.50/day. Start a 14-Day Trial for You or Your Team.

Learn More →

Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative industries: evidence from France

Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative industries: evidence from France This paper focuses on creative industries and the role played by the existing spatial distribution and agglomeration economies of these activities in relation to their entry decisions. We rely on employment and firm-level data in the creative industries (provided by INSEE) and compare the location of new establishments in the creative and non-creative industries between 2009 and 2013 in French departments (NUTS 3 regions). We use count data models and spatial econometrics to show that location determinants are rather similar in creative and non-creative industries and that specialisation in creative industries positively influences the entry of all other industries. The French case provides new insights to understand the geographical patterns of creative industries. JEL Classification R39 · Z100 1 Introduction Considerable attention has been devoted in the economic literature to the factors that influence the location decisions of new firms (Arauzo-Carod et  al. 2010). Existing work attempts to identify and quantify the determinants of entry and tends to focus * Josep-Maria Arauzo-Carod josepmaria.arauzo@urv.cat * Eva Coll-Martínez eva.coll-martinez@sciencespo-toulouse.fr Camelia Turcu camelia.turcu@univ-orleans.fr Laboratoire d’Économie d’Orléans, Université d’Orléans, Rue de Blois, BP 26739, 45067 Orléans, France Sciences Po Toulouse, Manufacture Des Tabacs, LEREPS, Université de Toulouse, 21 Allée de Brienne - CS 88526, 31685 Toulouse cedex 6, France ECO-SOS & QURE, Departament d’Economia, Universitat Rovira I Virgili, Av. Universitat, 1, 43204 Reus, Catalonia, Spain Vol.:(0123456789) 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. either on specified industries aggregated over regions or, conversely, on aggregated industry sectors (manufacturing, services) in specific geographical regions. More detailed analyses, with both industries and regions being specified, would be of great interest in helping to elucidate spatial and industry-specific characteristics. These, however, are much scarcer. In addition, in developed countries there are some activities that have noticeably seen an increase in weight in overall economic activity very recently. Unfortunately, however, they have not received enough attention from the academic community in order to understand forces driving entry of firms and, especially, their location deci- sions when choosing among alternative territories. This paper, therefore, focuses on Creative Industries (CIs), a group of industries linked to cultural, creative, and high- tech activities that have experienced high growth rates in recent years and that have relevant positive externalities (Sanchez-Serra 2014). They contribute to knowledge generation and the prestige of areas specialised in these activities (Myerscough, 1988). This, in turn, may attract other firms and economic activity (Gutierrez-Posada et  al. 2021; Bille and Schulze 2006), boost regional employment growth (Piergiovanni et al. 2012) and the productivity of existent firms (Coll-Martinez and Arauzo-Carod 2019). Key works highlighting the positive perception of CIs include two contributions by Florida (2005, 2002), who he has provided a measure of a “creative class” and a first (qualitative) attempt to quantify its contribution over economic activity. The current understanding of CI entry determinants is quite limited and further work is necessary on the processes that drive their entry. This paper aims to par- tially address this gap by analysing the French case at the province (département, or NUTS 3) level. This is of special interest in view of the importance of CIs in terms of (i) the number of firms and employees (IFM 2013), (ii) the growth of workforce in CIs (Chantelot 2010a), (iii) the strong export profile of firms, and (iv) the fact that (despite some concentration in the Paris region), there is a relatively well-balanced territorial distribution—despite being noticeably heterogeneous, all departments generate and attract new CIs. In addition, French CIs have a worldwide reputation since they include some globally prominent actors in areas that include fashion design, arts and entertainment, and publishing (Scott 2000; APUR 2014). There are also important inter-industry linkages arising from CIs as they contribute to the prestige of certain areas and attract firms from quite different and unrelated industries (Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017). Understanding what determines CI location choices is crucial in designing public policies aiming at attracting inno- vative firms to French regions. Our econometric results, obtained using Panel Count Data Models for French departments, suggest that on average, the probability of a creative firm locating in a French department increases with the amount of human capital, disposable income per inhabitant, the unemployment rate, a number of cultural amenities such as museums and cinemas. This probability diminishes with the share of manufacturing activities, public investment per inhabitant, distance to Paris, and weather factors The list of specific activities included among CIs is quite wide but, in general terms, the following are considered: Arts, Advertising, Cinema, Fashion, Publishing, R&D, and Software. See Sect. 4 (Data) for details and Table 9 for the complete list of industries. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… (proxied by cumulative rainfall). We found that both creative and non-creative firms are positively influenced by the specialisation level of creative industries. However, when considering neighbouring effects, the impact of CIs does not extend beyond the borders of the department. The paper is organised as follows. In the second section, we discuss theoretical and empirical contributions regarding firm entry and CIs, and we focus on those that specifically analyse entries in these industries and that consider spatial factors. In the third section, we present the methodology and the econometric specification. In the fourth section, we describe the data and variables. In the fifth section, we discuss the main results. We present our conclusions in the sixth and final section. 2 Literature review: firm entry and CIs Understanding firm entry decisions is becoming more and more relevant for policy makers as new firms are commonly hypothesised to be drivers of a wide range of positive effects that include local and regional development (Acs et  al. 2009), regional diversity (Noseleit 2015), technological change (Rigby and Essletzbichler 2000), productivity growth (Brixy 2014) and innovation (Audretsch 1995). Initially, the analysis of these decisions focused solely on the industry-specific determinants without including a spatial dimension (Orr 1974). Spatial asymmetries, however, make some territories significantly more attractive than others and, since the mid- nineties, the spatial dimension has received more attention (Reynolds et al. 1994). Accordingly, empirical contributions focusing on aggregate firm entries (typically restricted to manufacturing industries but, to some extent, also to services) have identified several spatially specific entry determinants. The most well-known of these are agglomeration economies (Fotopoulos and Louri 2000), entrepreneurial attitude (Bosma and Schutjens 2011), firm structure (Arauzo-Carod and Segarra-Blasco 2005; Kangasharju 2000), population size (Armington and Acs 2002), institutional quality (Acs et  al. 2008), income (Elert 2014), human capital (Armington and Acs 2002), persistence of previous entries (Andersson and Koster 2010), and labour market characteristics (Santarelli et al. 2009). In the literature, “traditional” manufacturing or service activities have attracted much more attention than have CIs. When the latter were analysed, that attention has often been solely put on their role as magnets for other activities (Hall 2000), as promoters of firm entries (De Jong et al. 2007), or as tools for economic growth (De Propris 2013; Piergiovanni et  al. 2012), rather than on the specific entry determinants for these industries. Nevertheless, empirical contributions on the location determinants for CIs do exist. These include the works of Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod (2017) for Catalan municipalities, Coll-Martínez et  al. (2019) for Barcelona at the intra-urban level, Kiroff (2017) for the design subsector in Auckland, Sanchez-Serra (2016) for Spanish travel-to-work areas, Boix et  al. (2015) for a selection of European metropolitan areas, Wenting (2011) for fashion design firms in the Netherlands, Smit (2011) for three Dutch cities, Bertacchini and Borrione (2013) for Italian regions and Cruz and Teixeira (2014) for Portuguese municipalities. 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Although the methodologies, geographical areas and the research focus of these studies differ considerably, some common key location determinants have been identified. Specifically, as distinct from traditional agglomeration economies (Sanchez-Serra 2016), specialisation in CIs is a strong determinant for entries of both creative and non-creative firms (Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod, 2017). Similarly, there is empirical evidence indicating that all types of firms benefit from the existence of an intangible creative milieu favouring entries (Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017; Wojan et  al. 2007) as well as creative externalities (Sanchez- Serra 2016). Previous results highlight the strong interindustry linkages between creative and non-creative industries that enhance the positive effects of the former over the latter. In this sense, recent contributions highlight that only the cross- fertilisation of different creative talents working in different fields may stimulate creativity, ultimately enhancing regional development (Bakhshi and McVittie 2009; Cerisola 2018a, b; Innocenti and Lazzeretti 2021). Empirical evidence also indicates a strong preference for CI co-located clusters where there are also non-creative activities (Boix et al. 2015). In terms of the locational preferences of CIs, they tend to agglomerate in metropolitan areas (Boix et al. 2015; Sanchez-Serra 2013, 2014) and, within that, try to benefit from agglomeration economies by concentrating close to core neighbourhoods (Coll-Martínez et  al. 2019). Some, however, give more emphasis to urban amenities (Wenting 2011). Despite the interest of this topic in general and its specific importance for French creative and cultural markets, empirical evidence for France is unfortunately still scarce. Notable exceptions are Sanchez-Serra (2014, 2013). Sanchez-Serra (2013) focuses on the clustering of creative clusters at travel-to-work areas (Zones d’Emploi) and identifies 63 artistic creative local labour systems, showing that creative employ - ment is clearly more concentrated than is total employment, especially in and around big urban areas. Sanchez-Serra (2014) identifies creative clusters in France and their determinants, finding that the existence of information and communication technology jobs, education and the presence of foreign-born workers positively stimulate crea- tive clustering. In the same line, Barois (2020) studies the link between the weight of creative and cultural activities in the territories and the attractiveness of the population showing that young workers and students prefer to locate in areas where the weight of the creative and cultural industries is important. Finally, although Chantelot (2010a) focuses on CI workforce rather than on firm entries, he identifies urban amenities and market opportunities as being among the main determinants of CI workforce concen- tration in large French urban areas. 3 Methods 3.1 Model specification There is a degree of consensus that entry determinants are industry-specific (Audretsch and Fritsch 1999) and, more specifically, that CIs entries are affected See Chantelot (2010b) for an analysis of French creative class in terms of workforce. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… by creativity-specific factors (see for instance, Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017; Sanchez-Serra 2016; Cruz and Teixeira 2014; Lazzeretti et al. 2012). Among these, the median household income (income) (the income elasticity of demand for cultural assets tends to be high) and higher levels of public investment in cultural issues (public_investment) should favour CIs location. Their location decision is also determined by residential amenities that in this paper are proxied by the following variables: the average number of days of sun (sun) and cumulative rain in mm (rain), that are expected to capture natural amenities, and the number of cinemas (cinemas) and museums (museums), that are expected to capture cultural amenities. Finally, areas that are more specialised in CIs (LQ_creative) should favour the entry of all kinds of firms because of the existence of knowledge spillovers in terms of creativity and innovation, as shown in Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod (2017), and also should be more able to attract new firms because of the agglomeration advantages (localisation economies) created by the co-location of creative firms (Stam et  al. 2008; De Jong et al. 2007; Lee et al. 2004; Scott 2000, 2006). CIs also consider traditional location determinants (see Arauzo-Carod et  al. 2010, for an extensive review). Among them, education (human_capital) and agglomeration economies (in this paper proxied by population density: pop_ density) are important location factors whatever characteristics a firm may have. Share of manufacturing activities (manufacturing) is another well-known location determinant that fosters entries. Several different theories suggest that unemployment rates (unemployment) influence location decisions. Some studies show that high unemployment rates favour the creation of firms because of the lack of employment alternatives (Wagner and Sternberg 2004). However, other authors argue that high unemployment rates are linked to economic recession and, therefore, lower levels of consumption (Reynolds et  al. 1994; Aubry et  al. 2015) that in turn deter entries. Finally, geography and institutional issues matter (Guimarães et  al. 2000), as firms need easy access to services provided in cores—hence, we need to control for distance to main cities such as Paris (dist_paris). Moreover, proximity to the most important city of a country may capture, on the one hand, a potential competition effect in view of agglomeration of firms in the area and, on the other hand, a competitive advantage in terms of the services and amenities located in and around the city. To analyse the determinants of CIs location decisions and their relationship with the CIs specialisation, we estimated the number of new establishments as a function of the specific local characteristics, in Eq. (1): Firm entries =  +  human_capital +  pop_density it 0 1 it 2 it +  income +  manufacturing 3 it 4 it +  unemployment +  public_investment (1) 5 it 6 it +  LQ_creative +  dist_paris +  rain 7 it 8 it 9 it +  sun +  cinema +  museums + u 10 it 11 it 12 it it where Firm entries is the number of firms located in area i across the period t. Our it empirical strategy consists in estimating eight different models that share the same set 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. of explanatory variables with different dependent variables (Firm entries ): all firms it (entry_t), non-creative firms (entry_noncrea), creative firms (entry_crea), cinema and audiovisuals firms (entry_audio), sound recording (entry_sound), life performance (entry_life), arts craft (entry_craft), other music activities (entry_other), publishing firms (entry_pub), advertising firms (entry_adv) and videogames firms (entry_vide- ogames). This strategy allows us to compare the location determinants of the group of firms considered, with particular focus on the impact of the specialisation in CIs. 3.2 Model selection Most contributions in this field rely on cross section data, although a significant number use panel data approaches that cover a wide range of countries and entry typologies. Among them, for instance, we highlight the work of Hong et  al. (2015) for Korea; Karahasan (2015) and Günalp and Cilasun (2006) for Turkey; Abdesselam et al. (2014) for France; Elert (2014) and Nyström (2007) for Sweden; Arauzo-Carod and Teruel-Carrizosa (2005) for Spain; Kangasharju (2000) for Finland, or Dunne et al. (1988) for the U.S. Using panel data offers some advantages over cross section data (Hsiao 2014). For instance, the possibility of introducing standard fixed effects in the regression potentially reduces the correlation effects of the explanatory variables with unobservables (which are difficult to control with cross section data). Thus, one of the main contributions of this paper is to provide evidence on CIs location determinants by using panel data. Concretely, in this paper, we use Count Data Models to analyse the determinants of CIs location choices. The number of firm entries in a given region (in this paper, French departments) is a nonnegative integer (count) variable that is better estimated by techniques other than ordinary least squares (OLS) which can lead to biased, inefficient and inconsistent estimates (Long 1997). Count Data Models (CDM) have commonly been used when dealing with the location phenomenon from a spatial point of view: i.e. when trying to explain how the local characteristics of different sites (e.g. municipalities, counties, regions) can influence firms’ decisions (Arauzo-Carod et  al. 2010). These CDM include the Poisson Model (PM), the Negative Binomial Model (NBM), the Zero Inflated Poisson Model (ZIPM) and the Zero Inflated Negative Binomial Model (ZINBM). Although PM is the most popular CDM, it has two econometrical limits, “overdispersion” and “excess zeroes”. Since these problems may be solved using NBM, ZIPM and ZINBM, we follow Cameron and Trivedi (1998, 2005) in order to determine which of them is the most appropriate. To do this, we compute the following statistics: the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC), the Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC) and the Vuong test. The descriptive statistics of the dependent variables in the firm entry model showed signs of overdispersion but, since there is at least one establishment (except for publishing and videogames industries) located in each department, there is Specifically, zeroes were 6.94% for publishing and 30% for videogames entries. The key variable LQ_creative is replaced in each model for a LQ in each subgroup of CIs, that is, LQ_audio, LQ_sound, LQ_life, LQ_craft, LQ_other, LQ_pub, LQ_adv and LQ_videogames. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… not a zero-inflation problem. For this reason, we estimated a baseline specification using CDM and selected the specification with the best fit according to the above statistics. Tables  7 and 8 illustrate the results for these statistics and show that the NBM performed best according to AIC and BIC. The only exceptions are found for sound recording, publishing and videogames since the AIC, BIC and the Vuong test also favoured the ZINBM over the NBM. Nevertheless, the percentage of zeroes was not big enough to justify using an inflated model. Thus, we decided to use the NBM—for panel data and time fixed effects—for all the firm entry specifications, except for sound recording, publishing and videogames. As shown by many previous studies, neighbouring effects can be important. If the effects of the determinants of firm location decisions extend beyond departments, and this possible spatial dependence is not considered, then results may be biased and inconsistent. To account for spatial dependence, we also considered the spatially lagged variables of the independent variables (Spatial Lagged Model in the X (SLX)). These were estimated as: W_Z = WZ, where Z is a matrix that contains the independent variables and W is a row-standardised contiguity weighting matrix, an approach that has already been used in previous contributions for the case of French metropolitan départements (see for instance, Elhorst and Fréret 2009). 4 Data 4.1 Data sources All data in this paper relate to the 96 NUTS 3 departments of metropolitan France and include the location of new establishments (dependent variable) and a set of territorial characteristics (independent variables). The sources for the location of new establishments are the Répertoire des Entreprises et des Établissemetns (REE) and the Système Informatique pour le Répertoire des Entreprises et de leurs Établissements (SIRENE), supplied by the Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques (INSEE). These sources provide comprehensive information on the location of establishments (both manufacturing and services) in France between 2009 and 2013, including geographical information (at regional and department levels), employment data, and other characteristics at the 4-digit NAF level. The local characteristics of French departments are taken from different sources such as INSEE, the French Government and Eurostat. Table  9 shows some descriptive statistics (see Table 10 for the main correlation results for these variables). Regarding the definition of CIs, we use the APUR-INSEE proposal (2014) as it is the official classification of CIs used in France and roughly relies on the UNCTAD’s (2008) proposal, which is the most widely accepted by researchers (see, among oth- ers, Lazzeretti et  al. 2012; Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017). According to Other spatial weighting definitions were considered such as 5 nearest neighbours or an inverse dis- tance-based matrix. Even so, the best fit of the model is obtained when we rely on a row-standardised contiguity weighting matrix, an approach that has already been used in previous contributions for the case of French metropolitan départements (see for instance, Elhorst and Fréret 2009). 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 1 Creative Industries firm entries by year CIs Subgroups 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Cinema and audio-visuals 5292 5349 4925 5787 5697 % in all the CIs 23% 23% 18% 25% 26% Sound recording 635 628 704 806 691 % in all the CIs 3% 3% 3% 3% 3% Life performance 2892 2573 1951 2095 2421 % in all the CIs 13% 11% 7% 9% 11% Arts Craft 2529 2153 1400 1246 1566 % in all the CIs 11% 9% 5% 5% 7% Other artistic activities 6190 7113 6451 7446 6037 % in all the CIs 27% 31% 23% 32% 28% Publishing 1329 1258 1373 1731 1578 % in all the CIs 6% 6% 5% 7% 7% Advertising 3238 3315 10,506 3239 2895 % in all the CIs 14% 14% 38% 14% 13% Videogames 489 477 513 791 815 % in all the CIs 2% 2% 2% 3% 4% All creative industries 22,594 22,866 27,823 23,141 21,700 % in all the economy 5% 5% 7% 6% 6% Non-CIs 399,068 412,649 373,909 387,695 367,551 % in all the economy 95% 95% 93% 94% 94% All industries 421,662 435,515 401,732 410,836 389,251 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% Source: Authors, based on SIRENE data this criterion, we include 29 sectors in CIs, classified into 8 subgroups (cinema and audio-visuals, sound recording, life performance, arts craft, other music activities, publishing, advertising and videogames (see NAF-Rev. 2 industry classification in Table  11). Table  1 illustrates the 2009‒2013 period showing an increasing trend (between 2009 and 2011) followed by a short period of attrition that fits with the economic trend of these years, and Table  2 shows a weak decrease in employment in CIs sectors during the same period. The choice of the time span is driven by data availability at the level of NUTS 3 regions. Nevertheless, it is worth underlying that the considered period in our analysis starts after the Global Financial Crisis that hit France and its regions in 2007–2008, lowering then potential bias due to market turbulence. Hence, we analyse the location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative industries in a context of a certain economic recovery (Sensier et al. 2016; Although the Architecture and Engineering industries are typically included among CIs, we decided to exclude them as they have a very particular location patterns, are concentrated in some departments, and include an important share of nuclear activities (noticeably in Territoire Belfort where there is a cross- border cluster on both sides of the French-Swiss border) which are far away from CIs. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Table 2 Creative Industries employment by year CIs Subgroups 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Cinema and audio-visuals 4953 5076 4646 5357 5315 % in all the CIs 11% 11% 10% 11% 11% Sound recording 3772 3529 3642 3775 3927 % in all the CIs 8% 7% 8% 8% 8% Life performance 20,756 22,984 21,506 20,952 20,687 % in all the CIs 46% 49% 46% 43% 43% Arts Craft 377 337 438 477 505 % in all the CIs 1% 1% 1% 1% 1% Other music activities 10,332 10,669 11,838 12,803 13,299 % in all the CIs 23% 23% 25% 26% 27% Publishing 1158 1125 1193 1568 1447 % in all the CIs 3% 2% 3% 3% 3% Advertising 2944 3067 2765 2903 2608 % in all the CIs 7% 7% 6% 6% 5% Videogames 374 391 432 746 748 % in all the CIs 1% 1% 1% 2% 2% All creative industries 44,666 47,178 46,460 48,581 48,536 % in all the economy 0.31% 0.34% 0.31% 0.32% 0.32% All industries 14,566,204 13,942,865 15,062,343 14,994,756 15,103,455 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% Source: Authors with INSEE data Arcuri et al. 2019) as the economy has moved from negative growth rates (in 2009) to positive ones (over 2010–2013). 4.2 Stylised facts about creative industries and firm location in French Departments Figure 1 compares the location patterns of all firms, non-creative and creative firms. For both years (2009 and 2013), roughly 75% of all firms locate in and around Île- de-France and in the most populated departments such as Nord, Rhône, Bouches- sur-Rhône or Gironde, the same areas where most cultural jobs are located (Cléron and Patureau 2007). Thus, it seems clear that one of the key determinants of a firm’s location decision is the attractiveness of these densely populated areas, specialised labour markets, availability of suppliers and knowledge spillovers. Similar spatial distributions hold for both creative and non-creative firms. Moreover, it has not significantly changed from 2009 to 2013. Although the number of new creative firms has increased over these years, they have kept the same agglomeration pattern around larger cities, as it has been demonstrated by other studies using spatial analysis tools (Chantelot et al. 2010a, b). See Julien (2002) for empirical evidence regarding France. 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Fig. 1 Firm entries by department. Source: Authors with SIRENE data In order to identify location patterns for CIs in French departments, we calculate a Location Quotient (LQ), using employment data (Effectif salarié déclaré par les établissements) taken from INSEE. The same index has been used by other scholars but with different specifications (for example, in Lazzeretti et al. 2012). This index compares the relative specialisation of a department in a sector in relation to the national (France) average and is defined as: LQ_creative =(L ∕L )∕(L ∕L) ij ij j i where L is the workforce in the creative industry j in department i, L is the total ij j workforce in the creative industry j, L is the total workforce in department i, and L is total employment in the area (France). An LQ greater than 1 indicates that the clustering of a creative industry j in department i is larger than the national average, hence the department is specialised in CIs. Figure  2 shows LQ results for the ten most specialised French departments and the spatial distribution of LQ in CIs for 2009 and 2013, respectively. Departments located in the Île-de-France region are the most specialised in CIs (all with values higher than 1). Concretely, Hauts-de-Seine and Paris departments stand out with a LQ greater than 3 for both years. Although, since they have values below 1, the 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Fig. 2 Specialisation in crea- tive industries by department. Source: Authors with INSEE data remaining most populated departments are not specialised in CI’s, nevertheless they comprise most of the creative employment in France. These results have not signifi- cantly changed over these years. 5 Results 5.1 Main results Table  3 shows the results of the econometric estimation of CIs location determi- nants. Negative Binomial estimates are presented for all firm entries, both creative and non-creative, in order to compare the determinants of location decisions of dif- ferent types of industries. In general, for all types of entries, most of the explana- tory variables are significant, but there are some remarkable differences between the creative and non-creative industries. Specifically, population density (a proxy for agglomeration economies) has a negative effect over all industries and non-creative industries, although the coefficient is not significant for CIs. Nevertheless, the role of population density is not clear, as correlation analysis shows a significant and positive relationship with all entries, but especially with those of CIs. This result could be understood in terms of an unknown relationship between the location Chantelot (2010a) analyses determinants of CIs workforce location and reaches a similar result for big urban areas in France. 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 3 Location determinants of firms (NB) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) Firm entries All Creative Non-Creative Human capital 0.023*** 0.026*** 0.023*** (0.008) (0.007) (0.008) pop_density −8.70e − 05** −6.33e − 05 −8.91e − 05** (4.16e − 05) (5.25e − 05) (4.10e − 05) Income 1.27e − 05 1.55e − 05* 1.25e − 05 (7.85e − 06) (8.71e − 06) (7.80e − 06) Manufacturing −1.152** −1.585*** −1.132** (0.481) (0.537) (0.478) Unemployment 4.604** 4.079* 4.636** (2.222) (2.190) (2.224) Public investment −0.001* −0.00102* −0.00109* (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) LQ_creative 0.223* 0.286* 0.217 (0.135) (0.169) (0.132) dist_paris −0.0003 −0.0006** −0.0003 (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0003) Rain −0.0002 −0.0001 −0.0002 (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) Sun 2.37e − 05 3.06e − 05 2.33e − 05 (0.0001) (9.69e − 05) (0.0001) Cinema 0.029*** 0.029*** 0.028*** (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) Museums 0.011** 0.011** 0.011** (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) Constant 5.725*** 2.514*** 5.684*** (0.606) (0.614) (0.606) N 480 480 480 Departments 96 96 96 Time FE Y Y Y Wald X 884.01 1124.97 854.26 Log pseudolikelihood −3993.583 −2575.39 −3969.217 lnalpha −2.452*** −2.393*** −2.452*** (0.141) (0.145) (0.141) Alpha 0.086 0.091 0.086 (0.121) (0.013) (0.121) Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 quotient of CIs and population density, although the influence of density over entries seems to be blurred by other explanatory variables. The aggregated income level of departments also plays a different role as it only boosts the entries of CIs. This may suggest some structural differences in terms of markets: CIs may, for example, 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… target the upper income levels of population. In a similar way, specialisation in CIs (LQ_creative) pushes up entries in CIs and for all firms but has no significant effect on entries of non-creative firms. This result supports our assumption regarding the positive effects of specialisation in CIs in terms of attracting new economic activ - ity, no matter what the industry of the entering firms. Noticeably, departments spe- cialised in CIs are more likely to attract new businesses. In terms of geographical position, a greater distance to Paris deters the entry of creative firms, as they may have more difficulties in establishing networking activities and an access to cultural amenities (that are highly concentrated in the French capital). Despite specific effects at industry level, there are common location determinants that act in a similar way across different types of industries (i.e. creative and non- creative), similarly to previous results also for Catalonia by Arauzo-Carod (2021) and Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod (2017). In this sense, entries in all subgroups are attracted to areas that have more people enrolled in education (this is a neces- sary production factor, no matter the industry), while they are repelled from areas with more manufacturing activity. This result may be explained by the fact that these areas are associated with negative externalities that do not fit with cultural and crea- tive environments. Surprisingly, regional economic conditions favour areas with high unemployment rates and, similarly, those that receive higher levels of public investment. Cultural amenities (i.e. cinema and museums), exert the same positive effect on entries across all firm profiles whilst climate conditions (rain and sun) have no significant effect on entries. Nevertheless, it is important to precise that our approach analyses location determinants for both creative and non-creative indus- tries considering firms included in these categories, but without taking into account the profile of workforce at firm/industry level. In this sense, creative and non-cre- ative jobs coexist in both creative-and-non-creative firms, although with different shares. Negative Binomial estimates are presented in Table 4 for entering firms belonging to sound, life, craft, other, audio-visuals, publishing, advertising, and videogames, in order to compare the determinants of location decision for these CIs. This strategy allows us to analyse the location behaviour of specific CIs, given that overall results may not reveal some heterogeneities due to the locational specificities of each CIs. As expected, many CIs subgroups share most of the location determinants, such as the positive role played by human capital, income and the cultural amenities (i.e. museums and cinema), as well as the negative effect of share of manufactur - ing activity, but there are noticeable differences for other determinants. In particu- lar, we may distinguish between (mostly) cultural oriented and (mostly) technology- oriented subgroups: the former includes arts, sound, life, craft, other activities and Additionally, we tested alternative covariates for proxying proximity to the political power (regional capital), climate conditions (temperature and humidity), natural amenities (coast, forest area and natural parks), tourism activities (lodging size), and diversity (foreign population), but model fit did not improve when they were included, and main results generally remained quite similar. Although the focus of this paper is on creative industries and not on creative jobs, which demands a different type of dataset, there is empirical evidence showing that creative jobs exert positive effects over close local service employment (Gutierrez-Posada et al. 2021). 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. 1 3 Table 4 Location determinants of Creative Industries Subgroups (NB) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Firm entries Sound Life Craft Other Audio-visuals Publishing Advertising Videogames human capital 0.061*** 0.026*** 0.018*** 0.0195*** 0.033*** 0.026*** 0.031*** 0.041*** (0.0099) (0.007) (0.006) (0.007) (0.009) (0.009) (0.008) (0.012) pop_density 7.70e − 05 −5.12e − 05 −3.81e − 05 −7.48e − 05** −7.55e − 05 2.67e − 05 −5.76e − 05 −2.45e − 05 (7.66e − 05) (4.48e − 05) (2.72e − 05) (3.08e − 05) (6.00e − 05) (6.62e − 05) (4.14e − 05) (3.14e − 05) Income 3.34e − 05** 2.11e − 05** 1.54e − 05** 1.28e − 05* 2.28e − 05** 1.94e − 05** 2.38e − 05** 9.34e − 07 (1.30e − 05) (8.37e − 06) (7.42e − 06) (6.94e − 06) (1.05e − 05) (8.76e − 06) (1.09e − 05) (7.18e − 06) manufacturing −5.562*** −1.204* −0.832 −1.142** −2.310*** −3.429*** −2.045*** −4.863*** (0.873) (0.683) (0.560) (0.459) (0.613) (0.823) (0.654) (0.948) Unemployment −4.174 3.826* 5.010** 4.605** 3.583 −4.224 3.161 0.680 (2.686) (2.180) (2.294) (1.877) (2.707) (3.290) (2.383) (4.595) public investment 0.0004 −0.0008 −2.04e − 05 −0.0006 −0.001 −0.0006 −0.001* −0.0013 (0.0009) (0.0006) (0.0006) (0.0005) (0.0007) (0.0009) (0.00067) (0.00103) LQ_$ −0.132 0.193* 0.0151 −0.00144 0.259* 0.0162 0.312** 0.505*** (0.176) (0.109) (0.012) (0.054) (0.135) (0.169) (0.133) (0.067) Dist_paris −0.0004 −0.001*** −0.001*** −0.007** −0.0008** −0.0006 −0.0003 0.0004 (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0006) Rain −0.0001 −0.0001 −0.0003 −8.31e − 05 −0.0002 −0.0002 −0.0003** −0.0003 (0.0003) (0.0008) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0003) Sun −9.38e − 05 0.0001 0.0001 2.74e − 05 −1.11e − 05 0.0002 −6.28e − 05 −0.0004* (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001) (8.96e − 05) (0.0001) (0.0007) (0.0001) (0.0002) Cinema 0.0120 0.0307*** 0.0247*** 0.0275*** 0.0320*** 0.0257*** 0.0259*** 0.0267*** (0.007) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.007) (0.006) (0.008) Museums 0.0076 0.0072 0.0142*** 0.0116** 0.0098 0.0153** 0.0105* 0.0058 (0.0078) (0.0053) (0.0041) (0.0047) (0.006) (0.007) (0.006) (0.008) Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 4 (continued) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Firm entries Sound Life Craft Other Audio-visuals Publishing Advertising Videogames Constant −2.371*** 0.166 0.773 1.816*** 0.678 0.382 0.511 −1.108 (0.873) (0.658) (0.632) (0.598) (0.693) (0.787) (0.724) (1.088) Inflate Pop −0.000* − − − − −0.000** − −0.000** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) constant 4.449*** − − – − 2.463 − 3.12** (2.369) 1.642 (1.08) N 480 480 480 480 480 480 480 480 Departments 96 96 96 96 96 96 96 96 Time FE Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Wald X 562.83 1044.05 1055.76 663.72 1061.69 505.00 2990.01 937.34 Log pseudolikelihood −1088.507 −1620.841 −1525.022 −2060.629 −1950.449 −1385.312 −1872.121 −954.435 Lnalpha −1.932*** −2.270 −2.402 −2.561 −2.159 −1.912 −2.096 −2.094*** (0.185) (0.165) (0.165) (0.129) (0.159) (0.194) (0.161) (0.432) Alpha 0.146 0.103 0.090 0.077 0.115 0.148 0.123 0.123 (0.027) (0.017) (0.015) (0.010) (0.018) (0.029) (0.019) (0.053) Vuong 3.51*** − − − − 2.74** − 4.09*** Robust standard errors in parentheses, ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 5 Spatial Lag Model: Location determinants of firms (NB) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) Firm entries All Creative Non-Creative human capital 0.0224*** 0.0256*** 0.0222*** (0.0027) (0.0029) (0.0027) W_human capital −0.0013 −0.0013 −0.0013 (0.0012) (0.0012) (0.0012) pop_density −8.63e − 05*** −6.35e − 05*** −8.83e − 05*** (1.20e − 05) (1.27e − 05) (1.20e − 05) W_pop_density −3.58e − 05* −3.58e − 05* −3.58e − 05* (2.18e − 05) (2.18e − 05) (2.18e − 05) income 1.17e − 05** 1.42e − 05** 1.16e − 05** (5.43e − 06) (5.72e − 06) (5.42e − 06) W_income 1.89e − 08 1.89e − 08 1.89e − 08 (9.48e − 06) (9.48e − 06) (9.48e − 06) Manufacturing −1.163*** −1.593*** −1.143*** (0.243) (0.257) (0.243) W_manufacturing 0.366 0.366 0.366 (0.457) (0.457) (0.457) Unemployment 4.551*** 3.939*** 4.589*** (0.906) (0.963) (0.906) W_unemployment −2.452 −2.452 −2.452 (1.752) (1.752) (1.752) public investment −0.0011*** −0.0012*** −0.0011*** (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) W_public investment 0.0005 0.0005 0.0005 (0.0004) (0.0004) (0.0004) LQ_creative 0.236*** 0.306*** 0.230*** (0.058) (0.059) (0.058) W_LQ_creative 0.146 0.146 0.146 (0.128) (0.128) (0.128) dist_paris −0.0003** −0.0006*** −0.0003** (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001) Rain −0.0002*** −0.0001* −0.0002*** (8.27e − 05) (8.81e − 05) (8.28e − 05) Sun 1.98e − 05 2.67e − 05 1.93e − 05 (5.36e − 05) (5.64e − 05) (5.36e − 05) Cinema 0.0281*** 0.0290*** 0.0281*** (0.0019) (0.002) (0.0019) W_cinema −0.0016 −0.0016 −0.0016 (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Museums 0.0116*** 0.0113*** 0.0116*** (0.0022) (0.0023) (0.0022) W_museums 0.0033 0.0033 0.0033 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Table 5 (continued) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) Firm entries All Creative Non-Creative (0.0048) (0.0048) (0.0048) Constant 5.768*** 2.539*** 5.720*** (0.465) (0.458) (0.465) N 480 480 480 Departments 96 96 96 Time FE Y Y Y Wald X 885.42 995.95 877.11 Log pseudolikelihood −3987.721 −2566.505 −3963.184 Robust standard errors in parentheses, ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 publishing, whilst the latter include audio-visuals, advertising and videogames. Although the patterns are not clearly divided into two groups, the main difference is found in the role played by localisation economies since, while for technology- oriented subgroups, location quotients in their subgroup foster entries, this effect is only found for one out of the six cultural oriented subgroups, that is, life perform- ing arts. This is a relevant issue, since agglomeration economies at department level matter for these activities, although it could also be argued that their geographical scope is much smaller than that of a department. Surprisingly, except for Audio-vis- uals, technology-oriented subgroups do not suffer from distance to Paris, suggesting that it is possible to attract such firms outside the Île-de-France region. Regarding unemployment rates, technology-oriented subgroups also have some specifi- cities as they are not positively attracted by them, as for the rest of subgroups. This may be explained by the fact that, for these industries, the creation of new firms is mainly driven by innovative ideas or market opportunities. Thus, the conditions leading to higher unemploy- ment rates may deter innovative-based CIs entries (Storey 1991; Fritsch 2008). For the cul- tural CIs subgroups (i.e. life performance, arts craft and other artistic activities) the impact of unemployment is positive and significant. This is consistent with the findings of Aubry et al. (2015) who show that start-ups in France are mainly explained by a refugee effect (i.e. the creation of firms is a strategy to escape from unemployment). This result is also in line with the higher part-time work and unemployment rates that usually characterise employ- ment in the more artistic and cultural CIs (Faggian et al. 2013; Pareja-Eastaway 2016). In order to account for inter-department neighbouring externalities for both the entries grouped (Table 5) and at a subgroup level (Table 6), we estimate an enlarged location decision model including such spatial externalities. We have to take into account that the way in which these activities have been grouped also differs. Concretely, CIs subgroups include NACE5 subsectors but with different quantities (see Table  11): Craft and Sound include 1 subsector; Life, Advertising and Other include 2 subsectors; Publishing and Vide- ogames include 5 subsectors; and Audio-visuals includes 12 subsectors. These results could be also affected by firm size, however information of the size of firms was not available. In any case, firms in cultural and creative industries tend to be of smaller size than the rest of economic activities (i.e. size variation is lower inside them) and, partially due to that reason, papers focusing on entry determinants or spatial distribution of firms use to group firms of different sizes together (see Coll-Martínez 2019; Fahmi et al. 2016; Lazzeretti et al. 2008, among others). 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. 1 3 Table 6 Spatial Lag Model: Location determinants of Creative Industries Subgroups (NB) Dep. Var: Firm entries (1) Sound (2) Life (3) Craft (4) Other (5) Audio-visuals (6) Publishing (7) Advertising (8) Videogames human capital 0.0623*** 0.0272*** 0.0179*** 0.0193*** 0.0333*** 0.0256*** 0.0307*** 0.0421*** (0.0068) (0.0039) (0.0037) (0.0029) (0.0036) (0.0054) (0.0037) (0.0078) W_human capital −0.0034 −0.0037** −0.0044*** −0.0003 −0.0016 −0.0032 −0.0041** −0.0029 (0.0026) (0.0016) (0.0017) (0.0013) (0.0016) (0.0022) (0.0016) (0.0027) pop_density 6.92e − 05** −4.91e − 05*** −3.59e − 05*** −7.17e − 05*** −7.68e − 05*** 2.60e − 05 −5.46e − 05*** −2.26e − 05 (3.22e − 05) (1.42e − 05) (1.10e − 05) (9.50e − 06) (1.73e − 05) (2.17e − 05) (1.23e − 05) (1.77e − 05) W_pop_density −3.85e − 05 −2.16e − 05 −1.46e − 05 −2.74e − 05* −1.85e − 05 −5.85e − 06 −1.91e − 05 2.96e − 05 (6.98e − 05) (2.40e − 05) (1.92e − 05) (1.57e − 05) (2.96e − 05) (4.62e − 05) (2.13e − 05) (2.99e − 05) Income 3.01e − 05*** 1.83e − 05*** 1.50e − 05** 1.13e − 05** 2.08e − 05*** 1.91e − 05** 2.29e − 05*** −2.64e − 07 (9.18e − 06) (6.35e − 06) (6.13e − 06) (5.24e − 06) (6.76e − 06) (8.34e − 06) (7.07e − 06) (9.03e − 06) W_income −1.54e − 05 −1.17e − 07 −6.41e − 06 9.81e − 06 2.59e − 06 3.49e − 06 −9.09e − 06 5.10e − 06 (1.99e − 05) (1.28e − 05) (1.29e − 05) (9.79e − 06) (1.21e − 05) (1.67e − 05) (1.26e − 05) (2.22e − 05) Manufacturing −5.126*** −1.098*** −0.914*** −1.130*** −2.356*** −3.475*** −1.984*** −4.993*** (0.563) (0.355) (0.331) (0.258) (0.318) (0.457) (0.334) (0.651) W_manufacturing 2.629** 1.149* 0.655 0.315 0.204 1.693** 1.330** −0.441 (1.022) (0.645) (0.623) (0.490) (0.606) (0.836) (0.640) (1.121) Unemployment −4.293** 3.577*** 4.776*** 4.591*** 3.228*** −4.725*** 2.697** −0.0459 (1.945) (1.235) (1.246) (0.958) (1.194) (1.719) (1.240) (2.358) W_unemployment 4.623 0.903 −1.156 −2.855 −1.529 −0.998 −3.198 1.376 (3.614) (2.295) (2.362) (1.834) (2.296) (3.122) (2.365) (3.981) public investment 0.0003 −0.001*** −3.49e − 05 −0.0006*** −0.001*** −0.0006 −0.0014*** −0.0012* (0.0005) (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003) (0.0004) (0.0003) (0.0006) W_public investment 0.0016* 0.0013** 0.0007 0.0007* 0.0008* 0.0005 0.0011** 0.0012 (0.0008) (0.0005) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0007) (0.0005) (0.0009) Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 6 (continued) Dep. Var: Firm entries (1) Sound (2) Life (3) Craft (4) Other (5) Audio-visuals (6) Publishing (7) Advertising (8) Videogames LQ_$ −0.104 0.205*** 0.0170 −0.00914 0.271*** 0.0357 0.335*** 0.527*** (0.0897) (0.0668) (0.0114) (0.0280) (0.0527) (0.0713) (0.0570) (0.0484) W_LQ_$ 0.231 −0.0348 0.0109 −0.0193 0.0402 0.0642 0.277** −0.0145 (0.213) (0.127) (0.0201) (0.0502) (0.105) (0.189) (0.126) (0.142) dist_paris −0.0004 −0.0009*** −0.0009*** −0.0007*** −0.0008*** −0.0006*** −0.0002 0.0004 (0.0003) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0003) Rain −0.0002 −0.0002 −0.0003** −8.42e − 05 −0.0002* −0.0002 −0.0004*** −0.0004** (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001) (8.70e − 05) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002) Sun −6.04e − 05 0.0001* 0.0001 3.16e − 05 −8.47e − 06 0.0002* −5.59e − 05 −0.0004*** (0.0001) (7.33e − 05) (7.29e − 05) (5.59e − 05) (7.01e − 05) (0.0001) (7.21e − 05) (0.0001) Cinema 0.0141*** 0.0305*** 0.0240*** 0.0272*** 0.0318*** 0.0253*** 0.0254*** 0.0265*** (0.004) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.0024) (0.0033) (0.0024) (0.004) W_cinema 0.0068 0.001 0.0013 −0.0036 0.0003 0.0069 −0.0021 0.0037 (0.0072) (0.0045) (0.0045) (0.0035) (0.0043) (0.006) (0.0046) (0.0081) Museums 0.0062 0.0078*** 0.0143*** 0.0124*** 0.0099*** 0.0138*** 0.0107*** 0.0034 (0.0044) (0.0028) (0.0028) (0.0023) (0.0028) (0.0037) (0.0029) (0.0042) W_museums −0.0149 0.0044 0.0039 0.0095* 0.0012 −0.0168* −0.0016 −0.0219* (0.0105) (0.0066) (0.0065) (0.0051) (0.0064) (0.0089) (0.007) (0.0115) Constant −3.362*** −0.470 1.425** 1.667*** 0.981 0.584 0.401 0.005 (1.054) (0.651) (0.626) (0.492) (0.603) (0.852) (0.638) (1.173) Inflate Ppop −0.000** − − − − −0.000*** − −0.000*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) constant 4.506 − − − − 2.275** − 2.83*** J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. 1 3 Table 6 (continued) Dep. Var: Firm entries (1) Sound (2) Life (3) Craft (4) Other (5) Audio-visuals (6) Publishing (7) Advertising (8) Videogames (1.995) (0.979) (0.721) N 480 480 480 480 480 480 480 480 Time FE Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Log pseudolikelihood −1075.408 −1610.265 −1517.873 −2053.83 −1946.125 −1378.752 −1859.683 −953.819 Robust standard errors in parentheses; ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Regarding Table  5, almost all the key location determinants remain significant as in previous estimations. However, by adding spatial lagged variables, some variables such as population density, income, distance to Paris and rain levels become significant. Population density and income tend to be closely linked to market strength, which is a key location fac- tor, as well as that increased distance to main economic centres usually having a negative effect due to lower attractiveness of these areas (Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017). The effects of the specialisation in creative industries remain significant at the department level, but they do not seem significant beyond department borders. In other words, creative firms seem to be only affected by specialisation in CIs in the departments where they locate, but not by surrounding areas. This is a quite reason- able result as the spatial scope of agglomeration externalities captured by LQ_cre- ative tends to diminish after very short distances, as reported previously by Coll- Martínez et al. (2019) for Barcelona’s neighbourhoods, Cruz and Teixeira (2014) for Portuguese municipalities, and Wojan et al. (2007) for US counties. Finally, subgroup estimation including spatial lags (Table  6) slightly modifies the previous findings when taking spatial effects into account. In particular, the negative effects of population density and public investments on entries now become significant for most of the subgroups. A noticeable exception is Videogames since, for this indus- try, population density does not deter entries. This result fits perfectly with the existing literature regarding the locational patterns of Videogames industry, as empirical evi- dence has demonstrated the strong urban-core preferences of firms belonging to that industry (Moriset 2003; Méndez-Ortega and Arauzo-Carod 2019, 2020). In general terms, the subgroup estimations including spatial lags increase the signif- icance of most of covariates used in previous estimations, although failing to identify strong significant influences of neighbouring departments. This result may be, to some extent, explained by the fact that neighbouring relations have been defined by consid- ering a spatial contiguity matrix. Still, the use of a spatial contiguity matrix provides the best fit of the model. Anyway, the inclusion of spatial lags allows us to capture any source of spatial dependence in terms of knowledge spillovers spreading beyond geo- graphical limits and that cannot be considered otherwise. 6 Conclusion In this paper, we estimate the location determinants of new creative industries (CIs) firms across metropolitan France departments over the period 2009–2013. The econometric results show that the location determinants of creative and non-creative firms are quite similar, and that both creative and non-creative firms are positively affected by the specialisation in CIs. This influence supports public investments in these industries in view of the positive externalities arising from their spatial con- centration on firm entry. Our results also show that there are some locational spe- cificities among CIs activities due to their heterogeneity. Finally, when accounting for spatial dependence, we found that creative firms seem to be only affected by CI 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. specialisation in the departments where they locate, but not in surrounding areas, so the spatial scope of effects is less than a standard department. Our results are in line with those of previous empirical contributions and sup- port the positive association between the concentration of creative workers and new firms’ creation at the department level (Scott 2006; Lee et al. 2004; Stam et al. 2008; Audretsch and Belitski 2013; Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017). Moreover, they are in line with previous findings highlighting the uneven geographic distribu- tion of creative people, mainly concentrated in Paris and larger French cities (Chan- telot 2010a, 2010b; Sanchez-Serra 2013, 2014). Consequently, our results help to fill a gap in the empirical literature in terms of a lack of knowledge of the processes driving the entry decisions of CIs firms. This paper has certain limitations. Since it is focused on location determi- nants of CIs at a quite aggregated level, it remains for future research to analyse whether our results hold for alternative geographical disaggregation levels such as municipalities or metropolitan areas. Some empirical evidence already exists for the French case (see Chantelot 2010a) and this indicates that there are differ- ences between big and medium-small urban areas. Additionally, due to the huge concentration of CIs in Paris and the municipalities in its metropolitan area (see Boix et  al. 2016), it would be advisable to carry out a detailed and spatially disaggregated analysis for this region. Future efforts will also be conducted to understand and identify the complexity and the  cross-fertilisation of different creative jobs working in other industries than the CIs (Bakhshi and McVittie 2009; Cerisola 2018a, b; Innocenti and Lazzeretti 2019). Policy implications from our results point to the importance of achieving a critical mass of creative activities as a necessary condition for attracting firm entries from these industries. However, from a territorial cohesion point of view, is not a desirable to reinforce excessive concentration of CIs in and around main urban areas. Thus, given (i) the uneven spatial distribution of CIs entries in French departments and (ii) the fact that the most populated departments (where most CIs locate) are the ones receiving the most public funding and support for cultural and creative activities, less populated (rural) areas might benefit little from the potential of CIs for economic development and sustain- able growth. Thus, there is room for policy interventions which can support CIs in these (peripheral) areas. In fact, the COVID-19 pandemic and its immedi- ate consequences (i.e. shutdowns, economic slowdown, physical distance) may impact the activity and location choices of CIs firms. At the same time, this crisis may provide an opportunity for less urbanised areas to attract the creation of creative firms. We however leave this interesting and promising approaches for further research. Appendix See Tables 7, 8, 9, 10 and 11. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 7 Selection model tests Model 1 (All firms) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 151,752.47 151,823.42 − Negative binomial 8,023.16 8,023.16 − Zero-inflated Poisson 151,756.47 151,756.47 − Zero-inflated negative binomial 8027.165 8110.64 − Model 2 (Creative) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 12,696.39 12,767.79 − Negative binomial 5,245.14 5,245.14 − Zero-inflated Poisson 12,700.79 12,780.09 − Zero-inflated negative binomial 5.249.14 6165.74 −1.72 Model 3 (Non-Creative) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 163,629.84 163,708.25 − Negative binomial 9486.6961 9,569.4622 − Zero-inflated Poisson 163,629.84 163,708.25 − Zero-inflated negative binomial 9,490.6961 9582.1744 − ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 8 Selection model’s Model 1 (Sound) AIC BIC Vuong test tests for Creative Industries Subgroups Poisson 2580.85 2651.81 − Negative binomial 2285.78 2360.91 − Zero-inflated Poisson 2431.36 2510.66 3.27*** Zero-inflated negative binomial 2217.01 2,300.49 3.51*** Model 2 (Life) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 3916.10 3987.05 − Negative binomial 3277.68 3352.81 − Zero-inflated Poisson 3914.82 3994.12 0.77 Zero-inflated negative binomial 3281.68 3365.16 0 Model 3 (Craft) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 3414.11 3485.06 − Negative binomial 3086.04 3161.17 − Zero-inflated Poisson 3415.13 3494.43 0.66 Zero-inflated negative binomial 3090.04 3173.52 0 Model 4 (Other) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 5635.51 4157.26 − Negative binomial 5706.47 4232.39 − Zero-inflated Poisson − − − Zero-inflated negative binomial − − − Model 5 (Audio-visuals) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 6503.13 6581.54 − Negative binomial 4559.39 4642.15 − Zero-inflated Poisson 6495.85 6582.97 0.91 Zero-inflated negative binomial 4563.39 4654.86 −0.88 Model 6 (Publishing) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 3,974.44 4,052.85 − Negative binomial 3,360.88 3,443.65 − Zero-inflated Poisson 3,816.52 3,903.64 3.79*** Zero-inflated negative binomial 3,308.36 3,399.84 2.84** Model 7 (Advertising) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 6011.27 6089.68 − Negative binomial 4415.87 4498.64 − Zero-inflated Poisson 5981.14 6068.26 0.61 Zero-inflated negative binomial 4404.32 4495.80 0.5 Model 8 (Videogames) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 2508.96 2587.37 − Negative binomial 2377.21 2459.98 − Zero-inflated Poisson 2339.90 2427.03 4.78*** Zero-inflated negative binomial 2280.41 2371.89 4.67*** ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 9 Summary statistics Variable Description Source Obs Mean Std. Dev Min Max entry_t Number of total firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 4251.9 3125.7 477.0 14,608.0 entry_crea Number of creative firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 228.0 222.9 22.0 1623.0 entry_noncrea Number of non-creative firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 4027.7 2925.2 453.0 13,849.0 entry_sound Number of sound recording firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 6.8 11.7 0.0 96.0 entry_life Number of life performance firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 25.7 25.1 0.0 166.0 entry_craft Number of arts craft firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 17.9 15.3 0.0 83.0 entry_other Number of other music and arts firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 66.6 45.6 6.0 264.0 entry_audio Number of audio-visual firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 57.3 68.5 1.0 545.0 entry_pub Number of publishing firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 14.7 30.8 0.0 322.0 entry_adv Number of advertising firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 44.9 54.5 0.0 472.0 entry_videogames Number of videogames firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 6.3 13.3 0.0 123.0 Human capital Number of secondary students for 1000 inhabitantshttp:// www. colle ctivi tes- local es. gouv. fr/ 480 82.1 7.4 61.8 99.8 pop_density Population per squared km on 1st January Eurostat 480 559.7 2454.0 14.8 21,347.0 Income Disposable income in €/inhabitanthttp:// www. colle ctivi tes- local es. gouv. fr/ 480 12,820.6 4912.0 821.1 53,829.0 Manufacturing Manufacturing employment rate Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.4 Unemployment Unemployment ratehttp:// www. colle ctivi tes- local es. gouv. fr/ 480 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 Public investment Actual investment expenditure in € / inhabhttp:// www. colle ctivi tes- local es. gouv. fr/ 480 238.9 79.7 66.8 666.6 LQ_creative Location Quotient in Creative Industries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.6 0.5 0.2 3.7 LQ_sound Location Quotient in Sound Recording Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.3 0.8 0.0 7.5 LQ_life Location Quotient in Life Performance Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.6 0.5 0.0 4.1 LQ_craft Location Quotient in Arts Craft Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.9 1.8 0.0 13.2 LQ_other Location Quotient in Other Music and Arts Activities Own elaboration with INSEE 480 1.1 0.6 0.1 3.9 LQ_audio Location Quotient in Audio-visual Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.5 0.6 0.1 4.8 LQ_pub Location Quotient in Publishing Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.5 0.6 0.1 5.4 LQ_adv Location Quotient in Advertising Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.6 0.4 0.0 3.9 LQ_videogames Location Quotient in Videogames Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.5 0.7 0.0 4.2 dist_paris Distance in km from the capital of Department to Paris Own elaboration 480 353.5 205.5 0 918.9 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. 1 3 Table 9 (continued) Variable Description Source Obs Mean Std. Dev Min Max Rain Cumulate rain in a year in mm Eider—French Government 480 800.5 204.5 423.2 1625.3 Sun Cumulate sunny time in hours Eider—French Government 570 1973.2 385.3 73.1 3058.0 Cinema Number of cinemas CNC Eider—French Government 480 21.2 14.1 3.0 88.0 Museums Number of museums INSEE 480 12.7 8.7 2.0 59.0 Source: Authors Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 10 Correlation of main explanatory variables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 1. Human capital 1 2. Pop_density 0.1255* 1 3. Income 0.3447* 0.4078* 1 4. Manufacturing −0.1804* −0.3672* −0.2838* 1 5. Unemployment 0.1233* −0.0707 0.0289 −0.1363* 1 6. Public investment −0.1934* −0.1887* −0.3543* −0.0776 −0.1754* 1 7. LQ_creative 0.2000* 0.8446* 0.4591* −0.4485* −0.0771 −0.1566* 1 8. dist_paris −0.2999* −0.3144* −0.1670* −0.2824* 0.1562* 0.3689* −0.2359* 1 9. Rain −0.0936* −0.1638* 0.0197 0.2155* −0.0563 0.0051 −0.2242* 0.2175* 1 10. Sun −0.1187* −0.1281* −0.0182 −0.4306* 0.2231* 0.3041* −0.0213 0.6739* −0.1226* 1 11. Cinema 0.5033* 0.5203* 0.4242* −0.4691* −0.0765 −0.1715* 0.5744* 0.0112 0.0235 0.1002* 1 12. Museums 0.3500* 0.4692* 0.3542* −0.2476* 0.1219* −0.2563* 0.5117* −0.0975* −0.1122* 0.0597 0.6372* 1 Source: Authors. Significance level: *p < 0.05 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 11 Creative Industries Classification CIs subgroups Sectors Code APE- NAF Rev. 2 Cinema & Audio-visuals Reproduction of sound recording 1820Z (audiovisuals) Production of films and shows for television 5911A Production of institutional and advertising films 5911B Production of film for cinema 5911C Post-production of films and shows for television 5912Z Distribution of cinematographic films 5913A Editing and distribution of videotapes 5913B Projection of cinematographic films 5914Z Broadcasting and distribution of radio shows 6010Z Broadcasting of generalist channels 6020A Broadcasting of theme channels 6020B Photographic activities 7420Z Sound recording (sound) Sound recording and music editing 5920Z Life performance (life) Life performing arts 9001Z Life performing arts supporting activities 9002Z Arts craft (craft) Arts and crafts artistic creation 9003A Other artistic activities Other activities related to artistic creation 9003B (other) Other activities related to entertainment 9329Z Publishing (publishing) Publishing of books 511Z Publishing of newspapers 5813Z Magazine publishing 5814Z Other publishing activities 5819Z Other news agencies activities 6391Z Advertising (advertising) Advertising agencies activities 7311Z Management of advertising media 7312Z Videogames (videogames) Publishing of videogames 5821A Publishing of software systems 5829A Publishing of software for development tools and languages 5829B Publishing applicative software 5829C Source: Authors following APUR-INSEE classification Acknowledgements We would like to acknowledge the fruitful comments of the participants at the 55ème Colloque de l’ASRDLF (Caen, 2018) and at the 1st International workshop Rethinking Clusters: Critical issues and new trajectories of cluster research (Florence, 2018). Any errors are, of course, our own. Funding Open Access funding provided thanks to the CRUE-CSIC agreement with Springer Nature. This paper was partially funded by ECO2017-88888-P, the “Xarxa de Referència d’R + D + I en Eco- nomia i Polítiques Públiques”, the SGR programme (2014 SGR 299) of the Catalan Government, the “Departament d’Universitats, Recerca i Societat de la Informació de la Generalitat de Catalunya” FI Fel- lowship (2017 FI_B 00223) and the “Fundación SGAE”. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Declarations Conflict of interest No potential competing interest was reported by the authors. Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http:// creat iveco mmons. org/ licen ses/ by/4. 0/. References Abdesselam R, Bonnet J, Renou-Maissant P (2014) Typology of the French regional development: revealing the refugee versus Schumpeter effects in new-firm start-ups. Appl Econ 46(28):3437–3451 Acs Z, And DS, Hessels J (2008) Entrepreneurship, economic development and institutions. Small Bus Econ 31:219–234 Acs Z, Braunerhjelm P, Audretsch DB, Carlsson B (2009) The knowledge spillover theory of entrepre- neurship. Small Bus Econ 32:15–30 Andersson M, Koster S (2010) Sources of persistence in regional start-up rates—evidence from Sweden. J Econo Geogr 11(1):179–201 APUR (2014) Nouveaux regards sur l’économie à Paris. Quelques filières d’avenir: Industries creatives/ numérique/mode-design/écoactivités. APUR, Paris. Arauzo-Carod JM (2021) Location determinants of high-tech firms: an intra-urban approach. Ind Innov 28(10):1225–1248 Arauzo-Carod JM, Segarra-Blasco A (2005) The determinants of entry are not independent of start-up size: some evidence from Spanish Manufacturing. Rev Ind Organ 27:147–165 Arauzo-Carod JM, Teruel-Carrizosa M (2005) An urban approach to firm entry: the effect of urban size. Growth Chang 36(4):508–528 Arauzo-Carod JM, Liviano-Solis D, Manjón-Antolín M (2010) Empirical studies in industrial location: an assessment of their methods and results. J Reg Sci 50(3):685–711 Arcuri G, Brunetto M, Levratto N (2019) Spatial patterns and determinants of firm exit: an empirical analysis on France. Ann Reg Sci 62:99–116. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1007/ s00168- 018- 0887-0 Armington C, Acs Z (2002) The determinants of regional variation in new firms’ formation. Reg Stud 36(1):33–45 Aubry M, Bonnet J, Renou-Maissant P (2015) Entrepreneurship and the business cycle: the “Schum- peter” effect versus the “refugee” effect—a French appraisal based on regional data. Ann Reg Sci 54(1):23–55 Audretsch DB (1995) Innovation and industry evolution. The MIT Press, Cambridge Audretsch DB, Belitski M (2013) The missing pillar: the creativity theory of knowledge spillover entre- preneurship. Small Bus Econ 41(4):819–836 Audretsch DB, Fritsch M (1999) The Industry component of regional new firm formation processes. Rev Ind Organ 15:239–252 Bakhshi H, McVittie E (2009) Creative supply-chain linkages and innovation: do the creative industries stimulate business innovation in the wider economy? Innovation 11(2):169–189 Barois B (2020) Le rôle attractif des industries créatives et culturelles dans la localisation des jeunes en France. Region Et Developpement 51:45–64 Bertacchini E, Borrione P (2013) The Geography of the Italian creative economy: the special role of the design and craft-based industries. Reg Stud 47(2):135–147 Bille T, Schulze GG (2006) Culture in urban and regional development. In: Ginsburgh VA, Throsby D (eds) Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, Vol. 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Boix R, Hervás-Oliver JL, De Miguel-Molina B (2015) Micro-geographies of creative industries clusters in Europe: from hot spots to assemblages. Pap Reg Sci 94(4):753–773 Boix R, Capone F, De Propris L, Lazzeretti L, Sanchez D (2016) Comparing creative industries in Europe. Euro Urban Regional Stud 23(4):935–940 Bosma N, Schutjens V (2011) Understanding regional variation in entrepreneurial activity and entrepre- neurial attitude in Europe. Ann Reg Sci 47:711–742 Brixy U (2014) The significance of entry and exit for regional productivity growth. Reg Stud 48(6):1051–1070 Cameron AC, Trivedi PK (1998) Regression analysis of count data. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Cameron AC, Trivedi PK (2005) Microeconometrics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Cerisola S (2018a) Creativity and local economic development: the role of synergy among different tal- ents. Pap Reg Sci 97(2):199–215 Cerisola S (2018b) Multiple creative talents and their determinants at the local level. J Cult Econ 42(2):243–269 Chantelot S (2010a) La géographie de la classe créative : une application aux aires urbaines françaises. Canadian Journal of Regional Science - Revue Canadienne Des Sciences Régionales 33(3):89–108 Chantelot S (2010b) Vers une mesure de la créativité: la construction de la classe créative française. Revue D’économie Régionale Et Urbaine 3:511–540 Chantelot S, Peres S, Virol S (2010) The geography of French creative class: An exploratory spatial data analysis. Cahiers du GREThA 2010–16 Cléron É, Patureau F (2007) L’emploi dans les professions culturelles en 2005. Culture Chiffres 8:1–7 Coll-Martínez E (2019) Creativity and the city: testing the attenuation of agglomeration economies in Barcelona. J Cult Econ 43(3):365–395 Coll-Martínez E, Arauzo-Carod JM (2017) Creative milieu and firm location: an empirical appraisal. Environ Plan A 49(7):1613–1641 Coll-Martínez E, Moreno-Monroy A, Arauzo-Carod JM (2019) Agglomeration of Creative Industries: an Intra-metropolitan analysis for Barcelona. Pap Reg Sci 98(1):409–431 Cruz S, Teixeira AAC (2014) The determinants of spatial location of creative industries start-ups: evi- dence from Portugal using a discrete choice model approach. FEP Working Papers, University of Porto, Working Paper 546. De Propris L (2013) How are creative industries weathering the crisis? Cambridge Journal of Regions. Econ Soc 6(1):23–35 Dunne T, Roberts MJ, Samuelson L (1988) Patterns of firm entry and exit in U.S. Manufacturing indus- tries. RAND J Econ 19(4):495–515. Elert N (2014) What determines entry? Evidence from Sweden. Ann Reg Sci 53:55–92 Elhorst JP, Fréret S (2009) Evidence of political yardstick competition in France using a two-regime spa- tial Durbin model with fixed effects. J Reg Sci 49(5):931–951 Faggian A, Comunian R, Jewell S, Kelly U (2013) Bohemian graduates in the UK: disciplines and loca- tion determinants of creative careers. Reg Stud 47:183–200 Fahmi FZ, Koster S, van Dijk J (2016) The location of creative industries in a developing country: the case of Indonesia. Cities 59:66–79 Florida R (2002) The rise of the creative class, and how it’s transforming work, leisure, community and everyday life. Basic Books, New York Florida R (2005) Cities and the creative class. Routledge, London Fotopoulos G, Louri H (2000) Location and Survival of new entry. Small Bus Econ 14:311–321 Fritsch M (2008) How does new business formation affect regional development? Introduction to the spe- cial issue. Small Bus Econ 30(1):1–14 Günalp B, Cilasun SM (2006) Determinants of Entry in Turkish manufacturing industries. Small Bus Econ 27:275–287 Gutierrez-Posada D, Kitsos T, Nathan M, Nuccio M (2021) Do creative industries generate multiplier effects? Evidence from UK cities, 1997–2018. Creative Industries Policy & Evidence Centre, Dis- cussion Paper 2021/07 Guimarães P, Figueiredo O, Woodward D (2000) Agglomeration and the location of foreign direct invest- ment in Portugal. J Urban Econ 47(1):115–135. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1006/ juec. 1999. 2138 Hall P (2000) Creative cities and economic development. Urban Stud 37:639–649 Heiss F (2002) Structural choice analysis with nested logit models. Stand Genomic Sci 2(3):227–252 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Hong E, Lee IH, Sun L, Harrison R (2015) Entrepreneurship across time and space: empirical evidence from Korea. Small Bus Econ 44:705–719 Hsiao C (2014) Analysis of panel data. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge IFM (2013) The Economic Importance of Creative French Fashion Companies, Fédération française de la Couture. du Prêt-à-Porter des Couturiers et des Créateurs de Mode, Paris Innocenti N, Lazzeretti L (2019) Do the creative industries support growth and innovation in the wider economy? Industry relatedness and employment growth in Italy. Ind Innov 26(10):1152–1173 De Jong JPJ, Fris P, Stam E (2007) Creative industries–heterogeneity and connection with regional firm entry. EIM Business and Policy Research: Zoetermeer. Julien P (2002) Onze fonctions pour qualifier les grandes villes, Insee Première 840, March. Kangasharju A (2000) Regional variations in firm formation: panel and cross-section data evidence from Finland. Pap Reg Sci 79:355–373 Karahasan BC (2015) Dynamics of regional new firm formation in Turkey. Rev Urban Reg Dev Stud 27(1):18–39 Kiroff L (2017) Auckland and the creative industries: the spatial distribution of the design subsector. Urban Geogr 38(10):1573–1602 Lazzeretti L, Boix R, Capone F (2008) Do creative industries cluster? Mapping creative local production systems in Italy and Spain. Ind Innov 15(5):549–567 Lazzeretti L, Capone F, Boix R (2012) Reasons for clustering of creative industries in Italy and Spain. Eur Plan Stud 20(8):1243–1262 Lee SY, Florida R, Acs Z (2004) Creativity and entrepreneurship: a regional analysis of new firm forma- tion. Reg Stud 38(8):879–891. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1080/ 00343 40042 00028 0910 Long JS (1997) Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables (Advanced Quanti- tative Techniques in the Social Sciences). Sage Publications, London Méndez-Ortega C, Arauzo-Carod JM (2019) Locating software, video game and editing electronics firms: using microgeographic data to Study Barcelona. J Urban Technol 26(3):81–9 Méndez-Ortega C, Arauzo-Carod JM (2020) Do Software and Video game firms share location patterns across cities? Evidence from Barcelona, Lyon and Hamburg. Ann Reg Sci 64:641–666 Moriset B (2003) The new economy in the city: emergence and location factors of internet-based compa- nies in the metropolitan area of Lyon, France. Urban Stud 40(11):2165–2186 Myerscough J (1988) The Economic Importance of the Arts in Glasgow. Policy Studies Institute, London Noseleit F (2015) The role of entry and market selection for the dynamics of regional diversity and spe- cialization. Reg Stud 49(1):76–94 Nyström K (2007) Interdependencies in the dynamics of firm entry and exit. J Ind Compet Trade 7(2):113–130 Orr D (1974) The determinants of entry: a study of the Canadian manufacturing industries. Rev Econ Stat 56(1):58–66 Pareja-Eastaway M (2016) Creative industries. J Evol Stud Bus 1:38–50 Piergiovanni R, Carree MA, Santarelli E (2012) Creative industries, new business formation, and regional economic growth. Small Bus Econ 39(3):539–560 Reynolds P, Storey DJ, Westhead P (1994) Cross-national comparisons of the variation in new firm for - mation rates: an editorial overview. Reg Stud 28(4):343–346 Rigby DL, Essletzbichler J (2000) Impacts of industry mix, technological change, selection and plant entry/exit on regional productivity growth. Reg Stud 34(4):333–342 Sanchez-Serra D (2014) Talent and creative economy in French local labour systems. Eviron Plann C Gov Policy 32:405–425 Sanchez-Serra D (2016) Location determinants of creative industries’ firms in Spain. Journal of Regional Research 34:23–48 Sanchez-Serra D (2013) Artistic creative clusters in France: a statistical approach. Territoire en mouve- ment 19/20(2):6–18 Santarelli E, Carrée M, Verheul I (2009) Unemployment and firm entry and exit: an update on a contro- versial relationship. Reg Stud 43(8):1061–1073 Scott AJ (2000) The cultural economy of Paris. Int J Urban Reg Res 24(3):567–582 Scott AJ (2006) Entrepreneurship, innovation and industrial development: geography and the creative field revisited. Small Bus Econ 26(1):1–24 Sensier M, Bristow G, Healy A (2016) Measuring regional economic resilience across Europe: operation- alizing a complex concept. Spat Econ Anal 11(2):128–151 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Smit AJ (2011) The influence of district visual quality on location decisions of creative entrepreneurs. J Am Plann Assoc 77(2):167–184 Stam E, De Jong JPJ, Marlet G (2008) Creative industries in the netherlands: structure, development, innovativeness and effects on urban growth. Geogr Ann: Series B, Human Geogr 90(2):119–132. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1111/j. 1468- 0467. 2008. 00282.x Storey DJ (1991) The birth of new firms—does unemployment matter? A review of the evidence. Small Bus Econ 3(3):167–178 UNCTAD (2008) Creative Economy. Report 2008. UNCTAD, Geneva Wagner J, Sternberg R (2004) Start-up activities, individual characteristics, and the regional milieu: les- sons for entrepreneurship support policies from German micro data. Ann Reg Sci 38(2):219–240. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1007/ s00168- 004- 0193-x Wenting R (2011) Urban amenities and agglomeration economies? The locational behaviour and eco- nomic success of Dutch fashion design entrepreneurs. Urban Studies 48(7):1333–1352 Wojan TR, Lambert DM, McGranahan DA (2007) Emoting with their feet: Bohemian attraction to crea- tive milieu. J Econ Geogr 7(6):711–736 Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. 1 3 http://www.deepdyve.com/assets/images/DeepDyve-Logo-lg.png The Annals of Regional Science Springer Journals

Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative industries: evidence from France

Loading next page...
 
/lp/springer-journals/location-attributes-explaining-the-entry-of-firms-in-creative-wVxuP35AtW

References (103)

Publisher
Springer Journals
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2023
ISSN
0570-1864
eISSN
1432-0592
DOI
10.1007/s00168-022-01196-w
Publisher site
See Article on Publisher Site

Abstract

This paper focuses on creative industries and the role played by the existing spatial distribution and agglomeration economies of these activities in relation to their entry decisions. We rely on employment and firm-level data in the creative industries (provided by INSEE) and compare the location of new establishments in the creative and non-creative industries between 2009 and 2013 in French departments (NUTS 3 regions). We use count data models and spatial econometrics to show that location determinants are rather similar in creative and non-creative industries and that specialisation in creative industries positively influences the entry of all other industries. The French case provides new insights to understand the geographical patterns of creative industries. JEL Classification R39 · Z100 1 Introduction Considerable attention has been devoted in the economic literature to the factors that influence the location decisions of new firms (Arauzo-Carod et  al. 2010). Existing work attempts to identify and quantify the determinants of entry and tends to focus * Josep-Maria Arauzo-Carod josepmaria.arauzo@urv.cat * Eva Coll-Martínez eva.coll-martinez@sciencespo-toulouse.fr Camelia Turcu camelia.turcu@univ-orleans.fr Laboratoire d’Économie d’Orléans, Université d’Orléans, Rue de Blois, BP 26739, 45067 Orléans, France Sciences Po Toulouse, Manufacture Des Tabacs, LEREPS, Université de Toulouse, 21 Allée de Brienne - CS 88526, 31685 Toulouse cedex 6, France ECO-SOS & QURE, Departament d’Economia, Universitat Rovira I Virgili, Av. Universitat, 1, 43204 Reus, Catalonia, Spain Vol.:(0123456789) 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. either on specified industries aggregated over regions or, conversely, on aggregated industry sectors (manufacturing, services) in specific geographical regions. More detailed analyses, with both industries and regions being specified, would be of great interest in helping to elucidate spatial and industry-specific characteristics. These, however, are much scarcer. In addition, in developed countries there are some activities that have noticeably seen an increase in weight in overall economic activity very recently. Unfortunately, however, they have not received enough attention from the academic community in order to understand forces driving entry of firms and, especially, their location deci- sions when choosing among alternative territories. This paper, therefore, focuses on Creative Industries (CIs), a group of industries linked to cultural, creative, and high- tech activities that have experienced high growth rates in recent years and that have relevant positive externalities (Sanchez-Serra 2014). They contribute to knowledge generation and the prestige of areas specialised in these activities (Myerscough, 1988). This, in turn, may attract other firms and economic activity (Gutierrez-Posada et  al. 2021; Bille and Schulze 2006), boost regional employment growth (Piergiovanni et al. 2012) and the productivity of existent firms (Coll-Martinez and Arauzo-Carod 2019). Key works highlighting the positive perception of CIs include two contributions by Florida (2005, 2002), who he has provided a measure of a “creative class” and a first (qualitative) attempt to quantify its contribution over economic activity. The current understanding of CI entry determinants is quite limited and further work is necessary on the processes that drive their entry. This paper aims to par- tially address this gap by analysing the French case at the province (département, or NUTS 3) level. This is of special interest in view of the importance of CIs in terms of (i) the number of firms and employees (IFM 2013), (ii) the growth of workforce in CIs (Chantelot 2010a), (iii) the strong export profile of firms, and (iv) the fact that (despite some concentration in the Paris region), there is a relatively well-balanced territorial distribution—despite being noticeably heterogeneous, all departments generate and attract new CIs. In addition, French CIs have a worldwide reputation since they include some globally prominent actors in areas that include fashion design, arts and entertainment, and publishing (Scott 2000; APUR 2014). There are also important inter-industry linkages arising from CIs as they contribute to the prestige of certain areas and attract firms from quite different and unrelated industries (Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017). Understanding what determines CI location choices is crucial in designing public policies aiming at attracting inno- vative firms to French regions. Our econometric results, obtained using Panel Count Data Models for French departments, suggest that on average, the probability of a creative firm locating in a French department increases with the amount of human capital, disposable income per inhabitant, the unemployment rate, a number of cultural amenities such as museums and cinemas. This probability diminishes with the share of manufacturing activities, public investment per inhabitant, distance to Paris, and weather factors The list of specific activities included among CIs is quite wide but, in general terms, the following are considered: Arts, Advertising, Cinema, Fashion, Publishing, R&D, and Software. See Sect. 4 (Data) for details and Table 9 for the complete list of industries. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… (proxied by cumulative rainfall). We found that both creative and non-creative firms are positively influenced by the specialisation level of creative industries. However, when considering neighbouring effects, the impact of CIs does not extend beyond the borders of the department. The paper is organised as follows. In the second section, we discuss theoretical and empirical contributions regarding firm entry and CIs, and we focus on those that specifically analyse entries in these industries and that consider spatial factors. In the third section, we present the methodology and the econometric specification. In the fourth section, we describe the data and variables. In the fifth section, we discuss the main results. We present our conclusions in the sixth and final section. 2 Literature review: firm entry and CIs Understanding firm entry decisions is becoming more and more relevant for policy makers as new firms are commonly hypothesised to be drivers of a wide range of positive effects that include local and regional development (Acs et  al. 2009), regional diversity (Noseleit 2015), technological change (Rigby and Essletzbichler 2000), productivity growth (Brixy 2014) and innovation (Audretsch 1995). Initially, the analysis of these decisions focused solely on the industry-specific determinants without including a spatial dimension (Orr 1974). Spatial asymmetries, however, make some territories significantly more attractive than others and, since the mid- nineties, the spatial dimension has received more attention (Reynolds et al. 1994). Accordingly, empirical contributions focusing on aggregate firm entries (typically restricted to manufacturing industries but, to some extent, also to services) have identified several spatially specific entry determinants. The most well-known of these are agglomeration economies (Fotopoulos and Louri 2000), entrepreneurial attitude (Bosma and Schutjens 2011), firm structure (Arauzo-Carod and Segarra-Blasco 2005; Kangasharju 2000), population size (Armington and Acs 2002), institutional quality (Acs et  al. 2008), income (Elert 2014), human capital (Armington and Acs 2002), persistence of previous entries (Andersson and Koster 2010), and labour market characteristics (Santarelli et al. 2009). In the literature, “traditional” manufacturing or service activities have attracted much more attention than have CIs. When the latter were analysed, that attention has often been solely put on their role as magnets for other activities (Hall 2000), as promoters of firm entries (De Jong et al. 2007), or as tools for economic growth (De Propris 2013; Piergiovanni et  al. 2012), rather than on the specific entry determinants for these industries. Nevertheless, empirical contributions on the location determinants for CIs do exist. These include the works of Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod (2017) for Catalan municipalities, Coll-Martínez et  al. (2019) for Barcelona at the intra-urban level, Kiroff (2017) for the design subsector in Auckland, Sanchez-Serra (2016) for Spanish travel-to-work areas, Boix et  al. (2015) for a selection of European metropolitan areas, Wenting (2011) for fashion design firms in the Netherlands, Smit (2011) for three Dutch cities, Bertacchini and Borrione (2013) for Italian regions and Cruz and Teixeira (2014) for Portuguese municipalities. 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Although the methodologies, geographical areas and the research focus of these studies differ considerably, some common key location determinants have been identified. Specifically, as distinct from traditional agglomeration economies (Sanchez-Serra 2016), specialisation in CIs is a strong determinant for entries of both creative and non-creative firms (Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod, 2017). Similarly, there is empirical evidence indicating that all types of firms benefit from the existence of an intangible creative milieu favouring entries (Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017; Wojan et  al. 2007) as well as creative externalities (Sanchez- Serra 2016). Previous results highlight the strong interindustry linkages between creative and non-creative industries that enhance the positive effects of the former over the latter. In this sense, recent contributions highlight that only the cross- fertilisation of different creative talents working in different fields may stimulate creativity, ultimately enhancing regional development (Bakhshi and McVittie 2009; Cerisola 2018a, b; Innocenti and Lazzeretti 2021). Empirical evidence also indicates a strong preference for CI co-located clusters where there are also non-creative activities (Boix et al. 2015). In terms of the locational preferences of CIs, they tend to agglomerate in metropolitan areas (Boix et al. 2015; Sanchez-Serra 2013, 2014) and, within that, try to benefit from agglomeration economies by concentrating close to core neighbourhoods (Coll-Martínez et  al. 2019). Some, however, give more emphasis to urban amenities (Wenting 2011). Despite the interest of this topic in general and its specific importance for French creative and cultural markets, empirical evidence for France is unfortunately still scarce. Notable exceptions are Sanchez-Serra (2014, 2013). Sanchez-Serra (2013) focuses on the clustering of creative clusters at travel-to-work areas (Zones d’Emploi) and identifies 63 artistic creative local labour systems, showing that creative employ - ment is clearly more concentrated than is total employment, especially in and around big urban areas. Sanchez-Serra (2014) identifies creative clusters in France and their determinants, finding that the existence of information and communication technology jobs, education and the presence of foreign-born workers positively stimulate crea- tive clustering. In the same line, Barois (2020) studies the link between the weight of creative and cultural activities in the territories and the attractiveness of the population showing that young workers and students prefer to locate in areas where the weight of the creative and cultural industries is important. Finally, although Chantelot (2010a) focuses on CI workforce rather than on firm entries, he identifies urban amenities and market opportunities as being among the main determinants of CI workforce concen- tration in large French urban areas. 3 Methods 3.1 Model specification There is a degree of consensus that entry determinants are industry-specific (Audretsch and Fritsch 1999) and, more specifically, that CIs entries are affected See Chantelot (2010b) for an analysis of French creative class in terms of workforce. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… by creativity-specific factors (see for instance, Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017; Sanchez-Serra 2016; Cruz and Teixeira 2014; Lazzeretti et al. 2012). Among these, the median household income (income) (the income elasticity of demand for cultural assets tends to be high) and higher levels of public investment in cultural issues (public_investment) should favour CIs location. Their location decision is also determined by residential amenities that in this paper are proxied by the following variables: the average number of days of sun (sun) and cumulative rain in mm (rain), that are expected to capture natural amenities, and the number of cinemas (cinemas) and museums (museums), that are expected to capture cultural amenities. Finally, areas that are more specialised in CIs (LQ_creative) should favour the entry of all kinds of firms because of the existence of knowledge spillovers in terms of creativity and innovation, as shown in Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod (2017), and also should be more able to attract new firms because of the agglomeration advantages (localisation economies) created by the co-location of creative firms (Stam et  al. 2008; De Jong et al. 2007; Lee et al. 2004; Scott 2000, 2006). CIs also consider traditional location determinants (see Arauzo-Carod et  al. 2010, for an extensive review). Among them, education (human_capital) and agglomeration economies (in this paper proxied by population density: pop_ density) are important location factors whatever characteristics a firm may have. Share of manufacturing activities (manufacturing) is another well-known location determinant that fosters entries. Several different theories suggest that unemployment rates (unemployment) influence location decisions. Some studies show that high unemployment rates favour the creation of firms because of the lack of employment alternatives (Wagner and Sternberg 2004). However, other authors argue that high unemployment rates are linked to economic recession and, therefore, lower levels of consumption (Reynolds et  al. 1994; Aubry et  al. 2015) that in turn deter entries. Finally, geography and institutional issues matter (Guimarães et  al. 2000), as firms need easy access to services provided in cores—hence, we need to control for distance to main cities such as Paris (dist_paris). Moreover, proximity to the most important city of a country may capture, on the one hand, a potential competition effect in view of agglomeration of firms in the area and, on the other hand, a competitive advantage in terms of the services and amenities located in and around the city. To analyse the determinants of CIs location decisions and their relationship with the CIs specialisation, we estimated the number of new establishments as a function of the specific local characteristics, in Eq. (1): Firm entries =  +  human_capital +  pop_density it 0 1 it 2 it +  income +  manufacturing 3 it 4 it +  unemployment +  public_investment (1) 5 it 6 it +  LQ_creative +  dist_paris +  rain 7 it 8 it 9 it +  sun +  cinema +  museums + u 10 it 11 it 12 it it where Firm entries is the number of firms located in area i across the period t. Our it empirical strategy consists in estimating eight different models that share the same set 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. of explanatory variables with different dependent variables (Firm entries ): all firms it (entry_t), non-creative firms (entry_noncrea), creative firms (entry_crea), cinema and audiovisuals firms (entry_audio), sound recording (entry_sound), life performance (entry_life), arts craft (entry_craft), other music activities (entry_other), publishing firms (entry_pub), advertising firms (entry_adv) and videogames firms (entry_vide- ogames). This strategy allows us to compare the location determinants of the group of firms considered, with particular focus on the impact of the specialisation in CIs. 3.2 Model selection Most contributions in this field rely on cross section data, although a significant number use panel data approaches that cover a wide range of countries and entry typologies. Among them, for instance, we highlight the work of Hong et  al. (2015) for Korea; Karahasan (2015) and Günalp and Cilasun (2006) for Turkey; Abdesselam et al. (2014) for France; Elert (2014) and Nyström (2007) for Sweden; Arauzo-Carod and Teruel-Carrizosa (2005) for Spain; Kangasharju (2000) for Finland, or Dunne et al. (1988) for the U.S. Using panel data offers some advantages over cross section data (Hsiao 2014). For instance, the possibility of introducing standard fixed effects in the regression potentially reduces the correlation effects of the explanatory variables with unobservables (which are difficult to control with cross section data). Thus, one of the main contributions of this paper is to provide evidence on CIs location determinants by using panel data. Concretely, in this paper, we use Count Data Models to analyse the determinants of CIs location choices. The number of firm entries in a given region (in this paper, French departments) is a nonnegative integer (count) variable that is better estimated by techniques other than ordinary least squares (OLS) which can lead to biased, inefficient and inconsistent estimates (Long 1997). Count Data Models (CDM) have commonly been used when dealing with the location phenomenon from a spatial point of view: i.e. when trying to explain how the local characteristics of different sites (e.g. municipalities, counties, regions) can influence firms’ decisions (Arauzo-Carod et  al. 2010). These CDM include the Poisson Model (PM), the Negative Binomial Model (NBM), the Zero Inflated Poisson Model (ZIPM) and the Zero Inflated Negative Binomial Model (ZINBM). Although PM is the most popular CDM, it has two econometrical limits, “overdispersion” and “excess zeroes”. Since these problems may be solved using NBM, ZIPM and ZINBM, we follow Cameron and Trivedi (1998, 2005) in order to determine which of them is the most appropriate. To do this, we compute the following statistics: the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC), the Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC) and the Vuong test. The descriptive statistics of the dependent variables in the firm entry model showed signs of overdispersion but, since there is at least one establishment (except for publishing and videogames industries) located in each department, there is Specifically, zeroes were 6.94% for publishing and 30% for videogames entries. The key variable LQ_creative is replaced in each model for a LQ in each subgroup of CIs, that is, LQ_audio, LQ_sound, LQ_life, LQ_craft, LQ_other, LQ_pub, LQ_adv and LQ_videogames. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… not a zero-inflation problem. For this reason, we estimated a baseline specification using CDM and selected the specification with the best fit according to the above statistics. Tables  7 and 8 illustrate the results for these statistics and show that the NBM performed best according to AIC and BIC. The only exceptions are found for sound recording, publishing and videogames since the AIC, BIC and the Vuong test also favoured the ZINBM over the NBM. Nevertheless, the percentage of zeroes was not big enough to justify using an inflated model. Thus, we decided to use the NBM—for panel data and time fixed effects—for all the firm entry specifications, except for sound recording, publishing and videogames. As shown by many previous studies, neighbouring effects can be important. If the effects of the determinants of firm location decisions extend beyond departments, and this possible spatial dependence is not considered, then results may be biased and inconsistent. To account for spatial dependence, we also considered the spatially lagged variables of the independent variables (Spatial Lagged Model in the X (SLX)). These were estimated as: W_Z = WZ, where Z is a matrix that contains the independent variables and W is a row-standardised contiguity weighting matrix, an approach that has already been used in previous contributions for the case of French metropolitan départements (see for instance, Elhorst and Fréret 2009). 4 Data 4.1 Data sources All data in this paper relate to the 96 NUTS 3 departments of metropolitan France and include the location of new establishments (dependent variable) and a set of territorial characteristics (independent variables). The sources for the location of new establishments are the Répertoire des Entreprises et des Établissemetns (REE) and the Système Informatique pour le Répertoire des Entreprises et de leurs Établissements (SIRENE), supplied by the Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques (INSEE). These sources provide comprehensive information on the location of establishments (both manufacturing and services) in France between 2009 and 2013, including geographical information (at regional and department levels), employment data, and other characteristics at the 4-digit NAF level. The local characteristics of French departments are taken from different sources such as INSEE, the French Government and Eurostat. Table  9 shows some descriptive statistics (see Table 10 for the main correlation results for these variables). Regarding the definition of CIs, we use the APUR-INSEE proposal (2014) as it is the official classification of CIs used in France and roughly relies on the UNCTAD’s (2008) proposal, which is the most widely accepted by researchers (see, among oth- ers, Lazzeretti et  al. 2012; Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017). According to Other spatial weighting definitions were considered such as 5 nearest neighbours or an inverse dis- tance-based matrix. Even so, the best fit of the model is obtained when we rely on a row-standardised contiguity weighting matrix, an approach that has already been used in previous contributions for the case of French metropolitan départements (see for instance, Elhorst and Fréret 2009). 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 1 Creative Industries firm entries by year CIs Subgroups 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Cinema and audio-visuals 5292 5349 4925 5787 5697 % in all the CIs 23% 23% 18% 25% 26% Sound recording 635 628 704 806 691 % in all the CIs 3% 3% 3% 3% 3% Life performance 2892 2573 1951 2095 2421 % in all the CIs 13% 11% 7% 9% 11% Arts Craft 2529 2153 1400 1246 1566 % in all the CIs 11% 9% 5% 5% 7% Other artistic activities 6190 7113 6451 7446 6037 % in all the CIs 27% 31% 23% 32% 28% Publishing 1329 1258 1373 1731 1578 % in all the CIs 6% 6% 5% 7% 7% Advertising 3238 3315 10,506 3239 2895 % in all the CIs 14% 14% 38% 14% 13% Videogames 489 477 513 791 815 % in all the CIs 2% 2% 2% 3% 4% All creative industries 22,594 22,866 27,823 23,141 21,700 % in all the economy 5% 5% 7% 6% 6% Non-CIs 399,068 412,649 373,909 387,695 367,551 % in all the economy 95% 95% 93% 94% 94% All industries 421,662 435,515 401,732 410,836 389,251 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% Source: Authors, based on SIRENE data this criterion, we include 29 sectors in CIs, classified into 8 subgroups (cinema and audio-visuals, sound recording, life performance, arts craft, other music activities, publishing, advertising and videogames (see NAF-Rev. 2 industry classification in Table  11). Table  1 illustrates the 2009‒2013 period showing an increasing trend (between 2009 and 2011) followed by a short period of attrition that fits with the economic trend of these years, and Table  2 shows a weak decrease in employment in CIs sectors during the same period. The choice of the time span is driven by data availability at the level of NUTS 3 regions. Nevertheless, it is worth underlying that the considered period in our analysis starts after the Global Financial Crisis that hit France and its regions in 2007–2008, lowering then potential bias due to market turbulence. Hence, we analyse the location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative industries in a context of a certain economic recovery (Sensier et al. 2016; Although the Architecture and Engineering industries are typically included among CIs, we decided to exclude them as they have a very particular location patterns, are concentrated in some departments, and include an important share of nuclear activities (noticeably in Territoire Belfort where there is a cross- border cluster on both sides of the French-Swiss border) which are far away from CIs. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Table 2 Creative Industries employment by year CIs Subgroups 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Cinema and audio-visuals 4953 5076 4646 5357 5315 % in all the CIs 11% 11% 10% 11% 11% Sound recording 3772 3529 3642 3775 3927 % in all the CIs 8% 7% 8% 8% 8% Life performance 20,756 22,984 21,506 20,952 20,687 % in all the CIs 46% 49% 46% 43% 43% Arts Craft 377 337 438 477 505 % in all the CIs 1% 1% 1% 1% 1% Other music activities 10,332 10,669 11,838 12,803 13,299 % in all the CIs 23% 23% 25% 26% 27% Publishing 1158 1125 1193 1568 1447 % in all the CIs 3% 2% 3% 3% 3% Advertising 2944 3067 2765 2903 2608 % in all the CIs 7% 7% 6% 6% 5% Videogames 374 391 432 746 748 % in all the CIs 1% 1% 1% 2% 2% All creative industries 44,666 47,178 46,460 48,581 48,536 % in all the economy 0.31% 0.34% 0.31% 0.32% 0.32% All industries 14,566,204 13,942,865 15,062,343 14,994,756 15,103,455 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% Source: Authors with INSEE data Arcuri et al. 2019) as the economy has moved from negative growth rates (in 2009) to positive ones (over 2010–2013). 4.2 Stylised facts about creative industries and firm location in French Departments Figure 1 compares the location patterns of all firms, non-creative and creative firms. For both years (2009 and 2013), roughly 75% of all firms locate in and around Île- de-France and in the most populated departments such as Nord, Rhône, Bouches- sur-Rhône or Gironde, the same areas where most cultural jobs are located (Cléron and Patureau 2007). Thus, it seems clear that one of the key determinants of a firm’s location decision is the attractiveness of these densely populated areas, specialised labour markets, availability of suppliers and knowledge spillovers. Similar spatial distributions hold for both creative and non-creative firms. Moreover, it has not significantly changed from 2009 to 2013. Although the number of new creative firms has increased over these years, they have kept the same agglomeration pattern around larger cities, as it has been demonstrated by other studies using spatial analysis tools (Chantelot et al. 2010a, b). See Julien (2002) for empirical evidence regarding France. 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Fig. 1 Firm entries by department. Source: Authors with SIRENE data In order to identify location patterns for CIs in French departments, we calculate a Location Quotient (LQ), using employment data (Effectif salarié déclaré par les établissements) taken from INSEE. The same index has been used by other scholars but with different specifications (for example, in Lazzeretti et al. 2012). This index compares the relative specialisation of a department in a sector in relation to the national (France) average and is defined as: LQ_creative =(L ∕L )∕(L ∕L) ij ij j i where L is the workforce in the creative industry j in department i, L is the total ij j workforce in the creative industry j, L is the total workforce in department i, and L is total employment in the area (France). An LQ greater than 1 indicates that the clustering of a creative industry j in department i is larger than the national average, hence the department is specialised in CIs. Figure  2 shows LQ results for the ten most specialised French departments and the spatial distribution of LQ in CIs for 2009 and 2013, respectively. Departments located in the Île-de-France region are the most specialised in CIs (all with values higher than 1). Concretely, Hauts-de-Seine and Paris departments stand out with a LQ greater than 3 for both years. Although, since they have values below 1, the 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Fig. 2 Specialisation in crea- tive industries by department. Source: Authors with INSEE data remaining most populated departments are not specialised in CI’s, nevertheless they comprise most of the creative employment in France. These results have not signifi- cantly changed over these years. 5 Results 5.1 Main results Table  3 shows the results of the econometric estimation of CIs location determi- nants. Negative Binomial estimates are presented for all firm entries, both creative and non-creative, in order to compare the determinants of location decisions of dif- ferent types of industries. In general, for all types of entries, most of the explana- tory variables are significant, but there are some remarkable differences between the creative and non-creative industries. Specifically, population density (a proxy for agglomeration economies) has a negative effect over all industries and non-creative industries, although the coefficient is not significant for CIs. Nevertheless, the role of population density is not clear, as correlation analysis shows a significant and positive relationship with all entries, but especially with those of CIs. This result could be understood in terms of an unknown relationship between the location Chantelot (2010a) analyses determinants of CIs workforce location and reaches a similar result for big urban areas in France. 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 3 Location determinants of firms (NB) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) Firm entries All Creative Non-Creative Human capital 0.023*** 0.026*** 0.023*** (0.008) (0.007) (0.008) pop_density −8.70e − 05** −6.33e − 05 −8.91e − 05** (4.16e − 05) (5.25e − 05) (4.10e − 05) Income 1.27e − 05 1.55e − 05* 1.25e − 05 (7.85e − 06) (8.71e − 06) (7.80e − 06) Manufacturing −1.152** −1.585*** −1.132** (0.481) (0.537) (0.478) Unemployment 4.604** 4.079* 4.636** (2.222) (2.190) (2.224) Public investment −0.001* −0.00102* −0.00109* (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) LQ_creative 0.223* 0.286* 0.217 (0.135) (0.169) (0.132) dist_paris −0.0003 −0.0006** −0.0003 (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0003) Rain −0.0002 −0.0001 −0.0002 (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) Sun 2.37e − 05 3.06e − 05 2.33e − 05 (0.0001) (9.69e − 05) (0.0001) Cinema 0.029*** 0.029*** 0.028*** (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) Museums 0.011** 0.011** 0.011** (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) Constant 5.725*** 2.514*** 5.684*** (0.606) (0.614) (0.606) N 480 480 480 Departments 96 96 96 Time FE Y Y Y Wald X 884.01 1124.97 854.26 Log pseudolikelihood −3993.583 −2575.39 −3969.217 lnalpha −2.452*** −2.393*** −2.452*** (0.141) (0.145) (0.141) Alpha 0.086 0.091 0.086 (0.121) (0.013) (0.121) Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 quotient of CIs and population density, although the influence of density over entries seems to be blurred by other explanatory variables. The aggregated income level of departments also plays a different role as it only boosts the entries of CIs. This may suggest some structural differences in terms of markets: CIs may, for example, 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… target the upper income levels of population. In a similar way, specialisation in CIs (LQ_creative) pushes up entries in CIs and for all firms but has no significant effect on entries of non-creative firms. This result supports our assumption regarding the positive effects of specialisation in CIs in terms of attracting new economic activ - ity, no matter what the industry of the entering firms. Noticeably, departments spe- cialised in CIs are more likely to attract new businesses. In terms of geographical position, a greater distance to Paris deters the entry of creative firms, as they may have more difficulties in establishing networking activities and an access to cultural amenities (that are highly concentrated in the French capital). Despite specific effects at industry level, there are common location determinants that act in a similar way across different types of industries (i.e. creative and non- creative), similarly to previous results also for Catalonia by Arauzo-Carod (2021) and Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod (2017). In this sense, entries in all subgroups are attracted to areas that have more people enrolled in education (this is a neces- sary production factor, no matter the industry), while they are repelled from areas with more manufacturing activity. This result may be explained by the fact that these areas are associated with negative externalities that do not fit with cultural and crea- tive environments. Surprisingly, regional economic conditions favour areas with high unemployment rates and, similarly, those that receive higher levels of public investment. Cultural amenities (i.e. cinema and museums), exert the same positive effect on entries across all firm profiles whilst climate conditions (rain and sun) have no significant effect on entries. Nevertheless, it is important to precise that our approach analyses location determinants for both creative and non-creative indus- tries considering firms included in these categories, but without taking into account the profile of workforce at firm/industry level. In this sense, creative and non-cre- ative jobs coexist in both creative-and-non-creative firms, although with different shares. Negative Binomial estimates are presented in Table 4 for entering firms belonging to sound, life, craft, other, audio-visuals, publishing, advertising, and videogames, in order to compare the determinants of location decision for these CIs. This strategy allows us to analyse the location behaviour of specific CIs, given that overall results may not reveal some heterogeneities due to the locational specificities of each CIs. As expected, many CIs subgroups share most of the location determinants, such as the positive role played by human capital, income and the cultural amenities (i.e. museums and cinema), as well as the negative effect of share of manufactur - ing activity, but there are noticeable differences for other determinants. In particu- lar, we may distinguish between (mostly) cultural oriented and (mostly) technology- oriented subgroups: the former includes arts, sound, life, craft, other activities and Additionally, we tested alternative covariates for proxying proximity to the political power (regional capital), climate conditions (temperature and humidity), natural amenities (coast, forest area and natural parks), tourism activities (lodging size), and diversity (foreign population), but model fit did not improve when they were included, and main results generally remained quite similar. Although the focus of this paper is on creative industries and not on creative jobs, which demands a different type of dataset, there is empirical evidence showing that creative jobs exert positive effects over close local service employment (Gutierrez-Posada et al. 2021). 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. 1 3 Table 4 Location determinants of Creative Industries Subgroups (NB) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Firm entries Sound Life Craft Other Audio-visuals Publishing Advertising Videogames human capital 0.061*** 0.026*** 0.018*** 0.0195*** 0.033*** 0.026*** 0.031*** 0.041*** (0.0099) (0.007) (0.006) (0.007) (0.009) (0.009) (0.008) (0.012) pop_density 7.70e − 05 −5.12e − 05 −3.81e − 05 −7.48e − 05** −7.55e − 05 2.67e − 05 −5.76e − 05 −2.45e − 05 (7.66e − 05) (4.48e − 05) (2.72e − 05) (3.08e − 05) (6.00e − 05) (6.62e − 05) (4.14e − 05) (3.14e − 05) Income 3.34e − 05** 2.11e − 05** 1.54e − 05** 1.28e − 05* 2.28e − 05** 1.94e − 05** 2.38e − 05** 9.34e − 07 (1.30e − 05) (8.37e − 06) (7.42e − 06) (6.94e − 06) (1.05e − 05) (8.76e − 06) (1.09e − 05) (7.18e − 06) manufacturing −5.562*** −1.204* −0.832 −1.142** −2.310*** −3.429*** −2.045*** −4.863*** (0.873) (0.683) (0.560) (0.459) (0.613) (0.823) (0.654) (0.948) Unemployment −4.174 3.826* 5.010** 4.605** 3.583 −4.224 3.161 0.680 (2.686) (2.180) (2.294) (1.877) (2.707) (3.290) (2.383) (4.595) public investment 0.0004 −0.0008 −2.04e − 05 −0.0006 −0.001 −0.0006 −0.001* −0.0013 (0.0009) (0.0006) (0.0006) (0.0005) (0.0007) (0.0009) (0.00067) (0.00103) LQ_$ −0.132 0.193* 0.0151 −0.00144 0.259* 0.0162 0.312** 0.505*** (0.176) (0.109) (0.012) (0.054) (0.135) (0.169) (0.133) (0.067) Dist_paris −0.0004 −0.001*** −0.001*** −0.007** −0.0008** −0.0006 −0.0003 0.0004 (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0006) Rain −0.0001 −0.0001 −0.0003 −8.31e − 05 −0.0002 −0.0002 −0.0003** −0.0003 (0.0003) (0.0008) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0003) Sun −9.38e − 05 0.0001 0.0001 2.74e − 05 −1.11e − 05 0.0002 −6.28e − 05 −0.0004* (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001) (8.96e − 05) (0.0001) (0.0007) (0.0001) (0.0002) Cinema 0.0120 0.0307*** 0.0247*** 0.0275*** 0.0320*** 0.0257*** 0.0259*** 0.0267*** (0.007) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.007) (0.006) (0.008) Museums 0.0076 0.0072 0.0142*** 0.0116** 0.0098 0.0153** 0.0105* 0.0058 (0.0078) (0.0053) (0.0041) (0.0047) (0.006) (0.007) (0.006) (0.008) Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 4 (continued) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Firm entries Sound Life Craft Other Audio-visuals Publishing Advertising Videogames Constant −2.371*** 0.166 0.773 1.816*** 0.678 0.382 0.511 −1.108 (0.873) (0.658) (0.632) (0.598) (0.693) (0.787) (0.724) (1.088) Inflate Pop −0.000* − − − − −0.000** − −0.000** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) constant 4.449*** − − – − 2.463 − 3.12** (2.369) 1.642 (1.08) N 480 480 480 480 480 480 480 480 Departments 96 96 96 96 96 96 96 96 Time FE Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Wald X 562.83 1044.05 1055.76 663.72 1061.69 505.00 2990.01 937.34 Log pseudolikelihood −1088.507 −1620.841 −1525.022 −2060.629 −1950.449 −1385.312 −1872.121 −954.435 Lnalpha −1.932*** −2.270 −2.402 −2.561 −2.159 −1.912 −2.096 −2.094*** (0.185) (0.165) (0.165) (0.129) (0.159) (0.194) (0.161) (0.432) Alpha 0.146 0.103 0.090 0.077 0.115 0.148 0.123 0.123 (0.027) (0.017) (0.015) (0.010) (0.018) (0.029) (0.019) (0.053) Vuong 3.51*** − − − − 2.74** − 4.09*** Robust standard errors in parentheses, ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 5 Spatial Lag Model: Location determinants of firms (NB) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) Firm entries All Creative Non-Creative human capital 0.0224*** 0.0256*** 0.0222*** (0.0027) (0.0029) (0.0027) W_human capital −0.0013 −0.0013 −0.0013 (0.0012) (0.0012) (0.0012) pop_density −8.63e − 05*** −6.35e − 05*** −8.83e − 05*** (1.20e − 05) (1.27e − 05) (1.20e − 05) W_pop_density −3.58e − 05* −3.58e − 05* −3.58e − 05* (2.18e − 05) (2.18e − 05) (2.18e − 05) income 1.17e − 05** 1.42e − 05** 1.16e − 05** (5.43e − 06) (5.72e − 06) (5.42e − 06) W_income 1.89e − 08 1.89e − 08 1.89e − 08 (9.48e − 06) (9.48e − 06) (9.48e − 06) Manufacturing −1.163*** −1.593*** −1.143*** (0.243) (0.257) (0.243) W_manufacturing 0.366 0.366 0.366 (0.457) (0.457) (0.457) Unemployment 4.551*** 3.939*** 4.589*** (0.906) (0.963) (0.906) W_unemployment −2.452 −2.452 −2.452 (1.752) (1.752) (1.752) public investment −0.0011*** −0.0012*** −0.0011*** (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) W_public investment 0.0005 0.0005 0.0005 (0.0004) (0.0004) (0.0004) LQ_creative 0.236*** 0.306*** 0.230*** (0.058) (0.059) (0.058) W_LQ_creative 0.146 0.146 0.146 (0.128) (0.128) (0.128) dist_paris −0.0003** −0.0006*** −0.0003** (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001) Rain −0.0002*** −0.0001* −0.0002*** (8.27e − 05) (8.81e − 05) (8.28e − 05) Sun 1.98e − 05 2.67e − 05 1.93e − 05 (5.36e − 05) (5.64e − 05) (5.36e − 05) Cinema 0.0281*** 0.0290*** 0.0281*** (0.0019) (0.002) (0.0019) W_cinema −0.0016 −0.0016 −0.0016 (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Museums 0.0116*** 0.0113*** 0.0116*** (0.0022) (0.0023) (0.0022) W_museums 0.0033 0.0033 0.0033 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Table 5 (continued) Dep. Var.: (1) (2) (3) Firm entries All Creative Non-Creative (0.0048) (0.0048) (0.0048) Constant 5.768*** 2.539*** 5.720*** (0.465) (0.458) (0.465) N 480 480 480 Departments 96 96 96 Time FE Y Y Y Wald X 885.42 995.95 877.11 Log pseudolikelihood −3987.721 −2566.505 −3963.184 Robust standard errors in parentheses, ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 publishing, whilst the latter include audio-visuals, advertising and videogames. Although the patterns are not clearly divided into two groups, the main difference is found in the role played by localisation economies since, while for technology- oriented subgroups, location quotients in their subgroup foster entries, this effect is only found for one out of the six cultural oriented subgroups, that is, life perform- ing arts. This is a relevant issue, since agglomeration economies at department level matter for these activities, although it could also be argued that their geographical scope is much smaller than that of a department. Surprisingly, except for Audio-vis- uals, technology-oriented subgroups do not suffer from distance to Paris, suggesting that it is possible to attract such firms outside the Île-de-France region. Regarding unemployment rates, technology-oriented subgroups also have some specifi- cities as they are not positively attracted by them, as for the rest of subgroups. This may be explained by the fact that, for these industries, the creation of new firms is mainly driven by innovative ideas or market opportunities. Thus, the conditions leading to higher unemploy- ment rates may deter innovative-based CIs entries (Storey 1991; Fritsch 2008). For the cul- tural CIs subgroups (i.e. life performance, arts craft and other artistic activities) the impact of unemployment is positive and significant. This is consistent with the findings of Aubry et al. (2015) who show that start-ups in France are mainly explained by a refugee effect (i.e. the creation of firms is a strategy to escape from unemployment). This result is also in line with the higher part-time work and unemployment rates that usually characterise employ- ment in the more artistic and cultural CIs (Faggian et al. 2013; Pareja-Eastaway 2016). In order to account for inter-department neighbouring externalities for both the entries grouped (Table 5) and at a subgroup level (Table 6), we estimate an enlarged location decision model including such spatial externalities. We have to take into account that the way in which these activities have been grouped also differs. Concretely, CIs subgroups include NACE5 subsectors but with different quantities (see Table  11): Craft and Sound include 1 subsector; Life, Advertising and Other include 2 subsectors; Publishing and Vide- ogames include 5 subsectors; and Audio-visuals includes 12 subsectors. These results could be also affected by firm size, however information of the size of firms was not available. In any case, firms in cultural and creative industries tend to be of smaller size than the rest of economic activities (i.e. size variation is lower inside them) and, partially due to that reason, papers focusing on entry determinants or spatial distribution of firms use to group firms of different sizes together (see Coll-Martínez 2019; Fahmi et al. 2016; Lazzeretti et al. 2008, among others). 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. 1 3 Table 6 Spatial Lag Model: Location determinants of Creative Industries Subgroups (NB) Dep. Var: Firm entries (1) Sound (2) Life (3) Craft (4) Other (5) Audio-visuals (6) Publishing (7) Advertising (8) Videogames human capital 0.0623*** 0.0272*** 0.0179*** 0.0193*** 0.0333*** 0.0256*** 0.0307*** 0.0421*** (0.0068) (0.0039) (0.0037) (0.0029) (0.0036) (0.0054) (0.0037) (0.0078) W_human capital −0.0034 −0.0037** −0.0044*** −0.0003 −0.0016 −0.0032 −0.0041** −0.0029 (0.0026) (0.0016) (0.0017) (0.0013) (0.0016) (0.0022) (0.0016) (0.0027) pop_density 6.92e − 05** −4.91e − 05*** −3.59e − 05*** −7.17e − 05*** −7.68e − 05*** 2.60e − 05 −5.46e − 05*** −2.26e − 05 (3.22e − 05) (1.42e − 05) (1.10e − 05) (9.50e − 06) (1.73e − 05) (2.17e − 05) (1.23e − 05) (1.77e − 05) W_pop_density −3.85e − 05 −2.16e − 05 −1.46e − 05 −2.74e − 05* −1.85e − 05 −5.85e − 06 −1.91e − 05 2.96e − 05 (6.98e − 05) (2.40e − 05) (1.92e − 05) (1.57e − 05) (2.96e − 05) (4.62e − 05) (2.13e − 05) (2.99e − 05) Income 3.01e − 05*** 1.83e − 05*** 1.50e − 05** 1.13e − 05** 2.08e − 05*** 1.91e − 05** 2.29e − 05*** −2.64e − 07 (9.18e − 06) (6.35e − 06) (6.13e − 06) (5.24e − 06) (6.76e − 06) (8.34e − 06) (7.07e − 06) (9.03e − 06) W_income −1.54e − 05 −1.17e − 07 −6.41e − 06 9.81e − 06 2.59e − 06 3.49e − 06 −9.09e − 06 5.10e − 06 (1.99e − 05) (1.28e − 05) (1.29e − 05) (9.79e − 06) (1.21e − 05) (1.67e − 05) (1.26e − 05) (2.22e − 05) Manufacturing −5.126*** −1.098*** −0.914*** −1.130*** −2.356*** −3.475*** −1.984*** −4.993*** (0.563) (0.355) (0.331) (0.258) (0.318) (0.457) (0.334) (0.651) W_manufacturing 2.629** 1.149* 0.655 0.315 0.204 1.693** 1.330** −0.441 (1.022) (0.645) (0.623) (0.490) (0.606) (0.836) (0.640) (1.121) Unemployment −4.293** 3.577*** 4.776*** 4.591*** 3.228*** −4.725*** 2.697** −0.0459 (1.945) (1.235) (1.246) (0.958) (1.194) (1.719) (1.240) (2.358) W_unemployment 4.623 0.903 −1.156 −2.855 −1.529 −0.998 −3.198 1.376 (3.614) (2.295) (2.362) (1.834) (2.296) (3.122) (2.365) (3.981) public investment 0.0003 −0.001*** −3.49e − 05 −0.0006*** −0.001*** −0.0006 −0.0014*** −0.0012* (0.0005) (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003) (0.0004) (0.0003) (0.0006) W_public investment 0.0016* 0.0013** 0.0007 0.0007* 0.0008* 0.0005 0.0011** 0.0012 (0.0008) (0.0005) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0007) (0.0005) (0.0009) Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 6 (continued) Dep. Var: Firm entries (1) Sound (2) Life (3) Craft (4) Other (5) Audio-visuals (6) Publishing (7) Advertising (8) Videogames LQ_$ −0.104 0.205*** 0.0170 −0.00914 0.271*** 0.0357 0.335*** 0.527*** (0.0897) (0.0668) (0.0114) (0.0280) (0.0527) (0.0713) (0.0570) (0.0484) W_LQ_$ 0.231 −0.0348 0.0109 −0.0193 0.0402 0.0642 0.277** −0.0145 (0.213) (0.127) (0.0201) (0.0502) (0.105) (0.189) (0.126) (0.142) dist_paris −0.0004 −0.0009*** −0.0009*** −0.0007*** −0.0008*** −0.0006*** −0.0002 0.0004 (0.0003) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0003) Rain −0.0002 −0.0002 −0.0003** −8.42e − 05 −0.0002* −0.0002 −0.0004*** −0.0004** (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001) (8.70e − 05) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002) Sun −6.04e − 05 0.0001* 0.0001 3.16e − 05 −8.47e − 06 0.0002* −5.59e − 05 −0.0004*** (0.0001) (7.33e − 05) (7.29e − 05) (5.59e − 05) (7.01e − 05) (0.0001) (7.21e − 05) (0.0001) Cinema 0.0141*** 0.0305*** 0.0240*** 0.0272*** 0.0318*** 0.0253*** 0.0254*** 0.0265*** (0.004) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.0024) (0.0033) (0.0024) (0.004) W_cinema 0.0068 0.001 0.0013 −0.0036 0.0003 0.0069 −0.0021 0.0037 (0.0072) (0.0045) (0.0045) (0.0035) (0.0043) (0.006) (0.0046) (0.0081) Museums 0.0062 0.0078*** 0.0143*** 0.0124*** 0.0099*** 0.0138*** 0.0107*** 0.0034 (0.0044) (0.0028) (0.0028) (0.0023) (0.0028) (0.0037) (0.0029) (0.0042) W_museums −0.0149 0.0044 0.0039 0.0095* 0.0012 −0.0168* −0.0016 −0.0219* (0.0105) (0.0066) (0.0065) (0.0051) (0.0064) (0.0089) (0.007) (0.0115) Constant −3.362*** −0.470 1.425** 1.667*** 0.981 0.584 0.401 0.005 (1.054) (0.651) (0.626) (0.492) (0.603) (0.852) (0.638) (1.173) Inflate Ppop −0.000** − − − − −0.000*** − −0.000*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) constant 4.506 − − − − 2.275** − 2.83*** J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. 1 3 Table 6 (continued) Dep. Var: Firm entries (1) Sound (2) Life (3) Craft (4) Other (5) Audio-visuals (6) Publishing (7) Advertising (8) Videogames (1.995) (0.979) (0.721) N 480 480 480 480 480 480 480 480 Time FE Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Log pseudolikelihood −1075.408 −1610.265 −1517.873 −2053.83 −1946.125 −1378.752 −1859.683 −953.819 Robust standard errors in parentheses; ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Regarding Table  5, almost all the key location determinants remain significant as in previous estimations. However, by adding spatial lagged variables, some variables such as population density, income, distance to Paris and rain levels become significant. Population density and income tend to be closely linked to market strength, which is a key location fac- tor, as well as that increased distance to main economic centres usually having a negative effect due to lower attractiveness of these areas (Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017). The effects of the specialisation in creative industries remain significant at the department level, but they do not seem significant beyond department borders. In other words, creative firms seem to be only affected by specialisation in CIs in the departments where they locate, but not by surrounding areas. This is a quite reason- able result as the spatial scope of agglomeration externalities captured by LQ_cre- ative tends to diminish after very short distances, as reported previously by Coll- Martínez et al. (2019) for Barcelona’s neighbourhoods, Cruz and Teixeira (2014) for Portuguese municipalities, and Wojan et al. (2007) for US counties. Finally, subgroup estimation including spatial lags (Table  6) slightly modifies the previous findings when taking spatial effects into account. In particular, the negative effects of population density and public investments on entries now become significant for most of the subgroups. A noticeable exception is Videogames since, for this indus- try, population density does not deter entries. This result fits perfectly with the existing literature regarding the locational patterns of Videogames industry, as empirical evi- dence has demonstrated the strong urban-core preferences of firms belonging to that industry (Moriset 2003; Méndez-Ortega and Arauzo-Carod 2019, 2020). In general terms, the subgroup estimations including spatial lags increase the signif- icance of most of covariates used in previous estimations, although failing to identify strong significant influences of neighbouring departments. This result may be, to some extent, explained by the fact that neighbouring relations have been defined by consid- ering a spatial contiguity matrix. Still, the use of a spatial contiguity matrix provides the best fit of the model. Anyway, the inclusion of spatial lags allows us to capture any source of spatial dependence in terms of knowledge spillovers spreading beyond geo- graphical limits and that cannot be considered otherwise. 6 Conclusion In this paper, we estimate the location determinants of new creative industries (CIs) firms across metropolitan France departments over the period 2009–2013. The econometric results show that the location determinants of creative and non-creative firms are quite similar, and that both creative and non-creative firms are positively affected by the specialisation in CIs. This influence supports public investments in these industries in view of the positive externalities arising from their spatial con- centration on firm entry. Our results also show that there are some locational spe- cificities among CIs activities due to their heterogeneity. Finally, when accounting for spatial dependence, we found that creative firms seem to be only affected by CI 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. specialisation in the departments where they locate, but not in surrounding areas, so the spatial scope of effects is less than a standard department. Our results are in line with those of previous empirical contributions and sup- port the positive association between the concentration of creative workers and new firms’ creation at the department level (Scott 2006; Lee et al. 2004; Stam et al. 2008; Audretsch and Belitski 2013; Coll-Martínez and Arauzo-Carod 2017). Moreover, they are in line with previous findings highlighting the uneven geographic distribu- tion of creative people, mainly concentrated in Paris and larger French cities (Chan- telot 2010a, 2010b; Sanchez-Serra 2013, 2014). Consequently, our results help to fill a gap in the empirical literature in terms of a lack of knowledge of the processes driving the entry decisions of CIs firms. This paper has certain limitations. Since it is focused on location determi- nants of CIs at a quite aggregated level, it remains for future research to analyse whether our results hold for alternative geographical disaggregation levels such as municipalities or metropolitan areas. Some empirical evidence already exists for the French case (see Chantelot 2010a) and this indicates that there are differ- ences between big and medium-small urban areas. Additionally, due to the huge concentration of CIs in Paris and the municipalities in its metropolitan area (see Boix et  al. 2016), it would be advisable to carry out a detailed and spatially disaggregated analysis for this region. Future efforts will also be conducted to understand and identify the complexity and the  cross-fertilisation of different creative jobs working in other industries than the CIs (Bakhshi and McVittie 2009; Cerisola 2018a, b; Innocenti and Lazzeretti 2019). Policy implications from our results point to the importance of achieving a critical mass of creative activities as a necessary condition for attracting firm entries from these industries. However, from a territorial cohesion point of view, is not a desirable to reinforce excessive concentration of CIs in and around main urban areas. Thus, given (i) the uneven spatial distribution of CIs entries in French departments and (ii) the fact that the most populated departments (where most CIs locate) are the ones receiving the most public funding and support for cultural and creative activities, less populated (rural) areas might benefit little from the potential of CIs for economic development and sustain- able growth. Thus, there is room for policy interventions which can support CIs in these (peripheral) areas. In fact, the COVID-19 pandemic and its immedi- ate consequences (i.e. shutdowns, economic slowdown, physical distance) may impact the activity and location choices of CIs firms. At the same time, this crisis may provide an opportunity for less urbanised areas to attract the creation of creative firms. We however leave this interesting and promising approaches for further research. Appendix See Tables 7, 8, 9, 10 and 11. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 7 Selection model tests Model 1 (All firms) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 151,752.47 151,823.42 − Negative binomial 8,023.16 8,023.16 − Zero-inflated Poisson 151,756.47 151,756.47 − Zero-inflated negative binomial 8027.165 8110.64 − Model 2 (Creative) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 12,696.39 12,767.79 − Negative binomial 5,245.14 5,245.14 − Zero-inflated Poisson 12,700.79 12,780.09 − Zero-inflated negative binomial 5.249.14 6165.74 −1.72 Model 3 (Non-Creative) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 163,629.84 163,708.25 − Negative binomial 9486.6961 9,569.4622 − Zero-inflated Poisson 163,629.84 163,708.25 − Zero-inflated negative binomial 9,490.6961 9582.1744 − ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 8 Selection model’s Model 1 (Sound) AIC BIC Vuong test tests for Creative Industries Subgroups Poisson 2580.85 2651.81 − Negative binomial 2285.78 2360.91 − Zero-inflated Poisson 2431.36 2510.66 3.27*** Zero-inflated negative binomial 2217.01 2,300.49 3.51*** Model 2 (Life) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 3916.10 3987.05 − Negative binomial 3277.68 3352.81 − Zero-inflated Poisson 3914.82 3994.12 0.77 Zero-inflated negative binomial 3281.68 3365.16 0 Model 3 (Craft) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 3414.11 3485.06 − Negative binomial 3086.04 3161.17 − Zero-inflated Poisson 3415.13 3494.43 0.66 Zero-inflated negative binomial 3090.04 3173.52 0 Model 4 (Other) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 5635.51 4157.26 − Negative binomial 5706.47 4232.39 − Zero-inflated Poisson − − − Zero-inflated negative binomial − − − Model 5 (Audio-visuals) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 6503.13 6581.54 − Negative binomial 4559.39 4642.15 − Zero-inflated Poisson 6495.85 6582.97 0.91 Zero-inflated negative binomial 4563.39 4654.86 −0.88 Model 6 (Publishing) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 3,974.44 4,052.85 − Negative binomial 3,360.88 3,443.65 − Zero-inflated Poisson 3,816.52 3,903.64 3.79*** Zero-inflated negative binomial 3,308.36 3,399.84 2.84** Model 7 (Advertising) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 6011.27 6089.68 − Negative binomial 4415.87 4498.64 − Zero-inflated Poisson 5981.14 6068.26 0.61 Zero-inflated negative binomial 4404.32 4495.80 0.5 Model 8 (Videogames) AIC BIC Vuong test Poisson 2508.96 2587.37 − Negative binomial 2377.21 2459.98 − Zero-inflated Poisson 2339.90 2427.03 4.78*** Zero-inflated negative binomial 2280.41 2371.89 4.67*** ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 9 Summary statistics Variable Description Source Obs Mean Std. Dev Min Max entry_t Number of total firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 4251.9 3125.7 477.0 14,608.0 entry_crea Number of creative firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 228.0 222.9 22.0 1623.0 entry_noncrea Number of non-creative firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 4027.7 2925.2 453.0 13,849.0 entry_sound Number of sound recording firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 6.8 11.7 0.0 96.0 entry_life Number of life performance firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 25.7 25.1 0.0 166.0 entry_craft Number of arts craft firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 17.9 15.3 0.0 83.0 entry_other Number of other music and arts firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 66.6 45.6 6.0 264.0 entry_audio Number of audio-visual firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 57.3 68.5 1.0 545.0 entry_pub Number of publishing firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 14.7 30.8 0.0 322.0 entry_adv Number of advertising firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 44.9 54.5 0.0 472.0 entry_videogames Number of videogames firm entries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 6.3 13.3 0.0 123.0 Human capital Number of secondary students for 1000 inhabitantshttp:// www. colle ctivi tes- local es. gouv. fr/ 480 82.1 7.4 61.8 99.8 pop_density Population per squared km on 1st January Eurostat 480 559.7 2454.0 14.8 21,347.0 Income Disposable income in €/inhabitanthttp:// www. colle ctivi tes- local es. gouv. fr/ 480 12,820.6 4912.0 821.1 53,829.0 Manufacturing Manufacturing employment rate Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.4 Unemployment Unemployment ratehttp:// www. colle ctivi tes- local es. gouv. fr/ 480 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 Public investment Actual investment expenditure in € / inhabhttp:// www. colle ctivi tes- local es. gouv. fr/ 480 238.9 79.7 66.8 666.6 LQ_creative Location Quotient in Creative Industries Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.6 0.5 0.2 3.7 LQ_sound Location Quotient in Sound Recording Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.3 0.8 0.0 7.5 LQ_life Location Quotient in Life Performance Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.6 0.5 0.0 4.1 LQ_craft Location Quotient in Arts Craft Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.9 1.8 0.0 13.2 LQ_other Location Quotient in Other Music and Arts Activities Own elaboration with INSEE 480 1.1 0.6 0.1 3.9 LQ_audio Location Quotient in Audio-visual Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.5 0.6 0.1 4.8 LQ_pub Location Quotient in Publishing Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.5 0.6 0.1 5.4 LQ_adv Location Quotient in Advertising Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.6 0.4 0.0 3.9 LQ_videogames Location Quotient in Videogames Own elaboration with INSEE 480 0.5 0.7 0.0 4.2 dist_paris Distance in km from the capital of Department to Paris Own elaboration 480 353.5 205.5 0 918.9 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. 1 3 Table 9 (continued) Variable Description Source Obs Mean Std. Dev Min Max Rain Cumulate rain in a year in mm Eider—French Government 480 800.5 204.5 423.2 1625.3 Sun Cumulate sunny time in hours Eider—French Government 570 1973.2 385.3 73.1 3058.0 Cinema Number of cinemas CNC Eider—French Government 480 21.2 14.1 3.0 88.0 Museums Number of museums INSEE 480 12.7 8.7 2.0 59.0 Source: Authors Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… 1 3 Table 10 Correlation of main explanatory variables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 1. Human capital 1 2. Pop_density 0.1255* 1 3. Income 0.3447* 0.4078* 1 4. Manufacturing −0.1804* −0.3672* −0.2838* 1 5. Unemployment 0.1233* −0.0707 0.0289 −0.1363* 1 6. Public investment −0.1934* −0.1887* −0.3543* −0.0776 −0.1754* 1 7. LQ_creative 0.2000* 0.8446* 0.4591* −0.4485* −0.0771 −0.1566* 1 8. dist_paris −0.2999* −0.3144* −0.1670* −0.2824* 0.1562* 0.3689* −0.2359* 1 9. Rain −0.0936* −0.1638* 0.0197 0.2155* −0.0563 0.0051 −0.2242* 0.2175* 1 10. Sun −0.1187* −0.1281* −0.0182 −0.4306* 0.2231* 0.3041* −0.0213 0.6739* −0.1226* 1 11. Cinema 0.5033* 0.5203* 0.4242* −0.4691* −0.0765 −0.1715* 0.5744* 0.0112 0.0235 0.1002* 1 12. Museums 0.3500* 0.4692* 0.3542* −0.2476* 0.1219* −0.2563* 0.5117* −0.0975* −0.1122* 0.0597 0.6372* 1 Source: Authors. Significance level: *p < 0.05 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Table 11 Creative Industries Classification CIs subgroups Sectors Code APE- NAF Rev. 2 Cinema & Audio-visuals Reproduction of sound recording 1820Z (audiovisuals) Production of films and shows for television 5911A Production of institutional and advertising films 5911B Production of film for cinema 5911C Post-production of films and shows for television 5912Z Distribution of cinematographic films 5913A Editing and distribution of videotapes 5913B Projection of cinematographic films 5914Z Broadcasting and distribution of radio shows 6010Z Broadcasting of generalist channels 6020A Broadcasting of theme channels 6020B Photographic activities 7420Z Sound recording (sound) Sound recording and music editing 5920Z Life performance (life) Life performing arts 9001Z Life performing arts supporting activities 9002Z Arts craft (craft) Arts and crafts artistic creation 9003A Other artistic activities Other activities related to artistic creation 9003B (other) Other activities related to entertainment 9329Z Publishing (publishing) Publishing of books 511Z Publishing of newspapers 5813Z Magazine publishing 5814Z Other publishing activities 5819Z Other news agencies activities 6391Z Advertising (advertising) Advertising agencies activities 7311Z Management of advertising media 7312Z Videogames (videogames) Publishing of videogames 5821A Publishing of software systems 5829A Publishing of software for development tools and languages 5829B Publishing applicative software 5829C Source: Authors following APUR-INSEE classification Acknowledgements We would like to acknowledge the fruitful comments of the participants at the 55ème Colloque de l’ASRDLF (Caen, 2018) and at the 1st International workshop Rethinking Clusters: Critical issues and new trajectories of cluster research (Florence, 2018). Any errors are, of course, our own. Funding Open Access funding provided thanks to the CRUE-CSIC agreement with Springer Nature. This paper was partially funded by ECO2017-88888-P, the “Xarxa de Referència d’R + D + I en Eco- nomia i Polítiques Públiques”, the SGR programme (2014 SGR 299) of the Catalan Government, the “Departament d’Universitats, Recerca i Societat de la Informació de la Generalitat de Catalunya” FI Fel- lowship (2017 FI_B 00223) and the “Fundación SGAE”. 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Declarations Conflict of interest No potential competing interest was reported by the authors. Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http:// creat iveco mmons. org/ licen ses/ by/4. 0/. References Abdesselam R, Bonnet J, Renou-Maissant P (2014) Typology of the French regional development: revealing the refugee versus Schumpeter effects in new-firm start-ups. Appl Econ 46(28):3437–3451 Acs Z, And DS, Hessels J (2008) Entrepreneurship, economic development and institutions. Small Bus Econ 31:219–234 Acs Z, Braunerhjelm P, Audretsch DB, Carlsson B (2009) The knowledge spillover theory of entrepre- neurship. Small Bus Econ 32:15–30 Andersson M, Koster S (2010) Sources of persistence in regional start-up rates—evidence from Sweden. J Econo Geogr 11(1):179–201 APUR (2014) Nouveaux regards sur l’économie à Paris. Quelques filières d’avenir: Industries creatives/ numérique/mode-design/écoactivités. APUR, Paris. Arauzo-Carod JM (2021) Location determinants of high-tech firms: an intra-urban approach. Ind Innov 28(10):1225–1248 Arauzo-Carod JM, Segarra-Blasco A (2005) The determinants of entry are not independent of start-up size: some evidence from Spanish Manufacturing. Rev Ind Organ 27:147–165 Arauzo-Carod JM, Teruel-Carrizosa M (2005) An urban approach to firm entry: the effect of urban size. Growth Chang 36(4):508–528 Arauzo-Carod JM, Liviano-Solis D, Manjón-Antolín M (2010) Empirical studies in industrial location: an assessment of their methods and results. J Reg Sci 50(3):685–711 Arcuri G, Brunetto M, Levratto N (2019) Spatial patterns and determinants of firm exit: an empirical analysis on France. Ann Reg Sci 62:99–116. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1007/ s00168- 018- 0887-0 Armington C, Acs Z (2002) The determinants of regional variation in new firms’ formation. Reg Stud 36(1):33–45 Aubry M, Bonnet J, Renou-Maissant P (2015) Entrepreneurship and the business cycle: the “Schum- peter” effect versus the “refugee” effect—a French appraisal based on regional data. Ann Reg Sci 54(1):23–55 Audretsch DB (1995) Innovation and industry evolution. The MIT Press, Cambridge Audretsch DB, Belitski M (2013) The missing pillar: the creativity theory of knowledge spillover entre- preneurship. Small Bus Econ 41(4):819–836 Audretsch DB, Fritsch M (1999) The Industry component of regional new firm formation processes. Rev Ind Organ 15:239–252 Bakhshi H, McVittie E (2009) Creative supply-chain linkages and innovation: do the creative industries stimulate business innovation in the wider economy? Innovation 11(2):169–189 Barois B (2020) Le rôle attractif des industries créatives et culturelles dans la localisation des jeunes en France. Region Et Developpement 51:45–64 Bertacchini E, Borrione P (2013) The Geography of the Italian creative economy: the special role of the design and craft-based industries. Reg Stud 47(2):135–147 Bille T, Schulze GG (2006) Culture in urban and regional development. In: Ginsburgh VA, Throsby D (eds) Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, Vol. 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Boix R, Hervás-Oliver JL, De Miguel-Molina B (2015) Micro-geographies of creative industries clusters in Europe: from hot spots to assemblages. Pap Reg Sci 94(4):753–773 Boix R, Capone F, De Propris L, Lazzeretti L, Sanchez D (2016) Comparing creative industries in Europe. Euro Urban Regional Stud 23(4):935–940 Bosma N, Schutjens V (2011) Understanding regional variation in entrepreneurial activity and entrepre- neurial attitude in Europe. Ann Reg Sci 47:711–742 Brixy U (2014) The significance of entry and exit for regional productivity growth. Reg Stud 48(6):1051–1070 Cameron AC, Trivedi PK (1998) Regression analysis of count data. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Cameron AC, Trivedi PK (2005) Microeconometrics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Cerisola S (2018a) Creativity and local economic development: the role of synergy among different tal- ents. Pap Reg Sci 97(2):199–215 Cerisola S (2018b) Multiple creative talents and their determinants at the local level. J Cult Econ 42(2):243–269 Chantelot S (2010a) La géographie de la classe créative : une application aux aires urbaines françaises. Canadian Journal of Regional Science - Revue Canadienne Des Sciences Régionales 33(3):89–108 Chantelot S (2010b) Vers une mesure de la créativité: la construction de la classe créative française. Revue D’économie Régionale Et Urbaine 3:511–540 Chantelot S, Peres S, Virol S (2010) The geography of French creative class: An exploratory spatial data analysis. Cahiers du GREThA 2010–16 Cléron É, Patureau F (2007) L’emploi dans les professions culturelles en 2005. Culture Chiffres 8:1–7 Coll-Martínez E (2019) Creativity and the city: testing the attenuation of agglomeration economies in Barcelona. J Cult Econ 43(3):365–395 Coll-Martínez E, Arauzo-Carod JM (2017) Creative milieu and firm location: an empirical appraisal. Environ Plan A 49(7):1613–1641 Coll-Martínez E, Moreno-Monroy A, Arauzo-Carod JM (2019) Agglomeration of Creative Industries: an Intra-metropolitan analysis for Barcelona. Pap Reg Sci 98(1):409–431 Cruz S, Teixeira AAC (2014) The determinants of spatial location of creative industries start-ups: evi- dence from Portugal using a discrete choice model approach. FEP Working Papers, University of Porto, Working Paper 546. De Propris L (2013) How are creative industries weathering the crisis? Cambridge Journal of Regions. Econ Soc 6(1):23–35 Dunne T, Roberts MJ, Samuelson L (1988) Patterns of firm entry and exit in U.S. Manufacturing indus- tries. RAND J Econ 19(4):495–515. Elert N (2014) What determines entry? Evidence from Sweden. Ann Reg Sci 53:55–92 Elhorst JP, Fréret S (2009) Evidence of political yardstick competition in France using a two-regime spa- tial Durbin model with fixed effects. J Reg Sci 49(5):931–951 Faggian A, Comunian R, Jewell S, Kelly U (2013) Bohemian graduates in the UK: disciplines and loca- tion determinants of creative careers. Reg Stud 47:183–200 Fahmi FZ, Koster S, van Dijk J (2016) The location of creative industries in a developing country: the case of Indonesia. Cities 59:66–79 Florida R (2002) The rise of the creative class, and how it’s transforming work, leisure, community and everyday life. Basic Books, New York Florida R (2005) Cities and the creative class. Routledge, London Fotopoulos G, Louri H (2000) Location and Survival of new entry. Small Bus Econ 14:311–321 Fritsch M (2008) How does new business formation affect regional development? Introduction to the spe- cial issue. Small Bus Econ 30(1):1–14 Günalp B, Cilasun SM (2006) Determinants of Entry in Turkish manufacturing industries. Small Bus Econ 27:275–287 Gutierrez-Posada D, Kitsos T, Nathan M, Nuccio M (2021) Do creative industries generate multiplier effects? Evidence from UK cities, 1997–2018. Creative Industries Policy & Evidence Centre, Dis- cussion Paper 2021/07 Guimarães P, Figueiredo O, Woodward D (2000) Agglomeration and the location of foreign direct invest- ment in Portugal. J Urban Econ 47(1):115–135. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1006/ juec. 1999. 2138 Hall P (2000) Creative cities and economic development. Urban Stud 37:639–649 Heiss F (2002) Structural choice analysis with nested logit models. Stand Genomic Sci 2(3):227–252 1 3 Location attributes explaining the entry of firms in creative… Hong E, Lee IH, Sun L, Harrison R (2015) Entrepreneurship across time and space: empirical evidence from Korea. Small Bus Econ 44:705–719 Hsiao C (2014) Analysis of panel data. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge IFM (2013) The Economic Importance of Creative French Fashion Companies, Fédération française de la Couture. du Prêt-à-Porter des Couturiers et des Créateurs de Mode, Paris Innocenti N, Lazzeretti L (2019) Do the creative industries support growth and innovation in the wider economy? Industry relatedness and employment growth in Italy. Ind Innov 26(10):1152–1173 De Jong JPJ, Fris P, Stam E (2007) Creative industries–heterogeneity and connection with regional firm entry. EIM Business and Policy Research: Zoetermeer. Julien P (2002) Onze fonctions pour qualifier les grandes villes, Insee Première 840, March. Kangasharju A (2000) Regional variations in firm formation: panel and cross-section data evidence from Finland. Pap Reg Sci 79:355–373 Karahasan BC (2015) Dynamics of regional new firm formation in Turkey. Rev Urban Reg Dev Stud 27(1):18–39 Kiroff L (2017) Auckland and the creative industries: the spatial distribution of the design subsector. Urban Geogr 38(10):1573–1602 Lazzeretti L, Boix R, Capone F (2008) Do creative industries cluster? Mapping creative local production systems in Italy and Spain. Ind Innov 15(5):549–567 Lazzeretti L, Capone F, Boix R (2012) Reasons for clustering of creative industries in Italy and Spain. Eur Plan Stud 20(8):1243–1262 Lee SY, Florida R, Acs Z (2004) Creativity and entrepreneurship: a regional analysis of new firm forma- tion. Reg Stud 38(8):879–891. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1080/ 00343 40042 00028 0910 Long JS (1997) Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables (Advanced Quanti- tative Techniques in the Social Sciences). Sage Publications, London Méndez-Ortega C, Arauzo-Carod JM (2019) Locating software, video game and editing electronics firms: using microgeographic data to Study Barcelona. J Urban Technol 26(3):81–9 Méndez-Ortega C, Arauzo-Carod JM (2020) Do Software and Video game firms share location patterns across cities? Evidence from Barcelona, Lyon and Hamburg. Ann Reg Sci 64:641–666 Moriset B (2003) The new economy in the city: emergence and location factors of internet-based compa- nies in the metropolitan area of Lyon, France. Urban Stud 40(11):2165–2186 Myerscough J (1988) The Economic Importance of the Arts in Glasgow. Policy Studies Institute, London Noseleit F (2015) The role of entry and market selection for the dynamics of regional diversity and spe- cialization. Reg Stud 49(1):76–94 Nyström K (2007) Interdependencies in the dynamics of firm entry and exit. J Ind Compet Trade 7(2):113–130 Orr D (1974) The determinants of entry: a study of the Canadian manufacturing industries. Rev Econ Stat 56(1):58–66 Pareja-Eastaway M (2016) Creative industries. J Evol Stud Bus 1:38–50 Piergiovanni R, Carree MA, Santarelli E (2012) Creative industries, new business formation, and regional economic growth. Small Bus Econ 39(3):539–560 Reynolds P, Storey DJ, Westhead P (1994) Cross-national comparisons of the variation in new firm for - mation rates: an editorial overview. Reg Stud 28(4):343–346 Rigby DL, Essletzbichler J (2000) Impacts of industry mix, technological change, selection and plant entry/exit on regional productivity growth. Reg Stud 34(4):333–342 Sanchez-Serra D (2014) Talent and creative economy in French local labour systems. Eviron Plann C Gov Policy 32:405–425 Sanchez-Serra D (2016) Location determinants of creative industries’ firms in Spain. Journal of Regional Research 34:23–48 Sanchez-Serra D (2013) Artistic creative clusters in France: a statistical approach. Territoire en mouve- ment 19/20(2):6–18 Santarelli E, Carrée M, Verheul I (2009) Unemployment and firm entry and exit: an update on a contro- versial relationship. Reg Stud 43(8):1061–1073 Scott AJ (2000) The cultural economy of Paris. Int J Urban Reg Res 24(3):567–582 Scott AJ (2006) Entrepreneurship, innovation and industrial development: geography and the creative field revisited. Small Bus Econ 26(1):1–24 Sensier M, Bristow G, Healy A (2016) Measuring regional economic resilience across Europe: operation- alizing a complex concept. Spat Econ Anal 11(2):128–151 1 3 J.-M. Arauzo-Carod et al. Smit AJ (2011) The influence of district visual quality on location decisions of creative entrepreneurs. J Am Plann Assoc 77(2):167–184 Stam E, De Jong JPJ, Marlet G (2008) Creative industries in the netherlands: structure, development, innovativeness and effects on urban growth. Geogr Ann: Series B, Human Geogr 90(2):119–132. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1111/j. 1468- 0467. 2008. 00282.x Storey DJ (1991) The birth of new firms—does unemployment matter? A review of the evidence. Small Bus Econ 3(3):167–178 UNCTAD (2008) Creative Economy. Report 2008. UNCTAD, Geneva Wagner J, Sternberg R (2004) Start-up activities, individual characteristics, and the regional milieu: les- sons for entrepreneurship support policies from German micro data. Ann Reg Sci 38(2):219–240. https:// doi. org/ 10. 1007/ s00168- 004- 0193-x Wenting R (2011) Urban amenities and agglomeration economies? The locational behaviour and eco- nomic success of Dutch fashion design entrepreneurs. Urban Studies 48(7):1333–1352 Wojan TR, Lambert DM, McGranahan DA (2007) Emoting with their feet: Bohemian attraction to crea- tive milieu. J Econ Geogr 7(6):711–736 Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. 1 3

Journal

The Annals of Regional ScienceSpringer Journals

Published: Apr 5, 2023

Keywords: R39; Z100

There are no references for this article.