Get 20M+ Full-Text Papers For Less Than $1.50/day. Start a 14-Day Trial for You or Your Team.

Learn More →

Functional coefficient quantile regression model with time-varying loadings

Functional coefficient quantile regression model with time-varying loadings JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 2023, VOL. 26, NO. 1, 2167151 https://doi.org/10.1080/15140326.2023.2167151 RESEARCH ARTICLE Functional coefficient quantile regression model with time-varying loadings a b c Alev Atak , Gabriel Montes-Rojas and Jose Olmo a b Department of Economics, Middle East Technical University, Ankara, Turkey; Universidad de Buenos Aires and CONICET, Instituto Interdisciplinario de Economía Política, Buenos Aires, Argentina; Department of Economics, University of Southampton. UK. Departamento de Analisis Economico. Universidad de Zaragoza. Spain ABSTRACT ARTICLE HISTORY Received 22 February 2022 This paper proposes a functional coefficient quantile regression Accepted 1 January 2023 model with heterogeneous and time-varying regression coeffi - cients and factor loadings. Estimation of the model coefficients is KEYWORDS done in two stages. First, we estimate the unobserved common Quantile factor model; time- factors from a linear factor model with exogenous covariates. varying factor loadings; Second, we plug-in an affine transformation of the estimated com- partially linear regression mon factors to obtain the functional coefficient quantile regression model; panel data model. The quantile parameter estimators are consistent and asymptotically normal. The application of this model to the quantile process of a cross-section of U.S. firms’ excess returns confirms the predictive ability of firm-specific covariates and the good perfor- mance of the local estimator of the heterogeneous and time- varying quantile coefficients. 1. Introduction In a series of influential papers, Bai and Ng (2002) and Bai (2003, 2009) developed a general methodology for explaining economic and financial variables by a few common factors. Factor models allow for a drastic reduction of the cross-sectional dimension of a panel while providing a flexible way to summarize information from large data sets, see Pesaran (2006). In the literature on factor models it is common to assume a vector of constant factor loadings. This assumption is, however, rather restrictive. To the best of our knowledge, Eichler et al. (2011) is the first study to use time-varying loadings in a dynamic model with non-stationary time series. Bates et al. (2013) is another influential analysis that contributes to the idea of smooth changes in factor loadings. Su and Wang (2017) propose a local version of the principal component method using smoothly changing loadings, while Pelger and Xiong (2019) allow them to be state-dependent. In this setting the unobserved factor structure is thus allowed to vary over time. Another area of major interest in recent years is the study of the quantile process. Quantile regression (QR) has been studied extensively in both theoretical and empirical studies; see Koenker and Bassett (1978), Portnoy (1991), Chaudhuri et al. (1997), CONTACT Gabriel Montes-Rojas gabriel.montes@fce.uba.ar Universidad de Buenos Aires and CONICET, Instituto Interdisciplinario de Economía Política, Buenos Aires, Argentina © 2023 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group. This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/ licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. 2 A. ATAK ET AL. Koenker and Machado (1999), He and Zhu (2003), Koenker and Xiao (2006). This work has been recently extended to accommodate the presence of dynamics in the quantile coefficients, see Wei and He (2006) and Kim (2007). A more general approach that also allows for dynamics in the quantile parameters is based on nonparametric and semipara- metric estimation methods for dynamic smooth coefficient models, see De Gooijer and Zerom (2003), Yu and Lu (2004), Horowitz and Lee (2005), and more recently, Cai and Xu (2008) and Cai and Xiao (2012). Building on this work, recent contributions by Ando and Bai (2020), Chen et al. (2021) and Ma et al. (2021) have extended quantile regression models to incorporate unobserved common factors. These models consider heteroge- neous quantile effects that introduce much flexibility to the specification of factor models by capturing the presence of heterogeneity in the effect of observable covariates and unobserved factors at different quantiles. The current paper combines both approaches by considering a factor model with a time-varying factor loadings structure in a quantile heterogeneity framework with varying coefficients. The idea is to propose a flexible panel data model that is general enough to encompass unobserved heterogeneity arising from unobserved factors and quantile-indexed responses together in a dynamic setting. This is done in two stages. First, we propose a factor model for the mean process that includes observable regressors and unobservable factors. This model allows for heterogeneity across individuals and dynamics in the regression coefficients. By doing so, we extend standard factor model specifications that assume slope homogeneity in the observable regressors as in Bai (2003, 2009) and slope heterogeneity as in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015). As a salient feature, the model also entertains dynamics in the factor loadings. Second, we extend the model to describe the quantile process. The slope coefficients associated with the observable regressors in the quantile model face three different types of variation: heterogeneity across quantiles, individuals, and over time. The factor loadings accom- modate heterogeneity across individuals and over time. Estimation of the model coeffi- cients (quantile factors, quantile regression coefficients and factor loadings) is done in two stages. In the first stage, we estimate the unobservable common factors from a linear factor model with exogenous covariates. We adapt the principal component analysis introduced in Bai (2009) to a local setting using kernel estimation methods (see also Su and Wang (2017)) to simultaneously estimate the local common factors, factor loadings and slope coefficients associated with the observable regressors. In contrast to Su and Wang (2017), our model also accommodates the presence of observable regressors. In order to estimate the quantile common factors a fundamental assumption in our modelling framework is that these quantities are quantile-specific affine transformations of the factors obtained from the mean process in the first stage. In this regard, our model specification lies between the approximate factor models that only consider mean- shifting factors to describe quantile effects and the idiosyncratic quantile factor models in which the factors are estimated separately for each quantile using an iterative proce- dure, see Ando and Bai (2020), Chen et al. (2021) and Ma et al. (2021). By doing so, our quantile factors become observable covariates in the quantile process studied in the second stage. The estimation of the parameters in our model relies on the nonparametric quantile estimation method for dynamic smooth coefficients introduced in Cai and Xu (2008) and the semiparametric approach proposed in Cai and Xiao (2012) for models with partially JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 3 varying coefficients. Our proposed methodology is also framed within the recent litera- ture on QR models with an unobserved factor structure. Harding and Lamarche (2014) propose a quantile common correlated effects estimator for homogeneous panel data with endogenous regressors. The authors assume a parametric approach and time- invariant factor loadings, where the way of recovering the latent factors is different from ours. Inclusion of estimated quantities in regression models may affect the asymptotic distribution of the parameter estimates, see Pagan (1984). This observation is essential in our context, characterized by a quantile factor model with estimated factors. In principle, the inclusion of such covariates into the quantile model has effects on the asymptotic distribution of the quantile parameter estimates. We show that this is not the case under standard panel data assumptions, that is, if both N and T diverge to infinity pffiffiffiffi such that Th= N ! 1, with h ! 0 a bandwidth parameter. We derive the asymptotic distribution of the regression parameter estimates associated to the observable covariates for the mean and quantile models, and of the estimated factors and quantile factor loadings. A Monte Carlo simulation exercise studies the finite-sample performance (bias and mean square error) of two estimators of the slope coefficients that are based on our two- stage procedure. The first estimator considers time-varying factor loadings using the local estimation procedure developed in this paper. In this case we estimate individual- specific coefficients for all t ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; T. The second estimator considers a model with time-invariant loadings. In this case we do not impose the time-varying local estimation procedure and estimate, instead, a unique set of parameters for all t. This global factor estimator uses Ando and Bai (2015) iterative process. The simulation exercise confirms the consistency of our local two-stage estimation procedure and provides empirical support to our methodology for estimating heterogeneous and time-varying quantile regression coefficients and factor loadings. This novel quantile factor model is applied to explain the distributional risk premia for a cross-section of excess returns. To do this, we fit the model to different quantiles of the distribution for a cross-section of annual U.S. firms’ asset returns. We consider firm- specific covariates as pricing factors and allow for the presence of two unobserved factors. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the time- varying quantile factor model. Section 3 describes the estimation procedure based on local principal components and QR. Section 4 introduces the asymptotic properties of the parameter estimators. Section 5 presents a Monte Carlo simulation exercise to evaluate the performance in finite samples of our estimation procedure, in particular, we focus on bias and mean square error. Section 6 illustrates the suitability of the quantile factor model with exogenous covariates in an empirical asset pricing framework. Section 7 provides concluding remarks. An Appendix contains the mathematical proofs of the main results of the study. Tables and figures are collected as a second Appendix. It is prevalent in this literature to fix the number of unobserved common factors, see Bai (2009), Song (2013), and Ando and Bai (2015). Alternatively, information criteria and rank minimization are used in Ando and Bai (2020) and Chen et al. (2021), to determine the number of factors at each quantile while uncovering the quantile factors individually. 4 A. ATAK ET AL. Notation. Let ½T�;f1; 2; . . . ; Tg and ½N� ¼ f1; 2; . . . ; Ng be the sets of time periods and individual indices, respectively. The Frobenius norm is defined as k A k¼ 1=2 0 0 ½trðAAÞ� with tr denoting the trace of a matrix and A the transpose of A. 2. Time-varying quantile factor models 2.1. Identification of the quantile factors and factor loadings Let Y be an outcome variable of interest and X ¼ X ; . . . ; X be a vector of d it it 1;it d;it observable covariates, including a constant. Similarly, F ¼ ðF ; . . . ; F Þ is the vector τt τ;t1 τ;tR of unobservable common quantile factors indexed by τ where, for simplicity, R is assumed to be equal across τ 2 ð0; 1Þ. We consider the following quantile process conditional on X and F , given by it τt Q ðY jX ; F Þ ¼ X β þ F Λ ; (1) τ it it τt it τt τ;it τ;it for a given τ 2 ð0; 1Þ, where β ¼ β ðu Þ, with u ¼ t=T , is the vector of quantile slope t t τ;it τ;i coefficients associated to the observable regressors. Similarly, Λ ¼ ðλ ; . . . ; λ Þ , τ;it τ1;it τR;it with λ ¼ λ ðu Þ, are the loadings associated to the quantile factors F . Here the τj;it τj;i t τt factors are assumed to be τ-specific. Both β and Λ are assumed continuously τ;it τ;it differentiable smooth functions, see Cai (2007) for similar assumptions in a model with observable covariates. We impose the following assumption for the identification of the quantile factors. Assumption A.1 iÞ The conditional mean model satisfies EðY jX ; F Þ ¼ X β þ F Λ ; (2) it it t it t it it with β the slope coefficients for the conditional mean process; F ¼ ðF ; . . . ; F Þ the t t1 tR it vector of common factors affecting the conditional mean, and Λ the associated factor it loadings. iiÞ The quantile common factors satisfy F ¼ F þ s ; (3) τt t τt with s ¼ ½s ; . . . ; s � for all t 2 ½T�. τt τ;1t τ;Rt Assumption A.1 ii) implies that the quantile factors are location shifts of the vector of factors for the mean process. Under A.1, we can identify the quantile factors and the quantile factor loadings from the following quantile regression model: Q ðY jX ; F Þ ¼ a þ X β þ F Λ ; (4) τ it it t τ;it it t τ;it τ;it with a ¼ s Λ . Identification of the quantile parameters is possible if we condition τ;it τt τ;it on the vector X and F . The additional component a determines that the constant in it t τ;it (1) cannot be identified unless additional assumptions are imposed. In particular, identification of s is possible if there is no constant in the quantile regression models τ;tr JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 5 indexed by τ 2 ð0; 1Þ. Alternatively, we may impose Q ðs j F Þ ¼ 0 in assumption A.1. τ τt t This additional constraint allows for the identification of the constant in model (4) from the parameter vector β . Note however that this is not required for the estimation of the τ;it other parameters which is the main interest of the paper. The next section discusses a suitable estimation strategy for obtaining consistent � � estimates of the model parameters. The parameters of interest are β ; Λ ; F for the it t it n o mean regression equation in A.1, and β ; Λ ; F for the QR model (4). τ;it τt τ;it 2.2. Estimation In this section we consider local versions of principal components analysis to devise an iterative procedure for estimating the model parameters of the mean process (2). To do this, we adopt the estimation procedures in Bai (2009), Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) for the estimation of β , Λ and F . The parameters β and Λ of the quantile it t τ;it it τ;it factor model with observable regressors are estimated using QR methods applied to a local kernel version of model (18) in which the unknown common factors have been replaced by consistent estimates. 2.2.1. Estimation of slope coefficients and common factors In order to estimate the parameters of model (2), we apply local principal components as in Su and Wang (2017). In contrast to these authors we consider a factor model that also includes observable regressors. In order to estimate the slope coefficients β and Λ we need a panel data structure it it with large N and T that guarantee the consistency of the common factors and factor loadings, respectively. To do this, we extend the iterative estimation procedure in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) to accommodate dynamics in the β and Λ coefficients, until we reach convergence. For s 2 ½T� fixed, we consider the Taylor expansion of the vector β about β for u close to u such that t s it is ðqÞ q m is β ¼ β þ ðu u Þ þ oðju u j Þ; (5) t s t s it is q! q¼1 ðqÞ with β high-order derivatives of the functional parameter β evaluated at u . For is it simplicity, we consider the local approximation of order zero given by β such that the is remaining terms in the approximation are in the error term. Similarly, we replace Λ by it Λ such that we estimate the model is Y ¼ X β þ F Λ þ e ; (6) it it t is it is with e an error term that includes the high-order approximation terms of the model it parameters. The parameters of model (6) are estimated from minimizing the following local weighted least squares problem: N T � � XX u u 2 t s min Y X β F Λ k ; (7) it it t is � � is N T h β ;fΛ g ;fF g f g is t i¼1 t¼1 is i¼1 t¼1 i¼1 6 A. ATAK ET AL. where kð�Þ is a kernel smoothing function. The solution to this problem can be obtained applying local principal component analysis (LPCA). To do this, we multiply both sides 1=2 u u t s of expression (6) by k , with k ¼ k , see Su and Wang (2017) for a similar h;ts h;ts h estimation strategy. We obtain 1=2 1=2 1=2 1=2 k Y ¼ k X β þ k F Λ þ k e : (8) it it t is it is h;ts h;ts h;ts h;ts � � ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Now, define Y ¼ k Y such that Y ¼ Y ; . . . ; Y is a T � 1 vector and Y ¼ it it i i1 iT h;ts � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 Y ; . . . ; Y is a T � N matrix. Similarly, let X ¼ k X such that l;it 1 N l;it h;ts � � � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ X ¼ X ; . . . ; X , for l ¼ 1; . . . ; d, with X ¼ X ; . . . ; X . Similarly, e ¼ i 1;i it l;i l;i1 l;iT d;i � � 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ k e such that e ¼ e ; . . . ; e is a T � 1 vector. Let F ¼ k F such that F ¼ it t t h;ts i i1 iT h;ts ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 ðF ; . . . ; F Þ is a T � R matrix and Λ ¼ ðΛ ; . . . ; Λ Þ be a R� N matrix. For each s 1s Ns 1 T individual in the cross section, Equation 8 in vector form is ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Y ¼ X β þ F Λ þ e : (9) is i i is i In this setting, for a fixed s 2 ½T�, the minimization problem (7) becomes " # � �� � ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ min tr Y F Λ Y F Λ ; (10) is is i i ðsÞ fβ ;F ;Λ g is is i¼1 ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ with tr denoting the trace of the matrix and Y ¼ Y X β . For parameter identi- i i i is ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 fication, we impose restrictions F F =T ¼ I and Λ Λ ¼ diagonal matrix, with Λ ¼ R s s ðΛ ; . . . ; Λ Þ a R� N matrix. This objective function is a locally weighted version of the 1s Ns least square estimator in Bai (2009). ðsÞ Applying the procedure developed by these authors, we can estimate β and F using is an iterative estimation procedure. This approach decomposes the original estimation problem into two steps: the estimation of the individual coefficients given common factors, and the estimation of the common factors given individual coefficients. We maintain their assumption that the number of factors R is known. The extension to an unknown number of factors under heterogeneous regression coefficients is cumbersome and beyond the scope of this paper. Thus when the number of unobserved factors is known, Bai (2009) proposes a tractable solution to the estimation problem by concen- trating out the factor loadings from the objective function (10). Following this procedure, we assume that the factor loadings Λ satisfy a relationship of the form is 0 0 1 ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b ^ b Λ ¼ ðF F Þ F Y , with Y ¼ Y X β and β an estimate of the vector is i i i i is is of slope coefficients for fixed s 2 ½T�. Then, replacing this expression into (10), the objective function is ( " ! #) N N X X 0 0 0 ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ b b min Y Y tr F Y Y F : (11) i i i i ðsÞ fβ ;F ;Λ g T is is i¼1 i¼1 Therefore, the problem of interest becomes JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 7 " ! # ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ b b max tr F Y Y F : (12) i i ðsÞ fβ ;F g is i¼1 ðsÞ The estimators fβ ; F g should simultaneously solve a system of nonlinear equations is 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β ¼ ðX M ðsÞ X Þ X M ðsÞ Y (13) is i i i i b b F F � � ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ b b b b with M ðsÞ ¼ I F F F F , and " # ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b b b Y Y F ¼ F V ; (14) i i NT NT i¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� b b where V is a diagonal matrix with the R largest eigenvalues of ðNTÞ Y Y , and NT pffiffiffiffi ðsÞ the estimated transformed factors F are interpreted as the T times eigenvectors ðsÞ� ðsÞ� b b corresponding to the R largest eigenvalues of the T � T matrix Y Y , arranged in descending order. The actual estimation procedure can be implemented by iterating each of the two steps in (13) and (14) until convergence. The unknown factor loadings are obtained as 1 0 ðsÞ� ðsÞ b b b Λ ¼ F Y : (15) is The estimation above involves only local data points, i.e., locally weighted in a neighbourhood of s 2 f1; . . . ; Tg, and hence, the local estimates of β and Λ converge is is pffiffiffiffiffiffi to the true parameters at Th rate. In contrast, the methodology developed in Ando and pffiffiffiffi Bai (2015) obtains global estimators that converge under slope heterogeneity at T for each i ¼ 1; . . . ; N . Under the assumption of slope homogeneity, Bai (2009) obtains pffiffiffiffiffiffiffi estimators of the true slope parameters that converge at NT. The next step is to derive a consistent estimator of the common factors F . We propose an estimator of the common factors from the minimization of the following least squares problem: N T � � XX b b min Y F Λ ; (16) t it it ffF g g t¼1 i¼1 t¼1 b b b with Y ¼ Y X β , where β is obtained from the above iterative estimation proce- it it it it it dure for each s 2 ½T�. The solution to this problem is N N X X 0 0 � b b b b b F ¼ Λ Λ Λ Y : (17) it it t it it i¼1 i¼1 2.2.2. Estimation of time-varying quantile factor loadings In what follows, we propose a procedure to estimate the parameters of the quantile process (18). The unobserved quantile common factors are replaced by estimates of F obtained from the conditional mean regression model, such that the regression of interest is 8 A. ATAK ET AL. Q ðY jX ; F Þ � a þ X β þ F Λ ; (18) τ it it t τ;it it t τ;it τ;it ðtÞ ðtÞ with Λ ¼ ½H � Λ and H a rotation matrix characterizing the common factors; τ;it τ;it � � � ðtÞ a ¼ s Λ , with s ¼ s H . More compactly, consider the following regression τ;it τt τt τ;it τt model. Let Y ¼ Z θ þ w ; (19) it it τ;it τ;it be the feasible counterpart of Y ¼ Z θ þ ε , with Q ε jX ; F ¼ 0. Here we are it it τ;it τ;it τ τ;it it t using the notation Z ¼ ½X F � (note that X already contains a constant) and it it t ðtÞ � b b Z ¼ ½X F �, and also w ¼ ε ðF F H ÞΛ . it it t τ;it τ;it t t τ;it Estimation of the model parameters follows by adapting the nonparametric approach for dynamic quantile processes in Cai and Xu (2008). These authors consider a polynomial approximation of the parameters θ ;θ ðu Þ about u given by θ and defined as τ;it τ;i t s τ;is " ! ! ! # 0 0 q q q X X X ðjÞ j ðjÞ j �ð jÞ j θ ¼ a þ a ðu u Þ β þ β ðu u Þ Λ þ Λ ðu u Þ ; τ;is τ;is t s t s t s τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is j¼1 j¼1 j¼1 ð� jÞ j � � with Λ þ Λ ðu u Þ the local approximation of the rotated factor loadings Λ . t s τ;is τ;is τ;it j¼1 ðjÞ ðjÞ �ð jÞ Note that a , β and Λ are the derivatives of order j of the respective functional τ;is τ;is τ;is coefficients. As in Cai and Xu (2008) we disregard in the following derivations the approximation error from using a polynomial Taylor expansion of order q, see Fan and Gijbels (1996) for the suitability of this method and, in particular, the advantages of the local linear approximation. The parameters of model (19) can be estimated from the following local objective function: � � � � 1 u u t s min ρ Y Z θ k ; (20) it it τ;is fθ g T τ;is h t¼1 where ρ ð�Þ ¼ �½τ 1ð�< 0Þ� is the check function of Koenker and Bassett (1978) and 1ð�Þ is an indicator function that takes a value of one if the argument is true and zero otherwise; h is a suitable bandwidth parameter for the quantile estimation problem. Estimation of the quantile parameters is obtained from the first-order conditions of the optimization problem (20). Estimation of the common factors for the quantile process is also possible in a quantile model (1) without intercept. In this case, by invoking Assumption A.1, we plug-in the factors estimated from the mean regression in Equation 6 and estimate the quantile factors as b b F ¼ F þb s ; (21) τt t τt 1 1 � � � b b b b b with s ¼ a ½Λ � , where a is obtained from (20) and ½Λ � is a N � R generalized τt τt τt τ;t τ;t inverse matrix of the R� N matrix Λ obtained from the elements τ;t JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 9 �ð jÞ j � � Λ � Λ þ Λ ðu u Þ , with � denoting a Taylor approximation of order q. t s τ;it τ;is τ;is j¼1 1 1 � � � b b b The matrix ½Λ � satisfies that Λ ½Λ � ¼ I . τ;t τ;t τ;t 2.3. Determining the number of factors In the previous analysis, we assume that the number of factors, R, is known. In the simulations and the empirical application we fix the number of factors to R ¼ 2, follow- ing the framework in Galvao et al. (2018) and Galvao et al. (2019). In practice, however, it is an important question to determine R from the data. Different information criteria type models have been applied to select the number of factors, although not for our specific panel data model, with N and T dimensions, that combines both mean- and quantile-based model specifications. The former determines the type of objective function that will be used in the information criterion. The latter determines how the penalty factor is constructed as a function of N , T and R. Following Su and Wang (2017) or in Casas et al. (2021) AIC or BIC can be applied to the mean- based factor model, where we can use the objective value function that is minimized to obtain the parameters, including the factors and the factor loadings. Ando and Bai (2020) propose a model for selecting the number of factors where the check objective function from QR is used in an AIC or BIC framework, and it also combines both dimensions in the criteria. 3. Asymptotic properties of the estimators This section presents the asymptotic properties of the proposed estimators for the model parameters – including the common factors – for processes (6) and (19). There are three unique features of the current problem that pose challenges to the econometric theory. First, the proposed estimators of the common factors and beta coefficients do not have a closed-form expression. These quantities are obtained by solving a set of equations to be ðsÞ satisfied simultaneously by β and F . Second, the unobserved common factors are it treated as parameters to be estimated, and thus the number of parameters grows with T. Finally, each pair ði; tÞ, with i 2 ½N� and t 2 ½T�, has its own slope coefficient β and it factor loading Λ such that the number of parameters grows with N and T. it Our goal in the remaining of the section is to derive the asymptotic distribution of the quantile parameter estimates of model (19). Our results build on the nonparametric quantile estimation methodology for dynamic smooth coefficient models introduced in Cai and Xu (2008). Our model is also closely related to the recent contribution of Ando and Bai (2020). The salient feature of our model compared to Ando and Bai (2020) is that the quantile common factors are treated as estimated regressors that are obtained from the mean model (2). 3.1. Assumptions We first state the following notations and assumptions. Let ε ¼ ðε ; . . . ; ε Þ be the error t 1t Nt 1 0 of the mean regression model in Assumption A.1. Then, we denote γ ðs; tÞ ¼ N E½ε ε �, N s 10 A. ATAK ET AL. 1 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 γ ðs; tÞ ¼ N E½F ε ε �, γ ðs; tÞ ¼ N E½F ε � ε F �, and � ¼ N ½ε ε E½ε ε ��. t t t st t t s s s s s s N;F N;FF P P P P 1=2 1=2 N T T N h 0 0 h pffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffi Define ω ðsÞ ¼ k F ε Λ , and ω ðr; sÞ ¼ NT;1 h;ts it NT;2 i¼1 t¼1 t is t¼1 i¼1 NT NT 0 0 k F ε ε E½F ε ε � . Let C<1 denote a positive constant that may vary from case h;ts it is it is t t to case. Assumption A.2. (Error terms and common factors). The error terms and common factors satisfy (i) E½ε jX ; F � ¼ 0 and E½jε j �<1 for all i and t in ½T�; it it t i;t 8 0 (ii) max E k F k <1 and E½F F � ¼ � > 0 for some R� R matrix � . 1� t� T t t F F (iii) max jCovðF F ; F F Þj � C for m; n ¼ 1; . . . ; R, where F 1� t� T t;m t;n s;m s;n t;m s¼1 th denotes the m element of F . P P T T (iv) max k γðs; tÞ k� C and max k γðs; tÞ k� C for γ ¼ 1� t� T 1� s� T s¼1 t¼1 γ ; γ and γ . N N;F N;FF 1=2 1=2 0 4 (v) max EjN � j � C and max E k N Λ ε k � C. 1� s;t� T st 1� s;t� T s (vi) ω ðrÞ ¼ O ð1Þ and max E k ω ðr; sÞk � C for each r. NT;1 P s NT;2 Assumption A.3. (Factor Loadings). The factor loading matrix Λ satisfies that is 1 0 1=2 (i) N Λ Λ ¼ � þ OðN Þ as N ! 1, where � is an R� R diagonal matrix. s Λ Λ s s s 1=2 1=2 (ii) V is the diagonal matrix consisting of the eigenvalues of � � � and satisfies s F Λ Λ s s that inf v > 0 for all diagonal elements ðv ; . . . ; v Þ. s2½T� rs 1s Rs 1=2 0 (iii) N Λ ε ! Nð0; Γ Þ for each s; t, where t st P P N N 1 0 Γ ¼ lim N Λ Λ E½ε ε �. st N!1 is it jt i¼1 j¼1 js pffiffi pffiffi P P ðsÞ ðsÞ T T h h 0 pffiffiffi pffiffiffi (iv) F ε ¼ k F ε ! Nð0; Ω Þ, where h;ts it is t¼1 it t¼1 t T T � � X X X h T 2h T 1 T 2 0 2 0 Ω ¼ lim k E½F F ε �þ k k E½F F ε ε � : ~ ~ ~ is T!1 t h;ts h;ts t it it h;ts t it t t¼1 t¼1 t¼tþ1 T T Assumption A.4. (Explanatory Variables). The vector of observable covariates satisfies ðsÞ (i) E k X k < C: it ðsÞ ðsÞ (ii) The d� d matrix X M ðsÞ ðsÞ X is positive definite. i F H i 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 0 1 1 pffiffiffi (iii) Let A ¼ X M ðsÞ X , B ¼ ðΛ Λ Þ� I , C ¼ Λ � ðX M ðsÞÞ. For is T i i F i i i i F T is is ðsÞ ðsÞ each s 2 ½T�, let A be the collection of F such that ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ A ¼ fF : F F =T ¼ I g. Then, we assume that ðsÞ inf DðF Þ is positive definite; ðsÞ ðsÞ F 2A ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ with DðF Þ ¼ DðF Þ, where DðF Þ ¼ B C A C and A is i i i i i i i i¼1 ðsÞ the generalized inverse of A . i JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 11 1 ðsÞ 0 ðsÞ (iv) lim T k E½H F X � ¼ Oð1Þ, for s ¼ 1; . . . ; T. (H is a rotation matrix h;qs iq T!1 q¼1 characterizing the factors defined above.) Assumption A.5. (i) The kernel function k : R ! R is a symmetric continuously differentiable probability density function with compact support ½ 1; 1�, (ii) As 2 2 1=2 ðN; TÞ ! 1, h ! 0, Th ! 1, Nh ! 1, Th=N ! 0, and Th=N ! 1. Assumption A.6. (Central Limit). As T ! 1, h ! 0, and Th ! 1; pffiffiffi ðsÞ ðsÞ pffiffiffiffi X M ε ! Nð0; � Þ; ðsÞ ðsÞ i F H i i h i T T P P h 0 with � ¼ lim k k E X M ε ε M X . ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ε h;ts h;τs it iτ iτ i it T F H F H τ τ T!1 t t t¼1 τ¼1 These assumptions are standard in factor models. A.2 and A.3 mainly impose moment conditions in the error terms, factors, factor loadings, and their interactions, see, e.g., Bai and Ng (2002), Bai (2003, 2009). The main difference, and in line with Su and Wang 0 1 0 1=2 (2017), is that we require E½F F � ¼ � in A.2(ii) and N Λ Λ ¼ � þ OðN Þ in t F s Λ t s s A.3(i). Assumptions A.2(iii)-(v) restrict the time and cross-sectional dependence for the idiosyncratic errors ε and the weak dependence between factors and errors, which are in it the same spirit as Bai (2003, 2009) and Su and Wang (2017). A.2(vi) is a kernel-weighted version of Assumptions F.1-F.2 in Bai (2003). Following the recent literature on factor models, we assume that E½F F � is homogeneous over t. This assumption is made for convenience to facilitate the asymptotic results. Assumption A.3(iii) allows for factor loadings to be time-varying and Assumption A.3(iv) is a kernel weighted version of Assumption F in Bai (2003). Both parts are used to establish the asymptotic normality of our local principal components estimators. We extend the assumptions in Su and Wang (2017) by incorporating a set of assumptions in A.4 specific to the observable regressors. Assumption A.4 (i)-(iii) impose the boundedness of moments and the regressors are assumed to exhibit sufficient variation such that the coefficients β are identifiable. it Identification also requires that the observed regressors do not exhibit multicollinearity with the unobservable common factors F . Condition (iii) in the assumption guarantees the unique minimizer of the estimation objective function. The notation DðFÞ is used to emphasize that the entire term is a function of F. Assumption A.5 states conditions on the rates of convergence that guarantee the consistency and asymptotic normality of the kernel estimators. A.6 simplifies the proofs and is imposed, for example, in Ando and Bai (2015). More primitive conditions to obtain the asymptotic properties of these objects can be found in Song (2013) for a global factor model. We consider now each cross-sectional observation separately, such that Z denotes Z t it for each i ¼ 1; . . . ; N . Let f ð�j�Þ be the conditional density of Y given Z . Let Ω ¼ yjZ it it ð ð 0 � 0 j j 2 E½Z Z � and Ω ¼ E½Z Z f ðQ ðτjZ ÞÞ�, and define μ ¼ u KðuÞdu and ν ¼ u K ðuÞdu. t t yjz y t j t t j The relevant bandwidth parameter for the quantile problem is h such � � � � u u 1 u u t s t s that k ¼ K . h e e e h h h 12 A. ATAK ET AL. Assumption B.1. β , Λ , β and Λ are ðmþ 1Þ th order continuously differenti- ir τ;ir ir τ;ir able in a neighbourhood of u for any u ¼ r=T . Further, f ðyÞ is bounded and satisfies r r yjz the Lipschitz condition. 2ð2þδÞ Assumption B.2. For each i ¼ 1; . . . ; N , E½jjZ jj �<1 for some δ> 0, where it Z ¼ fX ; F g. Furthermore, Ω and Ω are positive definite and continuous in it it t a neighbourhood of u . These functions and their inverse functions are uniformly bounded. Assumption B.3. For each i ¼ 1; . . . ; N , the process fX ; F ; ε g is strictly stationary it t it α mixing, with mixing coefficients δ ðsÞ satisfying max δ ðsÞ � CδðsÞ such that i 1� i� N i δðsÞ ¼ Oðs Þ with �¼ ð2þ δÞð1þ δÞ=δ. Th e e e Assumption B.4. The bandwidth parameter h satisfies h ! 0, Th ! 1, ! 0, and 1=2 δ=4 δ=δ 1=2 δ=4 T h ¼ Oð1Þ, for δ > δ. This set of assumptions is found in Cai (2007) and Cai and Xu (2008). The main difference with respect to the latter authors is the assumption ðThÞ=N ! 0 that allows us to remove the effect of estimating the common factors F from the asymptotic distribu- tion of the quantile parameter estimates. A similar assumption is also found in A.4 for the mean process. Under this set of additional assumptions, we obtain the asymptotic distribution of the quantile parameter estimates of β and Λ , for i 2 ½N� and τ;it τ;it t 2 ½T�. This result shows that the estimation of the common factors F does not have an effect on the asymptotic distribution of the quantile parameter estimates. 3.2. Propositions With these assumptions in place we are ready to derive the asymptotic results. We derive first the uniform consistency of the parameter estimators associated to the observable regressors. Proposition 1. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, it follows that max jjβ β jj ¼ o ð1Þ; as N; T ! 1: (22) it it fi2½N�;s2½T�g The proof of this result, in the Appendix, follows from extending the results in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) to the presence of time-varying slope coefficients. The uniform consistency of these coefficients allows us to extend the results in Su and Wang (2017) from a pure factor model specification to our setting. The following result shows ðsÞ ðsÞ the asymptotic normality of F to a rotation of the true factors F . t t JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 13 Proposition 2. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, for each s; t ¼ 1; . . . ; T, we have � � pffiffiffiffi 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 0 1 N k F F H ! Nð0; V Q Γ Q V Þ; asN ! 1; (23) s st t t h;ts s s s ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 0 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ where H ¼ ðN Λ Λ ÞðT F F Þ½V � ; V denotes the R� R diagonal matrix of s NT NT ðsÞ� ðsÞ� the first R largest eigenvalues of ðNTÞ Y Y , V is the diagonal matrix consisting of 1=2 1=2 the eigenvalues of � � � in descending order; Γ is the corresponding normalized F s Λ Λ s s 1=2 1=2 0 1 eigenvector matrix such that Γ Γ ¼ I , and Q ¼ V Γ � . s R s s s s Λ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ In particular, the consistency of the local factors F to F H allows us to derive the t t asymptotic distribution of the slope parameter estimators associated to the observable regressors. Proposition 3. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, for any fixed pair ði; tÞ with i ¼ 1; . . . ; N and t ¼ 1; . . . ; T, the vector β obtained from expression (13) satisfies it pffiffiffiffiffiffi Thðβ β Þ! Nð0; � Þ; (24) it it it � � � � 0 1 0 1 ðtÞ ðtÞ ðtÞ ðtÞ with � ¼ S L � S L , where S and L are matrices defined in ε ii ii ii ii i ii ii it the Appendix. The proof of this result follows from extending the results in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) to the presence of time-varying slope coefficients. Similarly, we show that the asymptotic distribution of the factor loading estimates is unaffected by including a set of observable covariates X with time-varying parameters β that vary smoothly over it it time. More formally, Proposition 4. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, for each s; t ¼ 1; . . . ; T, we have pffiffiffiffiffiffi ðsÞ 1 0 1 1 ThðΛ ½H � Λ Þ! Nð0;½Q � Ω ½Q � Þ; (25) is is is s " # T T 1 T P P P h 2 0 2 2h 0 with Ω ¼ lim k EðF F ε Þþ k k EðF F ε ε Þ . is q h;qs h;ts q iq it q iq t T h;qs T T!1 q¼1 q¼1 t¼qþ1 pffiffiffiffi These results allow us to show the N consistency of the common factors estimated in (17). Proposition 5. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, as N ! 1; the estimator (17) of the common factors satisfies � � pffiffiffiffi ðtÞ N F F H ! Nð0; � Þ; (26) t t F N N PP 1 1 1 1 1 0 with � ¼ ½� Q � Γ � Q , where Γ ¼ lim Λ Λ E½ε ε �. F tt tt it it jt t Λ t Λ t jt t t N N!1 i¼1 j¼1 14 A. ATAK ET AL. Proposition 6. Under Assumptions A.1-A.6 and B.1-B.4, as N; T ! 1; the estimator 0 0 0 0 0 0 � � b b b θ ¼ ½a β Λ � of θ ¼ ½a β Λ � obtained from the minimization problem τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is (20) satisfies that qffiffiffiffiffiffi ðqþ1Þ h qþ1 ðqþ1Þ e b e Th θ θ θ þ o ðh Þ ! Nð0; � Þ; (27) τ;is τ;is P τ is ðqþ 1Þ! h � � � �i 0 0 ðqþ1Þ ðqþ1Þ ðqþ1Þ �ð qþ1Þ with θ ¼ a μ β μ Λ μ and is τ;is qþ1 τ;is qþ1 τ;is qþ1 � 1 � 1 � ¼ τð1 τÞν ½Ω � Ω ½Ω � : τ 0 This result shows that the bias of the estimator of the quantile parameters decreases as one takes higher order local polynomial expansions of the functional coefficients in (19). Inference for this model is based on bootstrap implementation for panel data models with time-dependent data. Standard errors are estimated using bootstrap by resampling only from cross-sectional units with replacement as in Kapetanios (2008) and Galvao and Montes-Rojas (2015). See also Galvao et al. (2021) for a recent study that discusses the assumptions for asymptotic validity of the bootstrap in a similar framework. The following section explores the finite-sample performance of our two-stage esti- mation procedure. 4. Monte Carlo study Our Monte Carlo design is a variation of the Monte Carlo exercises proposed in Bai (2009), Harding and Lamarche (2014), and Su and Wang (2017). We are interested in showing the consistency of the parameter estimators under the presence of time-varying factor loadings. Consider the following data generating process with R ¼ 2 unknown factors: Y ¼ β þ β X þ Λ F þ Λ F þ 1þ �X þ γ F þ γ F ε : (28) it it it;1 1t it;2 2t it 1t 2t it 0 1 1 2 In this model as well as in the empirical application below we assume a set of common factors that is constant across quantiles. For this exercise the parameter of interest is the marginal effect on the conditional quantile, which corresponds to β ðτÞ ¼ β þ �Q ðτÞ. 1 1 The parameter � thus determines if there is heterogeneity across quantiles. For �¼ 0 we have a location-shift model while for �� 0 we have a location-scale shift model. The parameters γ and γ determine whether the factors also have an effect on the scale that 1 2 may potentially contaminate the estimators of the quantile marginal effects. We consider two distributions for the error term ε , Gaussian and standardized chi-squared with 1 it degree of freedom. For all models we fix β ¼ 0 and β ¼ 1, and we consider different 0 1 scenarios with �2 f0; 0:1g and ðγ ; γ Þ 2 fð0; 0Þ;ð0:1; 0:1Þg. For simplicity, we con- 1 2 sider X ,IID Nð0; 1Þ. it We generate the factors, j ¼ 1; 2, with the following model F ¼ ρ F þ η ; η ¼ ρ η þ e ; (29) j;t j;t 1 j;t f j;t j;t η j;t 1 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 15 where we assume for all cases that e are standard Gaussian independent random jt variables for i ¼ 1; . . . ; N, t ¼ 49; . . . ; 0; . . . ; T and j ¼ 1; 2. The common parameters are assumed ρ ¼ 0:90; ρ ¼ 0:25 as in Harding and Lamarche (2014). f η The time-varying factor loadings models for the common factors are DGP 1: Λ ,IID Nð0; 1Þ for j ¼ 1; 2; and DGP 2: Λ ¼ Λ ,IID Nð0; 1Þ for j ¼ 1; 2. DGP 1 it;j it;j i;j thus have factor loadings that vary across t and i while DGP 2 only varies across individuals. We study the finite-sample performance of two estimators of the slope parameters β . First, an estimator that considers time-varying factor loadings using the local estimation procedure developed in this paper, and denoted as β . In this case we are in fact estimating individual-specific coefficients (β , β and Λ for j ¼ 1; 2) for all it;j 0;it 1;it t ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; T. This estimator is thus the most demanding one. We will refer to this model as the local factor estimator. Second, we consider a model with time-invariant loadings, that is denoted as β . Here, we do not impose the time-varying local estimation procedure and, instead, we estimate a unique set of parameters (β , β and Λ for i;j 0 1 j ¼ 1; 2) for all t. The latter estimator will be referred to as the global factor estimator. In all cases we consider a fixed bandwidth of h ¼ h ¼ 1. In order to evaluate the performance of our estimators and for comparability pur- poses, we study bias and mean squared error (MSE) by comparing the estimates with the β ðτÞ parameter defined above. For the local factor estimator we compute the sample average across i and t of β for every simulation. For the global factor estimator we 1;it compute the sample average across i. The sample size of the different simulation experiments comprises all possible com- binations of N; T ¼ f20; 50; 100g. The number of Monte Carlo experiments is 200 in every case. Tables 1 and 2 report the simulation exercise results for the case with �¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0 for DGP1 and DGP2, respectively. In this case all coefficients should be 1 2 estimating the same value of 1 for all quantiles. Tables 3 and 4 report the simulation exercise results for the case with �¼ 0:1; γ ¼ γ ¼ 0 for DGP1 and DGP2, respectively; 1 2 Tables 5 and 6 study the case given by �¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0:1 for DGP1 and DGP2, 1 2 respectively. Importantly, the last two cases generate heterogeneity across quantiles such that the coefficient estimates are different across quantiles. First, note that there is no clear pattern for bias reduction when T or N increases leaving the other dimension constant. However, bias monotonically reduces when both N and T increase. There is, however, a mean square error (MSE) reduction when either N or T increases. These results provide empirical evidence on the consistency of the parameter estimators above as T and N increase. Second, the time-varying local estimator exhibits a larger MSE value than the global factor estimator. This result is expected as the local estimator is more demanding and uses fewer observations to estimate the para- meters. In contrast, the estimator offers additional flexibility as we can estimate time- varying coefficients. The ratios of the MSE performance of the two estimators are similar across specifications. Third, those simulation scenarios are given by an error term ε it following a chi-squared distribution show differences across quantiles for both estima- tors. One unexpected feature is that the MSE performance of τ ¼ 0:25 is worse than that of τ ¼ 0:75 for the local estimator. This may be the result of the estimated factors 16 A. ATAK ET AL. Table 1. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 1 it 20 20 −0.0360 0.0010 −0.0261 0.0055 −0.0303 0.0046 0.3681 0.0252 0.3527 0.0167 0.4850 0.0216 20 50 −0.0129 0.0003 −0.0154 −0.0007 −0.0142 0.0028 0.1010 0.0070 0.0994 0.0050 0.0943 0.0084 20 100 0.0060 0.0015 0.0145 0.0031 0.0141 0.0042 0.0333 0.0047 0.0376 0.0028 0.0283 0.0036 50 20 0.0088 −0.0098 0.0188 −0.0088 0.0184 −0.0080 0.1536 0.0125 0.1787 0.0083 0.1469 0.0099 50 50 −0.0140 −0.0012 −0.0148 0.0003 −0.0133 0.0009 0.0508 0.0034 0.0527 0.0027 0.0501 0.0036 50 100 0.0064 0.0012 0.0015 0.0004 0.0050 0.0020 0.0132 0.0016 0.0128 0.0011 0.0126 0.0011 100 20 0.0064 −0.0021 0.0065 0.0005 0.0135 0.0047 0.1263 0.0050 0.1027 0.0034 0.0936 0.0065 100 50 −0.0045 −0.0016 −0.0094 −0.0029 −0.0149 −0.0005 0.0184 0.0016 0.0168 0.0012 0.0191 0.0016 100 100 −0.0072 −0.0026 −0.0042 −0.0022 −0.0076 0.0005 0.0082 0.0008 0.0074 0.0005 0.0067 0.0007 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 2 it 20 20 −0.0177 0.0170 −0.0071 0.0141 −0.0080 0.0110 0.4007 0.0262 0.4420 0.0196 0.4676 0.0257 20 50 0.0330 −0.0013 0.0170 0.0035 0.0213 0.0108 0.1544 0.0077 0.1150 0.0049 0.1060 0.0070 20 100 0.0186 −0.0022 0.0125 0.0001 −0.0049 −0.0004 0.0906 0.0034 0.0987 0.0026 0.0486 0.0035 50 20 0.0351 −0.0015 0.0175 0.0030 0.0104 0.0031 0.1322 0.0095 0.1392 0.0071 0.1422 0.0103 50 50 0.0216 0.0017 0.0249 0.0022 0.0246 0.0030 0.0462 0.0031 0.0511 0.0024 0.0577 0.0032 50 100 0.0075 0.0002 0.0073 −0.0001 0.0106 0.0040 0.0147 0.0018 0.0144 0.0012 0.0156 0.0014 100 20 0.0173 −0.0034 0.0085 −0.0007 −0.0055 −0.0006 0.1131 0.0057 0.0972 0.0035 0.0797 0.0054 100 50 −0.0131 −0.0007 −0.0150 0.0032 −0.0137 −0.0004 0.0206 0.0014 0.0225 0.0010 0.0174 0.0017 100 100 0.0065 0.0017 0.0073 0.0026 0.0045 0.0002 0.0049 0.0007 0.0044 0.0005 0.0044 0.0007 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 17 Table 2. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,χ , DGP 1 it 20 20 −0.0295 0.0037 0.0182 0.0035 −0.0122 −0.0058 1.4004 0.0168 0.6702 0.0135 0.3696 0.0231 20 50 −0.0111 −0.0018 −0.0007 0.0015 0.0007 0.0070 0.0826 0.0054 0.0732 0.0040 0.0784 0.0055 20 100 0.0191 −0.0022 0.0262 −0.0014 0.0370 −0.0026 0.0482 0.0027 0.0505 0.0018 0.0336 0.0026 50 20 0.0293 0.0019 0.0209 0.0015 0.0218 −0.0008 0.2709 0.0068 0.2654 0.0049 0.2623 0.0061 50 50 −0.0081 0.0057 −0.0105 0.0033 −0.0085 0.0064 0.0346 0.0023 0.0377 0.0015 0.0362 0.0023 50 100 0.0151 0.0018 0.0101 0.0020 0.0028 0.0016 0.0116 0.0010 0.0112 0.0007 0.0121 0.0010 100 20 −0.0317 −0.0033 −0.0334 0.0003 −0.0302 0.0001 0.1769 0.0040 0.1805 0.0029 0.1825 0.0036 100 50 0.0097 −0.0013 0.0041 −0.0003 −0.0072 0.0022 0.0280 0.0011 0.0283 0.0007 0.0223 0.0012 100 100 0.0056 0.0009 0.0043 0.0004 −0.0015 −0.0003 0.0061 0.0005 0.0062 0.0004 0.0099 0.0005 ε ,χ , DGP 2 it 20 20 −0.0475 −0.0031 −0.0207 0.0029 0.0249 0.0077 0.3110 0.0225 0.3397 0.0154 0.4451 0.0216 20 50 0.0179 0.0084 0.0194 0.0045 0.0231 −0.0006 0.0832 0.0058 0.0959 0.0035 0.0938 0.0059 20 100 −0.0006 −0.0013 −0.0032 −0.0015 0.0004 0.0002 0.0353 0.0026 0.0354 0.0017 0.0510 0.0028 50 20 −0.0243 −0.0105 −0.0253 −0.0032 −0.0134 −0.0006 0.2504 0.0091 0.2696 0.0056 0.2395 0.0071 50 50 0.0063 −0.0015 −0.0034 0.0022 −0.0042 0.0028 0.0309 0.0025 0.0533 0.0016 0.0438 0.0023 50 100 −0.0170 0.0005 −0.0135 0.0001 −0.0105 0.0005 0.0116 0.0010 0.0116 0.0009 0.0148 0.0010 100 20 0.0009 0.0034 −0.0026 0.0028 0.0026 −0.0021 0.0983 0.0031 0.1261 0.0029 0.0895 0.0039 100 50 −0.0695 −0.0036 −0.0159 −0.0016 −0.0106 −0.0037 0.7384 0.0012 0.0121 0.0008 0.0129 0.0011 100 100 0.0005 −0.0014 −0.0001 0.0004 0.0000 −0.0018 0.0081 0.0007 0.0083 0.0004 0.0075 0.0005 18 A. ATAK ET AL. Table 3. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ 0:1; γ ¼ γ ¼ 0. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 1 it 20 20 0.0098 0.0354 −0.0505 −0.0026 −0.0753 −0.0374 0.4408 0.0318 0.4566 0.0237 0.3714 0.0249 20 50 0.0397 0.0138 −0.0184 −0.0103 −0.0889 −0.0349 0.3219 0.0282 0.3170 0.0245 0.3828 0.0269 20 100 0.0756 0.0213 0.0041 0.0004 −0.1157 −0.0244 0.3268 0.0234 0.2997 0.0154 0.2746 0.0287 50 20 0.0613 0.0321 0.0245 −0.0075 −0.0311 −0.0414 0.3470 0.0243 0.3390 0.0154 0.3849 0.0280 50 50 0.0786 0.0296 0.0126 0.0028 −0.0669 −0.0243 0.0681 0.0078 0.0752 0.0056 0.0947 0.0087 50 100 0.0681 0.0251 −0.0022 −0.0014 −0.0694 −0.0248 0.0681 0.0099 0.0732 0.0055 0.0809 0.0088 100 20 0.0619 0.0333 −0.0177 0.0023 −0.0873 −0.0357 0.0815 0.0092 0.0869 0.0071 0.1002 0.0148 100 50 0.0754 0.0286 0.0179 0.0029 −0.0540 −0.0249 0.0803 0.0087 0.1104 0.0061 0.1222 0.0132 100 100 0.0652 0.0247 −0.0015 0.0005 −0.0686 −0.0217 0.0308 0.0038 0.0255 0.0029 0.9163 0.0042 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 2 it 20 20 0.0716 0.0354 0.0367 −0.0040 −0.0595 −0.0401 0.0400 0.0048 0.0405 0.0026 0.0485 0.0048 20 50 0.0724 0.0337 0.0068 −0.0004 −0.0640 −0.0339 0.0322 0.0057 0.0357 0.0038 0.0585 0.0098 20 100 0.0408 0.0295 −0.0284 0.0020 −0.0888 −0.0254 0.0342 0.0059 0.0383 0.0043 0.0545 0.0094 50 20 0.0851 0.0246 0.0153 −0.0047 −0.0892 −0.0392 0.1974 0.0099 0.1305 0.0078 0.1730 0.0123 50 50 0.1059 0.0276 0.0018 0.0022 −0.0604 −0.0245 0.3655 0.0096 0.3506 0.0072 0.3184 0.0131 50 100 0.0662 0.0223 −0.0022 −0.0004 −0.0713 −0.0244 0.3033 0.0096 0.1910 0.0084 0.1797 0.0165 100 20 0.1031 0.0393 0.0330 0.0082 −0.0347 −0.0217 0.4136 0.0112 0.3090 0.0081 0.5705 0.0161 100 50 0.0584 0.0252 0.0062 −0.0024 −0.0609 −0.0323 0.0403 0.0043 0.0323 0.0025 0.0425 0.0044 100 100 0.0618 0.0224 −0.0053 −0.0020 −0.0719 −0.0244 0.3769 0.0039 0.1005 0.0020 0.0638 0.0034 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 19 Table 4. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ 0:1; γ ¼ γ ¼ 0. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 1 it 20 20 0.0098 0.0354 −0.0505 −0.0026 −0.0753 −0.0374 0.4408 0.0318 0.4566 0.0237 0.3714 0.0249 20 50 0.0397 0.0138 −0.0184 −0.0103 −0.0889 −0.0349 0.3219 0.0282 0.3170 0.0245 0.3828 0.0269 20 100 0.0756 0.0213 0.0041 0.0004 −0.1157 −0.0244 0.3268 0.0234 0.2997 0.0154 0.2746 0.0287 50 20 0.0613 0.0321 0.0245 −0.0075 −0.0311 −0.0414 0.3470 0.0243 0.3390 0.0154 0.3849 0.0280 50 50 0.0786 0.0296 0.0126 0.0028 −0.0669 −0.0243 0.0681 0.0078 0.0752 0.0056 0.0947 0.0087 50 100 0.0681 0.0251 −0.0022 −0.0014 −0.0694 −0.0248 0.0681 0.0099 0.0732 0.0055 0.0809 0.0088 100 20 0.0619 0.0333 −0.0177 0.0023 −0.0873 −0.0357 0.0815 0.0092 0.0869 0.0071 0.1002 0.0148 100 50 0.0754 0.0286 0.0179 0.0029 −0.0540 −0.0249 0.0803 0.0087 0.1104 0.0061 0.1222 0.0132 100 100 0.0652 0.0247 −0.0015 0.0005 −0.0686 −0.0217 0.0308 0.0038 0.0255 0.0029 0.9163 0.0042 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 2 it 20 20 0.0716 0.0354 0.0367 −0.0040 −0.0595 −0.0401 0.0400 0.0048 0.0405 0.0026 0.0485 0.0048 20 50 0.0724 0.0337 0.0068 −0.0004 −0.0640 −0.0339 0.0322 0.0057 0.0357 0.0038 0.0585 0.0098 20 100 0.0408 0.0295 −0.0284 0.0020 −0.0888 −0.0254 0.0342 0.0059 0.0383 0.0043 0.0545 0.0094 50 20 0.0851 0.0246 0.0153 −0.0047 −0.0892 −0.0392 0.1974 0.0099 0.1305 0.0078 0.1730 0.0123 50 50 0.1059 0.0276 0.0018 0.0022 −0.0604 −0.0245 0.3655 0.0096 0.3506 0.0072 0.3184 0.0131 50 100 0.0662 0.0223 −0.0022 −0.0004 −0.0713 −0.0244 0.3033 0.0096 0.1910 0.0084 0.1797 0.0165 100 20 0.1031 0.0393 0.0330 0.0082 −0.0347 −0.0217 0.4136 0.0112 0.3090 0.0081 0.5705 0.0161 100 50 0.0584 0.0252 0.0062 −0.0024 −0.0609 −0.0323 0.0403 0.0043 0.0323 0.0025 0.0425 0.0044 100 100 0.0618 0.0224 −0.0053 −0.0020 −0.0719 −0.0244 0.3769 0.0039 0.1005 0.0020 0.0638 0.0034 20 A. ATAK ET AL. Table 5. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0:1. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 1 it 20 20 0.0483 0.0088 0.0094 −0.0183 −0.0527 −0.0551 0.3497 0.0299 0.2694 0.0211 0.2821 0.0318 20 50 0.0827 0.0287 0.0023 −0.0030 −0.0732 −0.0261 0.1266 0.0076 0.0815 0.0063 0.0807 0.0088 20 100 0.0618 0.0194 −0.0002 −0.0020 −0.0663 −0.0253 0.0274 0.0041 0.0255 0.0026 0.0310 0.0042 50 20 0.0811 0.0357 0.0242 0.0039 −0.0502 −0.0242 0.1440 0.0115 0.1806 0.0094 0.1830 0.0105 50 50 0.0826 0.0264 0.0112 −0.0014 −0.0441 −0.0246 0.0875 0.0036 0.0307 0.0023 0.0290 0.0040 50 100 0.0600 0.0221 −0.0138 0.0005 −0.0815 −0.0255 0.0164 0.0018 0.0122 0.0008 0.0184 0.0020 100 20 0.0421 0.0452 −0.0164 0.0091 −0.0853 −0.0313 0.1163 0.0086 0.1127 0.0042 0.1156 0.0073 100 50 0.0521 0.0289 −0.0099 −0.0008 −0.0766 −0.0294 0.0412 0.0025 0.0391 0.0014 0.0326 0.0023 100 100 0.0543 0.0234 −0.0084 −0.0031 −0.0742 −0.0247 0.0110 0.0012 0.0069 0.0006 0.0130 0.0013 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 2 it 20 20 0.0958 0.0361 0.0328 0.0070 −0.0296 −0.0261 0.4316 0.0276 0.3980 0.0188 0.4147 0.0214 20 50 0.0790 0.0259 0.0268 0.0008 −0.0236 −0.0396 0.1781 0.0076 0.1971 0.0056 0.2013 0.0095 20 100 0.0707 0.0256 −0.0089 0.0018 −0.0798 −0.0226 0.0328 0.0047 0.0293 0.0032 0.0366 0.0046 50 20 0.0762 0.0406 0.0172 −0.0045 −0.0512 −0.0331 0.1733 0.0102 0.1624 0.0077 0.1668 0.0116 50 50 0.0737 0.0275 0.0001 0.0031 −0.0760 −0.0262 0.0432 0.0038 0.0378 0.0023 0.0415 0.0039 50 100 0.0692 0.0290 0.0030 0.0006 −0.0703 −0.0267 0.0167 0.0024 0.0128 0.0010 0.0186 0.0022 100 20 0.1016 0.0305 0.0331 −0.0009 −0.0368 −0.0331 0.0970 0.0049 0.0828 0.0032 0.0836 0.0058 100 50 0.0788 0.0293 0.0022 0.0010 −0.0643 −0.0244 0.0300 0.0027 0.0225 0.0012 0.0243 0.0023 100 100 0.0737 0.0255 0.0072 −0.0004 −0.0639 −0.0257 0.0137 0.0015 0.0060 0.0006 0.0095 0.0015 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 21 Table 6. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ :1. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ :25 τ ¼ :5 τ ¼ :75 τ ¼ :25 τ ¼ :5 τ ¼ :75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,χ , DGP 1 it 20 20 0.0422 −0.0353 0.0128 −0.0521 −0.0868 −0.0820 0.3387 0.0231 0.3161 0.0165 0.4824 0.0279 20 50 −0.0466 −0.0535 −0.0635 −0.0480 −0.1576 −0.0929 0.1308 0.0099 0.0978 0.0078 0.0985 0.0141 20 100 0.0261 −0.0543 −0.0133 −0.0427 −0.0964 −0.0855 0.1126 0.0065 0.1181 0.0038 0.1278 0.0094 50 20 −0.0159 −0.0457 −0.0348 −0.0522 −0.1200 −0.0991 0.2613 0.0109 0.5243 0.0082 0.5611 0.0180 50 50 −0.0196 −0.0534 −0.0512 −0.0436 −0.1536 −0.0860 0.0425 0.0053 0.0471 0.0035 0.0631 0.0095 50 100 −0.0069 −0.0584 −0.0291 −0.0446 −0.1145 −0.0801 0.0118 0.0047 0.1143 0.0027 0.1316 0.0075 100 20 −0.0214 −0.0425 −0.0495 −0.0436 −0.1318 −0.0915 0.0501 0.0061 0.0577 0.0046 0.0855 0.0124 100 50 −0.0180 −0.0583 −0.0493 −0.0481 −0.1304 −0.0865 0.0200 0.0048 0.0203 0.0032 0.0341 0.0086 100 100 −0.0074 −0.0572 −0.0503 −0.0478 −0.1382 −0.0870 0.0057 0.0039 0.0080 0.0027 0.0246 0.0082 ε ,χ , DGP 2 it 20 20 0.0015 −0.0512 −0.0190 −0.0390 −0.0332 −0.0811 0.3054 0.0252 0.2958 0.0131 3.1877 0.0237 20 50 −0.0190 −0.0497 −0.0488 −0.0368 −0.1300 −0.0793 0.0638 0.0085 0.0603 0.0059 0.0724 0.0120 20 100 0.0069 −0.0551 −0.0139 −0.0417 −0.1105 −0.0849 0.0442 0.0054 0.0573 0.0035 0.0479 0.0097 50 20 0.0010 −0.0484 −0.0333 −0.0397 −0.1631 −0.0857 0.1740 0.0115 0.1684 0.0075 0.1699 0.0153 50 50 −0.0277 −0.0575 −0.0600 −0.0425 −0.1505 −0.0849 0.0334 0.0060 0.0444 0.0033 0.0680 0.0094 50 100 −0.0254 −0.0658 −0.0647 −0.0485 −0.1521 −0.0870 0.0136 0.0057 0.0208 0.0032 0.0402 0.0086 100 20 −0.0374 −0.0458 −0.0648 −0.0451 −0.1398 −0.0925 0.1174 0.0065 0.1255 0.0052 0.1347 0.0129 100 50 −0.0172 −0.0549 −0.0482 −0.0443 −0.1424 −0.0872 0.0163 0.0042 0.0178 0.0029 0.0382 0.0088 100 100 −0.0056 −0.0580 −0.0398 −0.0460 −0.1230 −0.0838 0.0060 0.0039 0.0081 0.0025 0.0213 0.0075 22 A. ATAK ET AL. absorbing a more substantial portion of the variance in the quantile location with more probability mass. 5. Empirical application This section applies the above model to an empirical asset pricing context. In contrast to standard asset pricing models, we explore the distributional risk premia by fitting the above models to different quantiles of the distribution of excess returns. We are interested in assessing the effect of including unobserved local factors with time- varying factor loadings in standard asset pricing specifications. The methodology developed above also allows us to estimate dynamic parameter estimates measuring the sensitivity of the quantile process of excess returns to a set of idiosyncratic firm- specific factors that are combined with Fama and French (1993) three-factor model. 5.1. Data The set of firm-specific covariates X is obtained from a panel of U.S. firms and obtained it from Compustat Industrial dataset. The sample consists of annual CRSP/Compustat data from the years 1970 through 2011. Following standard practice, we exclude financial firms (SIC codes 6000–6999), regulated utilities (SIC codes 4900–4999), and non-profit organizations (SIC codes greater than or equal to 9000). We omit firm-years with a missing or negative value for fixed assets and sales, with a missing or less than ten million 1983 dollar book value of total assets, and with growth rates of fixed assets, sales, and the book value of total assets greater than 100%. We consider the following list of firm characteristics: MB denotes firms’ market- to-book ratio; LNTA denotes the log of the firm’s asset size; EBITTA denotes earnings before interest and taxes as a proportion of total assets; MDR denotes the market debt ratio, defined as the book value of debt over the market value of assets; and DEPTA denotes depreciation as a proportion of total assets. The set of covariates is completed by the following observable pricing factors taken from Kenneth French website. The common pricing factors are MKTRF, SMB and HML. The factor MKTRF is defined as a value-weighted average market portfolio return net of the risk-free asset. The risk-free rate is proxied by daily returns on the U.S. three-month Treasury bill. The factor SMB is a small-minus-big portfolio constructed as the difference between the returns on diversified portfolios of small and large asset size. The factor HML is high-minus-low portfolio constructed as the difference between the returns on diversified portfolios of high and small book-to- market equity. The firms’ excess returns are the annual excess return on assets computed over the annual interest rate offered by one-month U.S. Treasury bills. The final sample includes a balanced panel of 297 firms with 2 years of data. Although there is no consensus in the literature on the length of the time dimension; we acknowledge that the time dimension selection criteria might favor larger and more mature companies, which may lead to the results being valid only for large and mature companies. However, the average estimated effects from our sample are in line with the consensus in the literature, and thus, the results could be applied to all companies. The log of total assets is the only variable that is not a ratio, and is deflated to the 1983 dollar with the consumer price index obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 23 5.2. Empirical models In a similar spirit to Giovannetti (2013), Galvao et al. (2018) and Galvao et al. (2019), we propose a quantile process for modelling the distribution of excess returns. The objective of this study is to show if an empirical pricing strategy based on firm-specific variables coupled with unobserved quantile factors with time-varying loadings is able to explain the cross-section of excess returns on a set of U.S. firms. As a byproduct, we also study if this model adds predictive ability to the standard Fama-French three-factor model. The pricing factors of our baseline model are firm-specific financial ratios, see Kogan and Papanikolaou (2013) for a discussion of empirical asset pricing models using firm- specific variables. This approach has recently gained support due to the strong evidence of the co-movement in stock returns of firms with similar characteristics that is unrelated to their exposures to the market portfolio. Our baseline model is Q Y j X ; F ¼ X β þ F Λ ; i ¼ 1; . . . ; n; t ¼ 1; . . . ; T; (30) τ it it τ;it it τ;it τ;it τ;it with τ 2 ð0; 1Þ and R ¼ 2. We assume that the unobserved common factors for the quantile model are location shift transformations of the estimates of the mean factors F 1t and F . The shifts defining the quantile factors are captured by the values of the dynamic 2t intercepts a of the different quantile models. We estimate two versions of this model τ;it for τ 2 f0:10; 0:25; 0:50; 0:75; 0:90g. A first version considers global factors and uses the methodology proposed in Ando and Bai (2015) to estimate the factors, F , which are then used to estimate the set of parameters ðβ ; Λ Þ. The second version considers local τ;i factors and uses the methodology developed above to estimate the time-varying para- meters ðβ ; Λ Þ. Note that the loadings associated to the observable covariates do not τ;it τ;it only vary over time but also across individuals. We consider two models. Model 1 uses only firm-specific covariates, X ¼ ½MBR; EBITTA; MB; DEPTA; LNTA�. Model 2 aug- ments the above model by MKTRF, SMB, and HML. Standard errors are estimated using bootstrap by resampling only from cross-sectional units with replacement as in Kapetanios (2008) and Galvao and Montes-Rojas (2015) using 100 replications. In all cases the bandwidth parameter is set to 10. The results are reported in Tables 7–10. The results are an extension of the findings in Galvao et al. (2018). In this case, we incorporate the presence of unobserved common factors. Firm-specific covariates are Table 7. Model 1. Firm-specific quantile regression model with R ¼ 2 unobserved factors. Global factors with fixed loadings. Standard errors are in brackets. 0.10 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.90 CONST −8.912 −7.582 −5.427 −6.313 −4.827 (1.661) (1.100) (0.925) (1.112) (1.847) MDR 2.963 2.447 2.412 2.603 3.067 (0.379) (0.219) (0.189) (0.206) (0.321) EBITTA 0.806 0.211 −0.040 −0.193 −0.519 (0.388) (0.251) (0.264) (0.288) (0.475) MB −0.053 −0.118 −0.174 −0.123 0.006 (0.058) (0.046) (0.045) (0.055) (0.076) DEPTA −4.647 −4.734 −5.820 −7.949 −10.123 (2.178) (1.515) (1.314) (1.646) (2.515) LNTA 0.397 0.359 0.275 0.344 0.278 (0.086) (0.056) (0.046) (0.057) (0.098) 24 A. ATAK ET AL. Table 8. Model 1. Firm-specific quantile regression model with R ¼ 2 unobserved factors. Local factors with time-varying factor loadings. Standard errors are in brackets. 0.10 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.90 CONST −6.688 −4.522 −3.422 −1.886 −0.582 (0.921) (0.672) (0.606) (0.721) (1.119) MBR 2.514 2.185 2.344 2.605 2.869 (0.185) (0.138) (0.153) (0.201) (0.293) EBITTA 0.830 0.129 −0.122 −0.410 −0.454 (0.346) (0.234) (0.233) (0.277) (0.390) MB −0.024 −0.105 −0.116 −0.079 −0.005 (0.063) (0.046) (0.041) (0.045) (0.076) DEPTA −3.722 −5.923 −6.927 −8.828 −11.270 (1.818) (1.190) (1.131) (1.515) (2.445) LNTA 0.276 0.199 0.163 0.108 0.061 (0.045) (0.033) (0.030) (0.036) (0.056) Table 9. Model 2. Quantile regression model with R ¼ 2 unobserved global factors with fixed loadings. The model considers firm-specific covariates and Fama-French three-factor model. Standard errors are in brackets. 0.10 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.90 CONST −8.582 −5.759 −4.869 −4.649 −6.279 (1.420) (0.919) (0.729) (1.000) (1.981) MBR 2.386 2.095 2.093 2.330 2.640 (0.325) (0.198) (0.180) (0.214) (0.307) MB −0.129 −0.259 −0.391 −0.530 −0.260 (0.355) (0.218) (0.243) (0.255) (0.418) EBITTA −0.039 −0.112 −0.171 −0.072 0.027 (0.059) (0.045) (0.042) (0.053) (0.082) DEPTA −3.545 −4.978 −6.824 −7.539 −8.431 (1.982) (1.494) (1.382) (1.577) (2.596) LNTA 0.405 0.278 0.256 0.265 0.356 (0.075) (0.047) (0.039) (0.054) (0.104) MKTRF −0.510 −0.520 −0.615 −0.620 −0.620 0.062 0.048 0.043 0.057 0.094 SMB −0.840 −0.787 −0.740 −0.767 −0.797 0.107 0.074 0.063 0.070 0.123 HML −0.182 −0.189 −0.215 −0.212 −0.192 0.089 0.058 0.055 0.062 0.104 statistically significant in all models, and the model parameter estimates are similar across the different specifications of the empirical asset pricing model reported in Tables 7–10. The estimates reported for the model with local factors are averages across time and individuals of the parameter estimates of β for i ¼ 1; . . . ; N and t ¼ 1; . . . ; T. it Our empirical asset pricing model uncovers a positive exposure of firms’ excess returns to the market-to-book ratio (MDR) and the log of asset size (LNTA) and negative exposure to the market debt ratio (MB) and depreciation as a proportion of total assets (DEPTA). Earnings before interest and taxes as a proportion of total assets (EBITTA) have a positive effect on low quantiles and turn negative for τ ¼ 0:5 and beyond. The quantile parameter estimates are monotonically increasing on τ 2 ð0; 1Þ for LNTA and monotonically decreasing for DEPTA. All the coefficients are statistically significant at 5% significance levels. Tables 7–8 report the baseline case in expression (30) given by firm-specific covariates, Tables 9–10 report the pricing model augmented with Fama- French three-factor model. The results are also similar across specifications and JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 25 Table 10. Model 2: Quantile regression model with R ¼ 2 unobserved local factors with time-varying factor loadings. The model considers firm-specific covariates and Fama- French three-factor model. Standard errors are in brackets. 0.10 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.90 CONST −4.938 −3.503 −2.407 −1.710 −1.325 (0.788) (0.631) (0.548) (0.628) (1.021) MBR 2.319 1.988 2.020 2.222 2.267 (0.173) (0.135) (0.145) (0.170) (0.303) MB 0.081 −0.339 −0.478 −0.790 −0.511 (0.327) (0.224) (0.221) (0.238) (0.385) EBITTA −0.067 −0.127 −0.122 −0.065 0.026 (0.055) (0.038) (0.037) (0.045) (0.079) DEPTA −4.456 −6.037 −7.709 −9.996 −11.785 (1.927) (1.422) (1.211) (1.556) (2.256) LNTA 0.202 0.159 0.124 0.106 0.104 (0.037) (0.030) (0.026) (0.030) (0.049) MKTRF −0.516 −0.546 −0.588 −0.612 −0.636 0.070 0.051 0.049 0.065 0.100 SMB −0.724 −0.705 −0.716 −0.736 −0.677 0.121 0.095 0.077 0.086 0.135 HML −0.195 −0.221 −0.237 −0.231 −0.240 0.090 0.059 0.061 0.076 0.126 Figure 1. Model 2: Dynamics of β . 0.10 (blue), 0.25 (red), 0.50 (black), 0.75 (brown), and 0.90 (green) τ;t quantile coefficients with 95% confidence interval calculated with 200 bootstrap RTN α þ β MDR þ β EBITTA þ β MB þ β DEPTA þ i;tþ1 i i;t i;t i;t i;t it;MDR it;EBITTA it;MB it;DEPTA replications. β LNTA þ β MKTRF þ β SMB þ β HML þ ε it;LNTA i;t it;MKTRF i;t it;SMB i;t it;HML i;t i;tþ1 26 A. ATAK ET AL. Figure 2. Model 2 continued. Notes: 0.10 (blue), 0.25 (red), 0.50 (black), 0.75 (brown), and 0.90 (green) quantile coefficients with 95% confidence interval calculated with 200 bootstrap replications. RTN α þ β MDR þ β EBITTA þ β MB þ β DEPTA þ i;tþ1 i i;t i;t i;t i;t it;MDR it;EBITTA it;MB it;DEPTA β LNTA þ β MKTRF þ β SMB þ β HML þ ε i;t i;t i;t i;t i;tþ1 it;LNTA it;MKTRF it;SMB it;HML estimation methods. However, the magnitude of the model parameters changes signifi- cantly between the global and local factor estimation methods. The pricing model with local factors provides similar insights to the model with unobserved global factors but has the additional advantage of offering the possibility of studying the dynamics of the loadings β associated to each observable covariate. These τ;it dynamics are reported in Figures 1–2, corresponding to the local factor model with the augmented set of covariates in Table 10. Importantly, the model also allows the possibi- lity of studying the dynamics of the unobserved common factor loadings Λ , never- τ;it theless, we do not report these values as an interpretation of the results is difficult due to the lack of interpretation of the common factor estimates. Each panel reports five lines that reflect the dynamics of the parameters β over time. These estimates are constructed τ;t as the cross-sectional average of β for each t and the standard errors are calculated by τ;it bootstrap. The results show how the exposure of the excess returns to some covariates and factor models have evolved over time. The figures show that there was little variation in the average effects, and they are all within the 95% confidence interval of each other. One limitation in the analysis is that the time dimension (T ¼ 42) does not allow us to obtain a finer set of local estimates. JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 27 6. Conclusion This paper proposes a functional coefficient quantile regression model with time- varying factor loadings. Estimation of the quantile factors and factor loadings is done in two stages. First, we estimate the unobserved common factors from a linear factor mean-based model with exogenous covariates. In the second stage, we plug-in an affine transformation of the estimates of the common factors to obtain the quantile version of the factor model. This model requires both the number of individuals and the number of periods to grow to infinity. The number of individuals needs to diverge for the consistent estimation of the common factors in the first stage. Also, to consistently estimate the quantile factor loadings the number of time periods needs to diverge as well. As a byproduct, our model can capture dynamics and heterogeneity across individuals in both the quantile slope coefficients and the quantile factor loadings. The introduction of time-varying coefficients adds flexibility to standard factor model specifications that assume slope homogeneity as in Bai (2003, 2009) and slope heterogeneity as in Ando and Bai (2015). The model also extends the recent partial linear model of Su and Wang (2017) by considering the quantile process and including the presence of exogenous regressors. This model specification is applied in an empirical application to explain the distribu- tion of the excess returns for a cross-section of asset returns in the U.S. In contrast to standard asset pricing formulations, we consider firm-specific covariates as pricing factors and allow for the presence of two unobserved factors. The model provides satisfactory estimates of the sensitivity of the excess return to the pricing variables under both global (Ando & Bai, 2015) and local factor models. The main contribution of our methodology is to be able to estimate the dynamics of the slope coefficients (betas) for each asset and over time. By doing so, we can track the dynamic exposure of assets’ excess returns to the different financial ratios acting as pricing variables. Disclosure statement No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors. Notes on contributors Alev Atak has a PhD in Economics from Queen Mary, University of London. She works on econometrics and finance. Gabriel Montes-Rojas has a PhD in Economics from the University of Illinois at Urbana- Champaign. He especializes in econometric theory with works in quantile regression, panel data, and multivariate models. Jose Olmo has a PhD in Economics from Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. His research interests are in Financial and Applied Econometrics, and Financial Economics. Jose has also served in the editorial board of several academic journals. 28 A. ATAK ET AL. References Ando, T., & Bai, J. (2015). Asset pricing with a general multifactor structure. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 13(3), 556–604. https://doi.org/10.1093/jjfinec/nbu026 Ando, T., & Bai, J. (2020). Quantile co-movement in financial markets: A panel quantile model with unobserved heterogeneity. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 115(529), 266–279. https://doi.org/10.1080/01621459.2018.1543598 Bai, J. (2003). Inferential theory for factor models of large dimensions. Econometrica, 71(1), 135–171. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00392 Bai, J. (2009). Panel data models with interactive fixed effects. Econometrica, 77, 1229–1279. Bai, J., & Ng, S. (2002). Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models. Econometrica. Econometrica, 70(1), 191–221. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00273 Bates, B. J., Plagborg-Mø Ller, M., Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2013). Consistent factor estimation in dynamic factor models with structural instability. Journal of Econometrics, 177 (2), 289–304. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2013.04.014 Cai, Z. (2007). Trending time-varying coefficient time series models with serially correlated errors. Journal of Econometrics, 136(1), 163–188. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2005.08.004 Cai, Z., & Xiao, Z. (2012). Semiparametric quantile regression estimation in dynamic models with partially varying coefficients. Journal of Econometrics, 167(2), 413–425. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.jeconom.2011.09.025 Cai, Z., & Xu, X. (2008). Nonparametric quantile estimation for dynamic smooth coefficient models. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 103(484), 1595–1608. https://doi.org/ 10.1198/016214508000000977 Casas, I., Gao, J., Peng, B., & Xie, S. (2021). Time-varying income elasticities of healthcare expenditure for the OECD and Eurozone. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 36(3), 328–345. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.2809 Chaudhuri, P., Doksum, K., & Samarov, A. (1997). On average derivative quantile regression. Annals of Statistics, 25(2), 715–744. https://doi.org/10.1214/aos/1031833670 Chen, L., Dolado, J., & Gonzalo, J. (2021). Quantile factor models. Econometrica, 89(2), 875–910. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA15746 De Gooijer, J. G., & Zerom, D. (2003). On conditional density estimation. Statistica Neerlandica, 57(2), 159–176. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9574.00226 Eichler, M., Motta, G., & von Sachs, R. (2011). Fitting dynamic factor models to non-stationary time series. Journal of Econometrics, 163(1), 51–70. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2010.11.007 Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1), 3–56. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(93)90023-5 Fan, J., & Gijbels, I. (1996). Local polynomial modelling and its applications. Chapman & Hall. Galvao, A., Juhl, T., Montes-Rojas, G., & Olmo, J. (2018). Testing slope homogeneity in quantile regression panel data with an application to the cross-section of stock returns. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 16(2), 211–243. https://doi.org/10.1093/jjfinec/nbx016 Galvao, A., & Montes-Rojas, G. (2015). On bootstrap inference for quantile regression panel data: A Monte Carlo study. Econometrics , 3 (3), 654–666. https://doi.org/10.3390/ econometrics3030654 Galvao, A., Montes-Rojas, G., & Olmo, J. (2019). Tests of asset pricing with time-varying factor loads. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 34(5), 762–778. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.2687 Galvao, A., Parker, T., & Xiao, Z. 2021. Bootstrap inference for panel data quantile regression, https://arxiv.org/abs/2111.03626 . Giovannetti, B. C. (2013). Asset pricing under quantile utility maximization. Review of Financial Economics, 22(4), 169–179. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2013.05.008 Harding, M., & Lamarche, C. (2014). Estimating and testing a quantile regression model with interactive effects. Journal of Econometrics, 178, 101–113. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom. 2013.08.010 He, X., & Zhu, L. (2003). A lack-of-fit test for quantile regression. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 98(464), 1013–1022. https://doi.org/10.1198/016214503000000963 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 29 Horowitz, J. L., & Lee, S. (2005). Nonparametric estimation of an additive quantile regression model. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 100(472), 1238–1249. https://doi.org/10. 1198/016214505000000583 Kapetanios, G. A. (2008). Bootstrap procedure for panel datasets with many cross-sectional units. The Econometrics Journal, 11(2), 377–395. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1368-423X.2008.00243.x Kim, M. O. (2007). Quantile regression with varying coefficients. Annals of Statistics, 35(1), 92–108. https://doi.org/10.1214/009053606000000966 Koenker, R., & Bassett, G. S. (1978). Regression quantiles. Econometrica, 46(1), 33–50. https://doi. org/10.2307/1913643 Koenker, R., & Machado, J. A. F. (1999). Goodness of fit and related inference processes for quantile regression. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 94(448), 1296–1310. https:// doi.org/10.1080/01621459.1999.10473882 Koenker, R., & Xiao, Z. (2006). Quantile autoregression. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 101(475), 980–990. https://doi.org/10.1198/016214506000000672 Kogan, L., & Papanikolaou, D. (2013). Firm characteristics and stock returns: The role of investment-specific shocks. The Review of Financial Studies, 26(11), 2718–2759. https://doi. org/10.1093/rfs/hht026 Ma, S., Linton, O., & Gao, J. Estimation and inference in semiparametric quantile factor models. (2021). Journal of Econometrics, 222(1), 295–323. Part B. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom. 2020.07.003 Pagan, A. (1984). Econometric issues in the analysis of regressions with generated regressors. International Economic Review, 25(1), 221–247. https://doi.org/10.2307/2648877 Pelger, M., & Xiong, R. 2019. State-varying factor models of large dimensions. Papers 1807.02248v2, arXiv.org. 30 A. ATAK ET AL. Pesaran, M. H. (2006). Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a multifactor error structure. Econometrica, 74(4), 967–1012. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00692.x Portnoy, S. (1991). Asymptotic behavior of regression quantiles in nonstationary, dependent cases. Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 38(1), 100–113. https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-259X(91)90034-Y Song, M. 2013. Essays on large panel data analysis. Ph.D. thesis, Columbia University. Su, L., & Wang, X. (2017). On time-varying factor models: Estimation and testing. Journal of Econometrics, 198(1), 84–101. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2016.12.004 Wei, Y., & He, X. (2006). Conditional growth charts (with discussion). Annals of Statistics, 34(5), 2069–2097. https://doi.org/10.1214/009053606000000623 Yu, K., & Lu, Z. (2004). Local linear additive quantile regression. Scandinavian Journal of Statistics, 31(3), 333–346. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9469.2004.03_035.x Appendix Proof of Proposition 1. The proof of this proposition follows from an application of the results in Song (2013) and Ando and Ando and Bai (2015) to local principal components. The main difference is that we are considering local approximations using the kernels. � � ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Define Y ¼ k Y such that Y ¼ Y ; . . . ; Y is a T � 1 vector and Y ¼ it it h;ts i i1 iT � � � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Y ; . . . ; Y is a T � N matrix. Let X ¼ k X such that X ¼ X ; . . . ; X l;it 1 N l;it h;ts i 1;i d;i � � � � 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ and X ¼ X ; . . . ; X and ε ¼ k ε such that ε ¼ ε ; . . . ; ε is a T � 1 it it i i1 l;i l;i1 l;iT h;ts iT � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 vector. Similarly, e ¼ k e such that e ¼ e ; . . . ; e is a T � 1 vector. Let it it h;ts i i1 iT ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 ðsÞ F ¼ k F such that F ¼ ðF ; . . . ; F Þ is a T � R matrix and Λ ¼ ðΛ ; . . . ; Λ Þ t t s 1s Ns h;ts 1 T be a R� N matrix. For each individual in the cross section, Equation 6 in vector form is ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Y ¼ X β þ F Λ þ e ; is i i i is and the OLS estimator of β is is 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β ¼ ðX M X Þ X M Y ; (A:1) ðsÞ ðsÞ is i i i i b b F F such that 0 1 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ X M ðsÞ X X M ðsÞ h i i i i B b C b ðsÞ F F ðsÞ β β ¼ @ A F Λ þ e : is is is T T ðsÞ ðsÞ X M X ðsÞ i i Then, under assumptions A.2 and A.4, it follows that is positive definite. Now, using a similar decomposition to Proposition 1 of Song (2013), we have � � 1 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ X M F Λ ¼ L β β þ o ð1Þ; ðsÞ is p i iq;T is is T F T N q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ � � X M X ðsÞ q i 1 ðsÞ Λ Λ b 0 s F s where L ¼ a and a ¼ Λ Λ . Thus, iq iq qs iq;T T is N JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 31 " # h i � � 1 0 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b β β ¼ S L β β þ X M ðsÞ e þ o ð1Þ; is is iT iq;T is is i i NT T F q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ X M X ðsÞ i i ðsÞ with S ¼ . Then, iT T � � 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ S L ðβ β Þ ¼ X M ðsÞ e þ o ð1Þ; i i iT iT is is NT T F such that � � 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β β ¼ S L X M ðsÞ e þ o ð1Þ: is is iT iT i i NT T ðsÞ ðsÞ Now, the quantities S and L satisfy that iT iT h i p 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ S ! S ; lim k E X M X ðsÞ ðsÞ h;ts it iT ii it F H T!1 t t t¼1 and T N h i XX 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ L ! L ; lim k a E X M ðsÞ ðsÞ X ; h;ts iq it iT ii it F H T!1 t t NT NT t¼1 q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ such that L ! L as N; T ! 1. � � NT iT ii m jt sj Furthermore, note that e ¼ ε þ d þ o , with ε the errors of the mean regression it it it P it m ðqÞ m ðqÞ P P β q Λ q t s t s is is model in assumption A.1, and d ¼ X ð Þ þ F ð Þ , for any fixed s; t 2 ½T�. it it t q! T q! T q¼1 q¼1 Therefore, � � 1 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β β ¼ S L X M ðsÞ ε þ o ð1Þ; as T ! 1: (A:2) is is ii ii i i T F Now, taking the maximum over i 2 ½N� and s 2 ½T�, we obtain � � 1 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ max jjβ β jj � max jj S L jj max jj X M ðsÞ ε jj: (A:3) ii ii i i is is fi2½N�;s2½T�g fi2½N�;s2½T�g fi2½N�;s2½T�g F � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Finally, noting that max jj S L jj ¼ Oð1Þ and max jj X M ðsÞ ε jj ¼ o ð1Þ ii ii i i fi2½N�;s2½T�g fi2½N�;s2½T�g as T ! 1, the result in the proposition follows. ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ� b b b b b Proof of Proposition 2. Let Y ¼ Y X β and Y ¼ ½Y ; . . . ; Y � be i i i 1 N is ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ defined as in the text and define also Y ¼ Y X β . It follows from (14) that i i i is 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ b b b b b b ðNTÞ F Y Y ¼ F V . Note also that Y ¼ F Λ þ e X , with X ¼ NT t t t tβ tβ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b ½X ðβ β Þ; . . . ; X ðβ β Þ� a 1� N vector. 1t 1s 1s Nt Ns Ns Then, 32 A. ATAK ET AL. 1 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� 1 ðsÞ b b b b b F F H ¼ F Y Y ½V � F H t t t q q q NT NT q¼1 T h ih i ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b ¼ F F Λ þ e X F Λ þ e X ½V � F H : s s q q q t t NT t qβ qβ NT q¼1 This expression can be decomposed as T h ih i ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b ¼ F F Λ þ e F Λ þ e ½V � F H (A:4) s s q q q t t t NT NT q¼1 h i ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 b b F F Λ þ e X ½V � (A:5) q q q qβ NT NT q¼1 T h i ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b F X F Λ þ e ½V � (A:6) q qβ t t NT NT q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b þ F X X ½V � : (A:7) qβ qβ NT NT q¼1 pffiffiffiffi 1=2 Theorem 3.1 in Su and Wang (2017) shows that expression (A.4) multiplied by Nk converges h;ts ðsÞ 1 0 1 ðsÞ 1 0 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ in distribution to Nð0; V Q Γ Q V Þ, where H ¼ ðN Λ Λ ÞðT F F Þ½V � ; V is the s st s s s s s s NT 1=2 1=2 diagonal matrix consisting of the eigenvalues of � � � in descending order; Γ is the F s Λ Λ s s 1=2 1=2 0 1 corresponding normalized eigenvector matrix such that Γ Γ ¼ I , and Q ¼ V Γ � . s R s s s s Λ pffiffiffiffi s 1=2 To complete the proof we need to show that the remaining terms multiplied by Nk are h;ts ðsÞ o ð1Þ as N; T ! 1, with h ! 0. First, we show that V ! V as N; T ! 1. To do this, we P s NT ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� b b b decompose the elements of the matrix V given by Y Y for i; j ¼ 1; . . . ; N. More i j NT NT formally, 1 1 ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ b b b b Y Y ¼ ½Y X ðβ β Þ�½Y X ðβ β Þ� i j i i is is j j js js NT NT ðsÞ ðsÞ b b þ X ðβ β Þðβ β Þ X ¼ A þ A þ A þ A : 1 2 3 4 i is is js js j NT 0 0 0 1 1 1 ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� 0 ðsÞ b b ¼ Y Y X ðβ β ÞY Y ðβ β Þ X i j i is is j i js js j NT NT NT From Proposition 1, it follows that max jjβ β jj ¼ o ð1Þ, as T ! 1. Then, A ! 0, for P j it it fi2½N�;s2½T�g ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� j ¼ 2; 3; 4, as N; T ! 1, such that V ¼ V þ o ð1Þ, with V ¼ Y Y as defined in the NT NT NT i j NT ðsÞ text below Equation 14. Then, it follows that V ¼ V þ o ð1Þ. Therefore, using Assumption A.3 s P NT (ii) we have inf V > 0. Then, we need to prove that s2½T� s h i pffiffiffiffi 0 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Nk F F Λ þ e X ¼ o ð1Þ: (A:8) s P h;ts q q q qβ NT q¼1 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 33 � � m ðqÞ m ðqÞ P P jt sj β q Λ q X F it is t is Note also that e ¼ ε þ d þ o , where d ¼ ðt sÞ þ ðt sÞ , for any it it it P it T T q! T q! q¼1 q¼1 fixed s; t 2 ½T�. Then, the expression on the left hand side of (A.8) satisfies that ! ! T T X X � � � � 1 1 1 1 1=2 1=2 ðsÞ 0 ðsÞ 0 b b pffiffiffiffi F k k F Λ þ ε X þpffiffiffiffi F k k F Λ þ d X þ o ð1Þ: h;qs q s q h;qs q s q P q h;ts qβ q h;ts qβ T T N N q¼1 q¼1 (A:9) Now, noting that X ¼ o ð1Þ, for q ¼ 1; . . . ; T, and applying the law of large numbers with qβ P N; T ! 1, we obtain condition (A.8). Applying the same arguments to expressions (A.6) and (A.7), we obtain the consistency of the ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ 1 0 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ local factors to rotated versions of F given by H ¼ ðN Λ Λ ÞðT F F ÞðV Þ . t s NT Proof of Proposition 3. The proof of this proposition follows from the proof of Proposition 1 and the application of the results in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) to local principal components. For each individual in the cross section, Equation 6 in vector form is ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Y ¼ X β þ F Λ þ e ; is i i i is and the OLS estimator of β is is 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β ¼ ðX M X Þ X M Y ; (A:10) ðsÞ ðsÞ is i i i i b b F F such that 0 1 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ � � X M ðsÞ X X M ðsÞ h i pffiffiffiffiffiffi i i i pffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffi B b C b ðsÞ F F ðsÞ Th β β ¼ ThF Λ þ The : @ A is is is i T T Applying the results in the proof of Proposition 1, we have " # pffiffiffi � � h i N � � pffiffiffiffiffiffi X pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1 0 1 h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b Th β β ¼ S L Th β β þpffiffiffiffi X M ðsÞ e : i i is is iT iq;T is is q¼1 b b b We are interested in the asymptotic distribution of the entire vector β ¼ ðβ ; . . . ; β Þ . The above s 1s Ns equation implies, stacking over i " # pffiffiffi h i pffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1 h 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b Thðβ β Þ ¼ S L Thðβ β Þþpffiffiffiffi X M ðsÞ e ; s s T T s s ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ with S and L block-diagonal matrices with elements S and L . Then, T T iT iT pffiffiffi � � pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1 h 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ pffiffiffiffi S L Thðβ β Þ ¼ X M ðsÞ e ; T T s s T F such that 34 A. ATAK ET AL. pffiffiffi � � pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1 h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Thðβ β Þ ¼ S L pffiffiffiffi X M ðsÞ ε þ o ð1Þ; (A:11) s s T T � � jt sj given that e ¼ ε þ d þ o . Furthermore, from Proposition 2, we have that it it it P ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ F ¼ F H þ o ð1Þ. Then, 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðF H ÞðF H Þ ðsÞ ðsÞ H H ðsÞ ðsÞ M ðsÞ ¼ I F H ð Þ H F þ o ð1Þ ¼ I þ o ð1Þ ¼ M ðsÞ ðsÞ þ o ð1Þ T P T P P F H T T ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ F F , with H an orthogonal rotation matrix and ¼ I . Therefore, pffiffiffi pffiffiffi 0 0 h h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ pffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffi X M ðsÞ e ¼ X M ðsÞ ðsÞ ε þ o ð1Þ: i i i F H i T F T Now, using Assumption A.6, pffiffiffi h d ðsÞ ðsÞ pffiffiffiffi X M ε ! Nð0; � Þ; ðsÞ ðsÞ i F H i i h i T T P P h 0 with � ¼ lim k k E X M ðsÞ ðsÞ ε ε M ðsÞ ðsÞ X . ε h;ts h;τs it iτ iτ i it T F H F H t t τ τ T!1 t¼1 τ¼1 p p ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Furthermore, each block S and L satisfies that S ! S and L ! L . Then, stacking iT iT iT ii iT ii ðsÞ ðsÞ over all the individuals, we define S and L block-diagonal matrices, such that it follows that pffiffiffiffiffiffi Thðβ β Þ! Nð0; � Þ; s s s � � � � 1 1 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ with � ¼ S L � S L . □ β ε Proof of Proposition 4. The proof of this result follows closely the proof of Theorem 3.2 ðsÞ� 1 ðsÞ b b b in Su and Wang (2017). It follows from (15) that Λ ¼ T F Y . Then, replacing in is this expression, we obtain ðsÞ� ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ^ ^ ^ Λ ¼ T F ½Y X ðβ β Þ�: (A:12) is i i is is Operating with this expression, we obtain 0 0 ðsÞ� ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b b Λ ¼ T F Y T F X ðβ β Þ; (A:13) is i i is is 0 0 0 ðsÞ� 1 ðsÞ 1=2 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ with T F Y ¼ ½H � Λ þ T H F ε þ o ððThÞ Þ. Under assumption A.3 iii), is P i i qffiffiffi ðsÞ h ðsÞ F ε ! Nð0; Ω Þ, with is " # T T 1 T P P P h 2 0 2 2h 0 Ω ¼ lim k EðF F ε Þþ k k EðF F ε ε Þ . Then, is q h;qs h;ts q iq it h;qs q iq t T T T!1 q¼1 q¼1 t¼qþ1 rffiffiffiffi h 0 0 ðsÞ 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 H F ε ! Nð0;½Q � Ω ½Q � Þ: is s ðsÞ 1=2 1 ðsÞ b It remains to see that T F X ðβ β Þ ¼ o ððThÞ Þ as T ! 1. Using expression (A.11), i is is pffiffiffiffiffiffi and multiplying by Th, this expression can be rearranged as JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 35 pffiffiffi T T X X pffiffiffiffiffiffi h 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b b b pffiffiffiffi F X ðβ β Þ ¼ T F X Thðβ β Þ iq iq q iq iq q iq iq q¼1 q¼1 " # pffiffiffi � � T 1 0 0 1 h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ¼ T F X S L pffiffiffiffi X M ε þ o ð1Þ : ðsÞ q iq iT iT q q q¼1 Therefore, the right hand side of the expression is equal to " # pffiffiffi � � 1 T T X X 0 0 0 1 h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b S L T F X pffiffiffiffi X M ε þ T F X o ð1Þ : ðsÞ iT iT q iq q q q iq q¼1 q¼1 T T P p P 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 1 ðsÞ 0 Under assumption A.4 iv), T F X ! lim T k E½H F X � ¼ Oð1Þ. This implies h;qs iq iq q T!1 q¼1 q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 1 that T F X o ð1Þ ¼ o ð1Þ. Furthermore, S L ! S L . Now we need to show q P P iq iT iT ii ii q¼1 T pffiffi 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 h pffiffiffi that T F X X M ε ¼ o ð1Þ. To show this, from A.6, it follows that q q q ðsÞ P iq T F q¼1 � � pffiffi pffiffi ðsÞ ðsÞ h h pffiffiffi pffiffiffi X M ε ¼ z þ o , with z a zero-mean normal random variable with variance � . q ðsÞ q q P q ε T T ðsÞ ðsÞ Then, applying the law of large numbers and the law of iterated expectations to T F X z , q q iq q¼1 T T P p P ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 1 0 it follows that T F X z ! lim T k E½F X E½ε j F ; X ��. Finally, by assumption q q h;qs iq iq q iq iq q T!1 q¼1 q¼1 A.2 i), this quantity converges to zero in probability. Proof of Proposition 5. For convenience, we reproduce the analytical expression of the estimators: N N N � � X X X 0 0 � 1 b b b b b b b F ¼ Λ Λ Λ Y ¼ S Λ Y X β ; (A:14) it it it it it t it it it Λ;t N i¼1 i¼1 i¼1 1 0 b b where S ¼ N Λ Λ . Then, replacing in the expression, we obtain it i¼1 it Λ;t N N h i X X 1 1 0 1 � 1 b b b b b F ¼ S Λ Y S Λ X ðβ β Þ ;F þ F : (A:15) it it it a;t b;t t it it it b b Λ;t Λ;t N N i¼1 i¼1 The first term F has been analyzed in Su and Wang (2017) and satisfies that a;t 0 1 ðtÞ 0 1 ðtÞ 1 F H F ¼ S ½H � Λ ε þ o N : a;t it it p Λ;t N i¼1 1=2 Under assumption A3 i) S ¼ � þ OðN Þ as N ! 1, where � is an R� R diagonal Λ Λ s s Λ;t 1=2 0 matrix. Under assumption A.3 ii) it holds that N Λ ε ! Nð0; Γ Þ for each s; t, where t st pffiffiffiffi P P 0 N N 1 ðtÞ 0 Γ ¼ lim N Λ Λ E½ε ε �. Then, NðF H F Þ converges in distribution st N!1 is it jt a;t i¼1 j¼1 js t pffiffiffiffi 1 1 1 1 to Nð0; � Þ, with � ¼ ½� Q � Γ ½� Q �. Now, it remains to see that NF ! 0 as F F tt b;t t t Λ t Λ t t t N ! 0. To show this, note that 36 A. ATAK ET AL. pffiffiffiffi X b b NF ¼ S pffiffiffiffi Λ X ðβ β Þ (A:16) b;t it it it it Λ;t i¼1 � � 1 1 1 0 ðtÞ ðtÞ 1 ðtÞ ðtÞ pffiffiffiffi ¼ S Λ X S L X M ðtÞ ε þ o ð1Þ: (A:17) it it P iT iT Λ;t N T N F i¼1 0 p P 1 ðtÞ ðtÞ 0 By the law of large numbers, we have X M ðtÞ ε ! lim k E½X M ðtÞ ε �. Then, applying h;τt t t ðtÞ F H b τ T!1 τ¼1 1 ðtÞ the law of iterated expectations, under assumption A.2 (i), it follows that X M ðtÞ ε ¼ o ð1Þ as t P 1=2 T ! 1. Furthermore, noting that S ¼ � þ OðN Þ as N ! 1 and Λ;t ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ S L ! S L , we obtain the desired result. □ ii ii iT N iT Proof of Proposition 6. This proof is based on Theorem 1 of Cai and Xu (2008). The main difference is that we replace the observable covariates X by estimated common factors F such that the quantile factor model of interest is Y ¼ Z θ þ w ; (A:18) it it τ;it τ;it ðtÞ � with w ¼ ε ðF F H ÞΛ . τ;it τ;it t t τ;it Following Cai and Xu (2008), we consider a local polynomial expansion of the quantile parameters θ by θ . To simplify the proof, we consider a local linear approximation such τ;it τ;it h� �� � � �i 0 0 ð1Þ ð1Þ ð1Þ that θ ¼ a þ a ðu u Þ β þ β ðu u Þ Λ þ Λ ðu u Þ , that can be τ;it τ;is t s t s τ;is t s τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is h i � 0 reparametrized as θ ¼ ðα þ α ðu u ÞÞ η þ η ðu u Þ ð� þ �ðu u ÞÞ , and mini- τ;it 0 1 t s t s 0 1 t s 0 1 mize the following local objective function: � � T � � u u t s ρ Y Z θ k : it it τ;it h t¼1 � � � � T T P P b b u u � 1ðY δ < Y < Y þδ Þ u u 1 0 t 1 it T it it T 0 t b b Let Ω ¼ Z Z k and Ω ¼ Z Z k , for some δ ! 0 as t t T T t T 2T t e e e e h h h h t¼1 t¼1 T ! 1; 1ð�Þ is an indicator function and Y is the prediction of the quantile model evaluated at u. it These sample covariance matrices are consistent estimators of Ω and Ω defined above. e b b b Furthermore, let U ¼ ðu u Þ=h, Z ¼ ½1 X F U X U F U �, t s it t th it th t th it th e e w ¼ Y Z θ , and D ¼ diagðI ; hI Þ, with I as the identity matrix of dimen- τ;it it it τ;it 1þdþR 1þdþR 1þdþR sion 1þ dþ R, and let qffiffiffiffiffiffi ð0Þ ð1Þ ð1Þ �ð 1Þ 0 � 0 0 0 γ ¼ Th D ½α a ðη β Þ ð� Λ Þ α a ðη β Þ ð� Λ Þ�: 0 τ;is 0 1 1 it 0 τ;is τ;is τ;is 1 τ;is τ;is The above minimization problem can be rewritten as � � ρ w pffiffiffiffiffiffi Z γ k U : (A:19) τ;it h τ it it th t¼1 Th Using the same steps as in Cai and Xu (2008), we derive a local Bahadur representation of b γ such it that JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 37 � 1 T � � ½Ω � b γ ¼ pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðw ÞZ k U þ o ð1Þ τ τ;it P it it e e h th Th t¼1 with Ψ ðxÞ ¼ τ 1ðx< 0Þ. Now, after simple algebra, we decompose this expression in four terms as T � � b X ½Ω � pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε ÞZ k U (A:20) τ τ;it it e e h th Th t¼1 T � � � � b X ½Ω � � � þ pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε Þ Z Z k U (A:21) τ τ;it it it e e h th Th t¼1 � 1 � � � � ½Ω � � � þ pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðw Þ Ψ ðε Þ Z Z k U (A:22) τ τ;it τ τ;it it it e e h th Th t¼1 � 1 T � � b X ½Ω � pffiffiffiffiffiffi þ Ψ ðw Þ Ψ ðε Þ Z k U : (A:23) τ τ;it τ τ;it it e e h th Th t¼1 Under assumptions B.1-B.4, Cai and Xu (2008) show that expression (A.20) converges in dis- 1 1 � � tribution to Nð0; � Þ, with � ¼ τð1 τÞν ½Ω � Ω ½Ω � . In particular, to compute the asymp- τ τ 0 totic variance we rely on the α mixing condition B3 that limits the amount of serial dependence. More specifically, 1 h i E ðτ 1ðy � τ j Z ÞÞðτ 1ðy � τ j Z ÞÞZ Z ¼ it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼ 1 1 h i 0 2 0 τð1 τÞE½Z Z � 2τ E Z Z þ it it it i;tþs s¼1 1 h i 2 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z ÞZ Z : it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼1 The last term can be expressed as 1 1 h i h i X X 2 0 2 0 2 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ Z Z þ 2τ E Z Z : it it i;tþs i;tþs it it i;tþs i;tþs s¼1 s¼1 � � Now, noting that E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ j Z ¼ it it i;tþs i;tþs it � � E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ it it i;tþs i;tþs the above expression is 1 1 h i h i X X � �� 2 0 2 0 2 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ E Z Z þ 2τ E Z Z : it it i;tþs i;tþs it it i;tþs i;tþs s¼1 s¼1 Furthermore, applying Cauchy-Schwarz inequality to the first term, we have 38 A. ATAK ET AL. h i 2 0 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ Z Z � it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼1 1 1 h i X X � � 2 2 0 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ E Z Z : it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼1 s¼1 Finally, using the α mixing condition on fZ ; ε g in B3, we obtain it it � � E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ ! 0 it it i;tþs i;tþs s¼1 h i and E Z Z <1. Therefore, it s¼1 i;tþs 1 h i E ðτ 1ðy � τ j Z ÞÞðτ 1ðy � τ j Z ÞÞZ Z ¼ it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼ 1 1 h i 1 h i X X 0 2 0 2 0 τð1 τÞE½Z Z � 2τ E Z Z þ 2τ E Z Z ¼ τð1 τÞΩ: (A:24) it it it it i;tþs i;tþs s¼1 s¼1 The same derivations apply to Ω such that expression (A.20) converges to 1 1 � � τð1 τÞν ½Ω � Ω ½Ω � . For expression (A.21), we note that � 1 � � � � ½Ω � � � pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε Þ Z Z k U τ τ;it it it e e h th Th t¼1 � 1 h i � � ½Ω � ðtÞ ðtÞ b b ¼ pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε Þ 0 0 ðF F H Þ 0 0 ðF F H ÞU k U ; τ τ;it t t t t h e e th th Th t¼1 ðtÞ 1=2 with 0 denoting a 1� d vector. Now, using Proposition 5, F F H ¼ O N , as N ! 1. t t p pffiffiffiffi ðtÞ Define f ¼ NðF F H Þ. Then, t t t h i � � b X ½Ω � pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε Þ 0 0 f 0 0 f U k U ; pffiffiffiffi τ it t t e e e th h th N Th t¼1 that converges to zero in probability as N; T ! 1. To show this, consider the element sffiffiffiffiffiffi T � � 1 T � � b X e X ½Ω � Th½Ω � pffiffiffiffiffiffi k U Ψ ðε Þf ¼ k U Ψ ðε Þf þ o ð1Þ: τ it t τ it t P pffiffiffiffi e e e e h th h th N e Th N Th t¼1 t¼1 � � Under the law of large numbers, it follows that k U Ψ ðε Þf ¼ O ð1Þ. Then, the above τ it t P e e h th Th t¼1 Th expression converges to zero if ! 0. ðtÞ � � b b Now, the consistency of F to F H , as N ! 1, implies that Z Z ¼ o ð1Þ and t t P it it w ε ¼ o ð1Þ. Then, expressions (A.22) and (A.23) converge to zero in probability, and τ;it τ;it P the asymptotic result in Proposition 6 follows. □ http://www.deepdyve.com/assets/images/DeepDyve-Logo-lg.png Journal of Applied Economics Taylor & Francis

Functional coefficient quantile regression model with time-varying loadings

Functional coefficient quantile regression model with time-varying loadings

Abstract

This paper proposes a functional coefficient quantile regression model with heterogeneous and time-varying regression coefficients and factor loadings. Estimation of the model coefficients is done in two stages. First, we estimate the unobserved common factors from a linear factor model with exogenous covariates. Second, we plug-in an affine transformation of the estimated common factors to obtain the functional coefficient quantile regression model. The quantile parameter estimators are...
Loading next page...
 
/lp/taylor-francis/functional-coefficient-quantile-regression-model-with-time-varying-QFpEHHHXZU
Publisher
Taylor & Francis
Copyright
© 2023 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group.
ISSN
1667-6726
eISSN
1514-0326
DOI
10.1080/15140326.2023.2167151
Publisher site
See Article on Publisher Site

Abstract

JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 2023, VOL. 26, NO. 1, 2167151 https://doi.org/10.1080/15140326.2023.2167151 RESEARCH ARTICLE Functional coefficient quantile regression model with time-varying loadings a b c Alev Atak , Gabriel Montes-Rojas and Jose Olmo a b Department of Economics, Middle East Technical University, Ankara, Turkey; Universidad de Buenos Aires and CONICET, Instituto Interdisciplinario de Economía Política, Buenos Aires, Argentina; Department of Economics, University of Southampton. UK. Departamento de Analisis Economico. Universidad de Zaragoza. Spain ABSTRACT ARTICLE HISTORY Received 22 February 2022 This paper proposes a functional coefficient quantile regression Accepted 1 January 2023 model with heterogeneous and time-varying regression coeffi - cients and factor loadings. Estimation of the model coefficients is KEYWORDS done in two stages. First, we estimate the unobserved common Quantile factor model; time- factors from a linear factor model with exogenous covariates. varying factor loadings; Second, we plug-in an affine transformation of the estimated com- partially linear regression mon factors to obtain the functional coefficient quantile regression model; panel data model. The quantile parameter estimators are consistent and asymptotically normal. The application of this model to the quantile process of a cross-section of U.S. firms’ excess returns confirms the predictive ability of firm-specific covariates and the good perfor- mance of the local estimator of the heterogeneous and time- varying quantile coefficients. 1. Introduction In a series of influential papers, Bai and Ng (2002) and Bai (2003, 2009) developed a general methodology for explaining economic and financial variables by a few common factors. Factor models allow for a drastic reduction of the cross-sectional dimension of a panel while providing a flexible way to summarize information from large data sets, see Pesaran (2006). In the literature on factor models it is common to assume a vector of constant factor loadings. This assumption is, however, rather restrictive. To the best of our knowledge, Eichler et al. (2011) is the first study to use time-varying loadings in a dynamic model with non-stationary time series. Bates et al. (2013) is another influential analysis that contributes to the idea of smooth changes in factor loadings. Su and Wang (2017) propose a local version of the principal component method using smoothly changing loadings, while Pelger and Xiong (2019) allow them to be state-dependent. In this setting the unobserved factor structure is thus allowed to vary over time. Another area of major interest in recent years is the study of the quantile process. Quantile regression (QR) has been studied extensively in both theoretical and empirical studies; see Koenker and Bassett (1978), Portnoy (1991), Chaudhuri et al. (1997), CONTACT Gabriel Montes-Rojas gabriel.montes@fce.uba.ar Universidad de Buenos Aires and CONICET, Instituto Interdisciplinario de Economía Política, Buenos Aires, Argentina © 2023 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group. This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/ licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. 2 A. ATAK ET AL. Koenker and Machado (1999), He and Zhu (2003), Koenker and Xiao (2006). This work has been recently extended to accommodate the presence of dynamics in the quantile coefficients, see Wei and He (2006) and Kim (2007). A more general approach that also allows for dynamics in the quantile parameters is based on nonparametric and semipara- metric estimation methods for dynamic smooth coefficient models, see De Gooijer and Zerom (2003), Yu and Lu (2004), Horowitz and Lee (2005), and more recently, Cai and Xu (2008) and Cai and Xiao (2012). Building on this work, recent contributions by Ando and Bai (2020), Chen et al. (2021) and Ma et al. (2021) have extended quantile regression models to incorporate unobserved common factors. These models consider heteroge- neous quantile effects that introduce much flexibility to the specification of factor models by capturing the presence of heterogeneity in the effect of observable covariates and unobserved factors at different quantiles. The current paper combines both approaches by considering a factor model with a time-varying factor loadings structure in a quantile heterogeneity framework with varying coefficients. The idea is to propose a flexible panel data model that is general enough to encompass unobserved heterogeneity arising from unobserved factors and quantile-indexed responses together in a dynamic setting. This is done in two stages. First, we propose a factor model for the mean process that includes observable regressors and unobservable factors. This model allows for heterogeneity across individuals and dynamics in the regression coefficients. By doing so, we extend standard factor model specifications that assume slope homogeneity in the observable regressors as in Bai (2003, 2009) and slope heterogeneity as in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015). As a salient feature, the model also entertains dynamics in the factor loadings. Second, we extend the model to describe the quantile process. The slope coefficients associated with the observable regressors in the quantile model face three different types of variation: heterogeneity across quantiles, individuals, and over time. The factor loadings accom- modate heterogeneity across individuals and over time. Estimation of the model coeffi- cients (quantile factors, quantile regression coefficients and factor loadings) is done in two stages. In the first stage, we estimate the unobservable common factors from a linear factor model with exogenous covariates. We adapt the principal component analysis introduced in Bai (2009) to a local setting using kernel estimation methods (see also Su and Wang (2017)) to simultaneously estimate the local common factors, factor loadings and slope coefficients associated with the observable regressors. In contrast to Su and Wang (2017), our model also accommodates the presence of observable regressors. In order to estimate the quantile common factors a fundamental assumption in our modelling framework is that these quantities are quantile-specific affine transformations of the factors obtained from the mean process in the first stage. In this regard, our model specification lies between the approximate factor models that only consider mean- shifting factors to describe quantile effects and the idiosyncratic quantile factor models in which the factors are estimated separately for each quantile using an iterative proce- dure, see Ando and Bai (2020), Chen et al. (2021) and Ma et al. (2021). By doing so, our quantile factors become observable covariates in the quantile process studied in the second stage. The estimation of the parameters in our model relies on the nonparametric quantile estimation method for dynamic smooth coefficients introduced in Cai and Xu (2008) and the semiparametric approach proposed in Cai and Xiao (2012) for models with partially JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 3 varying coefficients. Our proposed methodology is also framed within the recent litera- ture on QR models with an unobserved factor structure. Harding and Lamarche (2014) propose a quantile common correlated effects estimator for homogeneous panel data with endogenous regressors. The authors assume a parametric approach and time- invariant factor loadings, where the way of recovering the latent factors is different from ours. Inclusion of estimated quantities in regression models may affect the asymptotic distribution of the parameter estimates, see Pagan (1984). This observation is essential in our context, characterized by a quantile factor model with estimated factors. In principle, the inclusion of such covariates into the quantile model has effects on the asymptotic distribution of the quantile parameter estimates. We show that this is not the case under standard panel data assumptions, that is, if both N and T diverge to infinity pffiffiffiffi such that Th= N ! 1, with h ! 0 a bandwidth parameter. We derive the asymptotic distribution of the regression parameter estimates associated to the observable covariates for the mean and quantile models, and of the estimated factors and quantile factor loadings. A Monte Carlo simulation exercise studies the finite-sample performance (bias and mean square error) of two estimators of the slope coefficients that are based on our two- stage procedure. The first estimator considers time-varying factor loadings using the local estimation procedure developed in this paper. In this case we estimate individual- specific coefficients for all t ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; T. The second estimator considers a model with time-invariant loadings. In this case we do not impose the time-varying local estimation procedure and estimate, instead, a unique set of parameters for all t. This global factor estimator uses Ando and Bai (2015) iterative process. The simulation exercise confirms the consistency of our local two-stage estimation procedure and provides empirical support to our methodology for estimating heterogeneous and time-varying quantile regression coefficients and factor loadings. This novel quantile factor model is applied to explain the distributional risk premia for a cross-section of excess returns. To do this, we fit the model to different quantiles of the distribution for a cross-section of annual U.S. firms’ asset returns. We consider firm- specific covariates as pricing factors and allow for the presence of two unobserved factors. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the time- varying quantile factor model. Section 3 describes the estimation procedure based on local principal components and QR. Section 4 introduces the asymptotic properties of the parameter estimators. Section 5 presents a Monte Carlo simulation exercise to evaluate the performance in finite samples of our estimation procedure, in particular, we focus on bias and mean square error. Section 6 illustrates the suitability of the quantile factor model with exogenous covariates in an empirical asset pricing framework. Section 7 provides concluding remarks. An Appendix contains the mathematical proofs of the main results of the study. Tables and figures are collected as a second Appendix. It is prevalent in this literature to fix the number of unobserved common factors, see Bai (2009), Song (2013), and Ando and Bai (2015). Alternatively, information criteria and rank minimization are used in Ando and Bai (2020) and Chen et al. (2021), to determine the number of factors at each quantile while uncovering the quantile factors individually. 4 A. ATAK ET AL. Notation. Let ½T�;f1; 2; . . . ; Tg and ½N� ¼ f1; 2; . . . ; Ng be the sets of time periods and individual indices, respectively. The Frobenius norm is defined as k A k¼ 1=2 0 0 ½trðAAÞ� with tr denoting the trace of a matrix and A the transpose of A. 2. Time-varying quantile factor models 2.1. Identification of the quantile factors and factor loadings Let Y be an outcome variable of interest and X ¼ X ; . . . ; X be a vector of d it it 1;it d;it observable covariates, including a constant. Similarly, F ¼ ðF ; . . . ; F Þ is the vector τt τ;t1 τ;tR of unobservable common quantile factors indexed by τ where, for simplicity, R is assumed to be equal across τ 2 ð0; 1Þ. We consider the following quantile process conditional on X and F , given by it τt Q ðY jX ; F Þ ¼ X β þ F Λ ; (1) τ it it τt it τt τ;it τ;it for a given τ 2 ð0; 1Þ, where β ¼ β ðu Þ, with u ¼ t=T , is the vector of quantile slope t t τ;it τ;i coefficients associated to the observable regressors. Similarly, Λ ¼ ðλ ; . . . ; λ Þ , τ;it τ1;it τR;it with λ ¼ λ ðu Þ, are the loadings associated to the quantile factors F . Here the τj;it τj;i t τt factors are assumed to be τ-specific. Both β and Λ are assumed continuously τ;it τ;it differentiable smooth functions, see Cai (2007) for similar assumptions in a model with observable covariates. We impose the following assumption for the identification of the quantile factors. Assumption A.1 iÞ The conditional mean model satisfies EðY jX ; F Þ ¼ X β þ F Λ ; (2) it it t it t it it with β the slope coefficients for the conditional mean process; F ¼ ðF ; . . . ; F Þ the t t1 tR it vector of common factors affecting the conditional mean, and Λ the associated factor it loadings. iiÞ The quantile common factors satisfy F ¼ F þ s ; (3) τt t τt with s ¼ ½s ; . . . ; s � for all t 2 ½T�. τt τ;1t τ;Rt Assumption A.1 ii) implies that the quantile factors are location shifts of the vector of factors for the mean process. Under A.1, we can identify the quantile factors and the quantile factor loadings from the following quantile regression model: Q ðY jX ; F Þ ¼ a þ X β þ F Λ ; (4) τ it it t τ;it it t τ;it τ;it with a ¼ s Λ . Identification of the quantile parameters is possible if we condition τ;it τt τ;it on the vector X and F . The additional component a determines that the constant in it t τ;it (1) cannot be identified unless additional assumptions are imposed. In particular, identification of s is possible if there is no constant in the quantile regression models τ;tr JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 5 indexed by τ 2 ð0; 1Þ. Alternatively, we may impose Q ðs j F Þ ¼ 0 in assumption A.1. τ τt t This additional constraint allows for the identification of the constant in model (4) from the parameter vector β . Note however that this is not required for the estimation of the τ;it other parameters which is the main interest of the paper. The next section discusses a suitable estimation strategy for obtaining consistent � � estimates of the model parameters. The parameters of interest are β ; Λ ; F for the it t it n o mean regression equation in A.1, and β ; Λ ; F for the QR model (4). τ;it τt τ;it 2.2. Estimation In this section we consider local versions of principal components analysis to devise an iterative procedure for estimating the model parameters of the mean process (2). To do this, we adopt the estimation procedures in Bai (2009), Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) for the estimation of β , Λ and F . The parameters β and Λ of the quantile it t τ;it it τ;it factor model with observable regressors are estimated using QR methods applied to a local kernel version of model (18) in which the unknown common factors have been replaced by consistent estimates. 2.2.1. Estimation of slope coefficients and common factors In order to estimate the parameters of model (2), we apply local principal components as in Su and Wang (2017). In contrast to these authors we consider a factor model that also includes observable regressors. In order to estimate the slope coefficients β and Λ we need a panel data structure it it with large N and T that guarantee the consistency of the common factors and factor loadings, respectively. To do this, we extend the iterative estimation procedure in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) to accommodate dynamics in the β and Λ coefficients, until we reach convergence. For s 2 ½T� fixed, we consider the Taylor expansion of the vector β about β for u close to u such that t s it is ðqÞ q m is β ¼ β þ ðu u Þ þ oðju u j Þ; (5) t s t s it is q! q¼1 ðqÞ with β high-order derivatives of the functional parameter β evaluated at u . For is it simplicity, we consider the local approximation of order zero given by β such that the is remaining terms in the approximation are in the error term. Similarly, we replace Λ by it Λ such that we estimate the model is Y ¼ X β þ F Λ þ e ; (6) it it t is it is with e an error term that includes the high-order approximation terms of the model it parameters. The parameters of model (6) are estimated from minimizing the following local weighted least squares problem: N T � � XX u u 2 t s min Y X β F Λ k ; (7) it it t is � � is N T h β ;fΛ g ;fF g f g is t i¼1 t¼1 is i¼1 t¼1 i¼1 6 A. ATAK ET AL. where kð�Þ is a kernel smoothing function. The solution to this problem can be obtained applying local principal component analysis (LPCA). To do this, we multiply both sides 1=2 u u t s of expression (6) by k , with k ¼ k , see Su and Wang (2017) for a similar h;ts h;ts h estimation strategy. We obtain 1=2 1=2 1=2 1=2 k Y ¼ k X β þ k F Λ þ k e : (8) it it t is it is h;ts h;ts h;ts h;ts � � ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Now, define Y ¼ k Y such that Y ¼ Y ; . . . ; Y is a T � 1 vector and Y ¼ it it i i1 iT h;ts � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 Y ; . . . ; Y is a T � N matrix. Similarly, let X ¼ k X such that l;it 1 N l;it h;ts � � � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ X ¼ X ; . . . ; X , for l ¼ 1; . . . ; d, with X ¼ X ; . . . ; X . Similarly, e ¼ i 1;i it l;i l;i1 l;iT d;i � � 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ k e such that e ¼ e ; . . . ; e is a T � 1 vector. Let F ¼ k F such that F ¼ it t t h;ts i i1 iT h;ts ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 ðF ; . . . ; F Þ is a T � R matrix and Λ ¼ ðΛ ; . . . ; Λ Þ be a R� N matrix. For each s 1s Ns 1 T individual in the cross section, Equation 8 in vector form is ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Y ¼ X β þ F Λ þ e : (9) is i i is i In this setting, for a fixed s 2 ½T�, the minimization problem (7) becomes " # � �� � ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ min tr Y F Λ Y F Λ ; (10) is is i i ðsÞ fβ ;F ;Λ g is is i¼1 ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ with tr denoting the trace of the matrix and Y ¼ Y X β . For parameter identi- i i i is ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 fication, we impose restrictions F F =T ¼ I and Λ Λ ¼ diagonal matrix, with Λ ¼ R s s ðΛ ; . . . ; Λ Þ a R� N matrix. This objective function is a locally weighted version of the 1s Ns least square estimator in Bai (2009). ðsÞ Applying the procedure developed by these authors, we can estimate β and F using is an iterative estimation procedure. This approach decomposes the original estimation problem into two steps: the estimation of the individual coefficients given common factors, and the estimation of the common factors given individual coefficients. We maintain their assumption that the number of factors R is known. The extension to an unknown number of factors under heterogeneous regression coefficients is cumbersome and beyond the scope of this paper. Thus when the number of unobserved factors is known, Bai (2009) proposes a tractable solution to the estimation problem by concen- trating out the factor loadings from the objective function (10). Following this procedure, we assume that the factor loadings Λ satisfy a relationship of the form is 0 0 1 ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b ^ b Λ ¼ ðF F Þ F Y , with Y ¼ Y X β and β an estimate of the vector is i i i i is is of slope coefficients for fixed s 2 ½T�. Then, replacing this expression into (10), the objective function is ( " ! #) N N X X 0 0 0 ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ b b min Y Y tr F Y Y F : (11) i i i i ðsÞ fβ ;F ;Λ g T is is i¼1 i¼1 Therefore, the problem of interest becomes JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 7 " ! # ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ b b max tr F Y Y F : (12) i i ðsÞ fβ ;F g is i¼1 ðsÞ The estimators fβ ; F g should simultaneously solve a system of nonlinear equations is 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β ¼ ðX M ðsÞ X Þ X M ðsÞ Y (13) is i i i i b b F F � � ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ b b b b with M ðsÞ ¼ I F F F F , and " # ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b b b Y Y F ¼ F V ; (14) i i NT NT i¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� b b where V is a diagonal matrix with the R largest eigenvalues of ðNTÞ Y Y , and NT pffiffiffiffi ðsÞ the estimated transformed factors F are interpreted as the T times eigenvectors ðsÞ� ðsÞ� b b corresponding to the R largest eigenvalues of the T � T matrix Y Y , arranged in descending order. The actual estimation procedure can be implemented by iterating each of the two steps in (13) and (14) until convergence. The unknown factor loadings are obtained as 1 0 ðsÞ� ðsÞ b b b Λ ¼ F Y : (15) is The estimation above involves only local data points, i.e., locally weighted in a neighbourhood of s 2 f1; . . . ; Tg, and hence, the local estimates of β and Λ converge is is pffiffiffiffiffiffi to the true parameters at Th rate. In contrast, the methodology developed in Ando and pffiffiffiffi Bai (2015) obtains global estimators that converge under slope heterogeneity at T for each i ¼ 1; . . . ; N . Under the assumption of slope homogeneity, Bai (2009) obtains pffiffiffiffiffiffiffi estimators of the true slope parameters that converge at NT. The next step is to derive a consistent estimator of the common factors F . We propose an estimator of the common factors from the minimization of the following least squares problem: N T � � XX b b min Y F Λ ; (16) t it it ffF g g t¼1 i¼1 t¼1 b b b with Y ¼ Y X β , where β is obtained from the above iterative estimation proce- it it it it it dure for each s 2 ½T�. The solution to this problem is N N X X 0 0 � b b b b b F ¼ Λ Λ Λ Y : (17) it it t it it i¼1 i¼1 2.2.2. Estimation of time-varying quantile factor loadings In what follows, we propose a procedure to estimate the parameters of the quantile process (18). The unobserved quantile common factors are replaced by estimates of F obtained from the conditional mean regression model, such that the regression of interest is 8 A. ATAK ET AL. Q ðY jX ; F Þ � a þ X β þ F Λ ; (18) τ it it t τ;it it t τ;it τ;it ðtÞ ðtÞ with Λ ¼ ½H � Λ and H a rotation matrix characterizing the common factors; τ;it τ;it � � � ðtÞ a ¼ s Λ , with s ¼ s H . More compactly, consider the following regression τ;it τt τt τ;it τt model. Let Y ¼ Z θ þ w ; (19) it it τ;it τ;it be the feasible counterpart of Y ¼ Z θ þ ε , with Q ε jX ; F ¼ 0. Here we are it it τ;it τ;it τ τ;it it t using the notation Z ¼ ½X F � (note that X already contains a constant) and it it t ðtÞ � b b Z ¼ ½X F �, and also w ¼ ε ðF F H ÞΛ . it it t τ;it τ;it t t τ;it Estimation of the model parameters follows by adapting the nonparametric approach for dynamic quantile processes in Cai and Xu (2008). These authors consider a polynomial approximation of the parameters θ ;θ ðu Þ about u given by θ and defined as τ;it τ;i t s τ;is " ! ! ! # 0 0 q q q X X X ðjÞ j ðjÞ j �ð jÞ j θ ¼ a þ a ðu u Þ β þ β ðu u Þ Λ þ Λ ðu u Þ ; τ;is τ;is t s t s t s τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is j¼1 j¼1 j¼1 ð� jÞ j � � with Λ þ Λ ðu u Þ the local approximation of the rotated factor loadings Λ . t s τ;is τ;is τ;it j¼1 ðjÞ ðjÞ �ð jÞ Note that a , β and Λ are the derivatives of order j of the respective functional τ;is τ;is τ;is coefficients. As in Cai and Xu (2008) we disregard in the following derivations the approximation error from using a polynomial Taylor expansion of order q, see Fan and Gijbels (1996) for the suitability of this method and, in particular, the advantages of the local linear approximation. The parameters of model (19) can be estimated from the following local objective function: � � � � 1 u u t s min ρ Y Z θ k ; (20) it it τ;is fθ g T τ;is h t¼1 where ρ ð�Þ ¼ �½τ 1ð�< 0Þ� is the check function of Koenker and Bassett (1978) and 1ð�Þ is an indicator function that takes a value of one if the argument is true and zero otherwise; h is a suitable bandwidth parameter for the quantile estimation problem. Estimation of the quantile parameters is obtained from the first-order conditions of the optimization problem (20). Estimation of the common factors for the quantile process is also possible in a quantile model (1) without intercept. In this case, by invoking Assumption A.1, we plug-in the factors estimated from the mean regression in Equation 6 and estimate the quantile factors as b b F ¼ F þb s ; (21) τt t τt 1 1 � � � b b b b b with s ¼ a ½Λ � , where a is obtained from (20) and ½Λ � is a N � R generalized τt τt τt τ;t τ;t inverse matrix of the R� N matrix Λ obtained from the elements τ;t JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 9 �ð jÞ j � � Λ � Λ þ Λ ðu u Þ , with � denoting a Taylor approximation of order q. t s τ;it τ;is τ;is j¼1 1 1 � � � b b b The matrix ½Λ � satisfies that Λ ½Λ � ¼ I . τ;t τ;t τ;t 2.3. Determining the number of factors In the previous analysis, we assume that the number of factors, R, is known. In the simulations and the empirical application we fix the number of factors to R ¼ 2, follow- ing the framework in Galvao et al. (2018) and Galvao et al. (2019). In practice, however, it is an important question to determine R from the data. Different information criteria type models have been applied to select the number of factors, although not for our specific panel data model, with N and T dimensions, that combines both mean- and quantile-based model specifications. The former determines the type of objective function that will be used in the information criterion. The latter determines how the penalty factor is constructed as a function of N , T and R. Following Su and Wang (2017) or in Casas et al. (2021) AIC or BIC can be applied to the mean- based factor model, where we can use the objective value function that is minimized to obtain the parameters, including the factors and the factor loadings. Ando and Bai (2020) propose a model for selecting the number of factors where the check objective function from QR is used in an AIC or BIC framework, and it also combines both dimensions in the criteria. 3. Asymptotic properties of the estimators This section presents the asymptotic properties of the proposed estimators for the model parameters – including the common factors – for processes (6) and (19). There are three unique features of the current problem that pose challenges to the econometric theory. First, the proposed estimators of the common factors and beta coefficients do not have a closed-form expression. These quantities are obtained by solving a set of equations to be ðsÞ satisfied simultaneously by β and F . Second, the unobserved common factors are it treated as parameters to be estimated, and thus the number of parameters grows with T. Finally, each pair ði; tÞ, with i 2 ½N� and t 2 ½T�, has its own slope coefficient β and it factor loading Λ such that the number of parameters grows with N and T. it Our goal in the remaining of the section is to derive the asymptotic distribution of the quantile parameter estimates of model (19). Our results build on the nonparametric quantile estimation methodology for dynamic smooth coefficient models introduced in Cai and Xu (2008). Our model is also closely related to the recent contribution of Ando and Bai (2020). The salient feature of our model compared to Ando and Bai (2020) is that the quantile common factors are treated as estimated regressors that are obtained from the mean model (2). 3.1. Assumptions We first state the following notations and assumptions. Let ε ¼ ðε ; . . . ; ε Þ be the error t 1t Nt 1 0 of the mean regression model in Assumption A.1. Then, we denote γ ðs; tÞ ¼ N E½ε ε �, N s 10 A. ATAK ET AL. 1 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 γ ðs; tÞ ¼ N E½F ε ε �, γ ðs; tÞ ¼ N E½F ε � ε F �, and � ¼ N ½ε ε E½ε ε ��. t t t st t t s s s s s s N;F N;FF P P P P 1=2 1=2 N T T N h 0 0 h pffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffi Define ω ðsÞ ¼ k F ε Λ , and ω ðr; sÞ ¼ NT;1 h;ts it NT;2 i¼1 t¼1 t is t¼1 i¼1 NT NT 0 0 k F ε ε E½F ε ε � . Let C<1 denote a positive constant that may vary from case h;ts it is it is t t to case. Assumption A.2. (Error terms and common factors). The error terms and common factors satisfy (i) E½ε jX ; F � ¼ 0 and E½jε j �<1 for all i and t in ½T�; it it t i;t 8 0 (ii) max E k F k <1 and E½F F � ¼ � > 0 for some R� R matrix � . 1� t� T t t F F (iii) max jCovðF F ; F F Þj � C for m; n ¼ 1; . . . ; R, where F 1� t� T t;m t;n s;m s;n t;m s¼1 th denotes the m element of F . P P T T (iv) max k γðs; tÞ k� C and max k γðs; tÞ k� C for γ ¼ 1� t� T 1� s� T s¼1 t¼1 γ ; γ and γ . N N;F N;FF 1=2 1=2 0 4 (v) max EjN � j � C and max E k N Λ ε k � C. 1� s;t� T st 1� s;t� T s (vi) ω ðrÞ ¼ O ð1Þ and max E k ω ðr; sÞk � C for each r. NT;1 P s NT;2 Assumption A.3. (Factor Loadings). The factor loading matrix Λ satisfies that is 1 0 1=2 (i) N Λ Λ ¼ � þ OðN Þ as N ! 1, where � is an R� R diagonal matrix. s Λ Λ s s s 1=2 1=2 (ii) V is the diagonal matrix consisting of the eigenvalues of � � � and satisfies s F Λ Λ s s that inf v > 0 for all diagonal elements ðv ; . . . ; v Þ. s2½T� rs 1s Rs 1=2 0 (iii) N Λ ε ! Nð0; Γ Þ for each s; t, where t st P P N N 1 0 Γ ¼ lim N Λ Λ E½ε ε �. st N!1 is it jt i¼1 j¼1 js pffiffi pffiffi P P ðsÞ ðsÞ T T h h 0 pffiffiffi pffiffiffi (iv) F ε ¼ k F ε ! Nð0; Ω Þ, where h;ts it is t¼1 it t¼1 t T T � � X X X h T 2h T 1 T 2 0 2 0 Ω ¼ lim k E½F F ε �þ k k E½F F ε ε � : ~ ~ ~ is T!1 t h;ts h;ts t it it h;ts t it t t¼1 t¼1 t¼tþ1 T T Assumption A.4. (Explanatory Variables). The vector of observable covariates satisfies ðsÞ (i) E k X k < C: it ðsÞ ðsÞ (ii) The d� d matrix X M ðsÞ ðsÞ X is positive definite. i F H i 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 0 1 1 pffiffiffi (iii) Let A ¼ X M ðsÞ X , B ¼ ðΛ Λ Þ� I , C ¼ Λ � ðX M ðsÞÞ. For is T i i F i i i i F T is is ðsÞ ðsÞ each s 2 ½T�, let A be the collection of F such that ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ A ¼ fF : F F =T ¼ I g. Then, we assume that ðsÞ inf DðF Þ is positive definite; ðsÞ ðsÞ F 2A ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ with DðF Þ ¼ DðF Þ, where DðF Þ ¼ B C A C and A is i i i i i i i i¼1 ðsÞ the generalized inverse of A . i JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 11 1 ðsÞ 0 ðsÞ (iv) lim T k E½H F X � ¼ Oð1Þ, for s ¼ 1; . . . ; T. (H is a rotation matrix h;qs iq T!1 q¼1 characterizing the factors defined above.) Assumption A.5. (i) The kernel function k : R ! R is a symmetric continuously differentiable probability density function with compact support ½ 1; 1�, (ii) As 2 2 1=2 ðN; TÞ ! 1, h ! 0, Th ! 1, Nh ! 1, Th=N ! 0, and Th=N ! 1. Assumption A.6. (Central Limit). As T ! 1, h ! 0, and Th ! 1; pffiffiffi ðsÞ ðsÞ pffiffiffiffi X M ε ! Nð0; � Þ; ðsÞ ðsÞ i F H i i h i T T P P h 0 with � ¼ lim k k E X M ε ε M X . ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ε h;ts h;τs it iτ iτ i it T F H F H τ τ T!1 t t t¼1 τ¼1 These assumptions are standard in factor models. A.2 and A.3 mainly impose moment conditions in the error terms, factors, factor loadings, and their interactions, see, e.g., Bai and Ng (2002), Bai (2003, 2009). The main difference, and in line with Su and Wang 0 1 0 1=2 (2017), is that we require E½F F � ¼ � in A.2(ii) and N Λ Λ ¼ � þ OðN Þ in t F s Λ t s s A.3(i). Assumptions A.2(iii)-(v) restrict the time and cross-sectional dependence for the idiosyncratic errors ε and the weak dependence between factors and errors, which are in it the same spirit as Bai (2003, 2009) and Su and Wang (2017). A.2(vi) is a kernel-weighted version of Assumptions F.1-F.2 in Bai (2003). Following the recent literature on factor models, we assume that E½F F � is homogeneous over t. This assumption is made for convenience to facilitate the asymptotic results. Assumption A.3(iii) allows for factor loadings to be time-varying and Assumption A.3(iv) is a kernel weighted version of Assumption F in Bai (2003). Both parts are used to establish the asymptotic normality of our local principal components estimators. We extend the assumptions in Su and Wang (2017) by incorporating a set of assumptions in A.4 specific to the observable regressors. Assumption A.4 (i)-(iii) impose the boundedness of moments and the regressors are assumed to exhibit sufficient variation such that the coefficients β are identifiable. it Identification also requires that the observed regressors do not exhibit multicollinearity with the unobservable common factors F . Condition (iii) in the assumption guarantees the unique minimizer of the estimation objective function. The notation DðFÞ is used to emphasize that the entire term is a function of F. Assumption A.5 states conditions on the rates of convergence that guarantee the consistency and asymptotic normality of the kernel estimators. A.6 simplifies the proofs and is imposed, for example, in Ando and Bai (2015). More primitive conditions to obtain the asymptotic properties of these objects can be found in Song (2013) for a global factor model. We consider now each cross-sectional observation separately, such that Z denotes Z t it for each i ¼ 1; . . . ; N . Let f ð�j�Þ be the conditional density of Y given Z . Let Ω ¼ yjZ it it ð ð 0 � 0 j j 2 E½Z Z � and Ω ¼ E½Z Z f ðQ ðτjZ ÞÞ�, and define μ ¼ u KðuÞdu and ν ¼ u K ðuÞdu. t t yjz y t j t t j The relevant bandwidth parameter for the quantile problem is h such � � � � u u 1 u u t s t s that k ¼ K . h e e e h h h 12 A. ATAK ET AL. Assumption B.1. β , Λ , β and Λ are ðmþ 1Þ th order continuously differenti- ir τ;ir ir τ;ir able in a neighbourhood of u for any u ¼ r=T . Further, f ðyÞ is bounded and satisfies r r yjz the Lipschitz condition. 2ð2þδÞ Assumption B.2. For each i ¼ 1; . . . ; N , E½jjZ jj �<1 for some δ> 0, where it Z ¼ fX ; F g. Furthermore, Ω and Ω are positive definite and continuous in it it t a neighbourhood of u . These functions and their inverse functions are uniformly bounded. Assumption B.3. For each i ¼ 1; . . . ; N , the process fX ; F ; ε g is strictly stationary it t it α mixing, with mixing coefficients δ ðsÞ satisfying max δ ðsÞ � CδðsÞ such that i 1� i� N i δðsÞ ¼ Oðs Þ with �¼ ð2þ δÞð1þ δÞ=δ. Th e e e Assumption B.4. The bandwidth parameter h satisfies h ! 0, Th ! 1, ! 0, and 1=2 δ=4 δ=δ 1=2 δ=4 T h ¼ Oð1Þ, for δ > δ. This set of assumptions is found in Cai (2007) and Cai and Xu (2008). The main difference with respect to the latter authors is the assumption ðThÞ=N ! 0 that allows us to remove the effect of estimating the common factors F from the asymptotic distribu- tion of the quantile parameter estimates. A similar assumption is also found in A.4 for the mean process. Under this set of additional assumptions, we obtain the asymptotic distribution of the quantile parameter estimates of β and Λ , for i 2 ½N� and τ;it τ;it t 2 ½T�. This result shows that the estimation of the common factors F does not have an effect on the asymptotic distribution of the quantile parameter estimates. 3.2. Propositions With these assumptions in place we are ready to derive the asymptotic results. We derive first the uniform consistency of the parameter estimators associated to the observable regressors. Proposition 1. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, it follows that max jjβ β jj ¼ o ð1Þ; as N; T ! 1: (22) it it fi2½N�;s2½T�g The proof of this result, in the Appendix, follows from extending the results in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) to the presence of time-varying slope coefficients. The uniform consistency of these coefficients allows us to extend the results in Su and Wang (2017) from a pure factor model specification to our setting. The following result shows ðsÞ ðsÞ the asymptotic normality of F to a rotation of the true factors F . t t JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 13 Proposition 2. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, for each s; t ¼ 1; . . . ; T, we have � � pffiffiffiffi 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 0 1 N k F F H ! Nð0; V Q Γ Q V Þ; asN ! 1; (23) s st t t h;ts s s s ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 0 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ where H ¼ ðN Λ Λ ÞðT F F Þ½V � ; V denotes the R� R diagonal matrix of s NT NT ðsÞ� ðsÞ� the first R largest eigenvalues of ðNTÞ Y Y , V is the diagonal matrix consisting of 1=2 1=2 the eigenvalues of � � � in descending order; Γ is the corresponding normalized F s Λ Λ s s 1=2 1=2 0 1 eigenvector matrix such that Γ Γ ¼ I , and Q ¼ V Γ � . s R s s s s Λ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ In particular, the consistency of the local factors F to F H allows us to derive the t t asymptotic distribution of the slope parameter estimators associated to the observable regressors. Proposition 3. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, for any fixed pair ði; tÞ with i ¼ 1; . . . ; N and t ¼ 1; . . . ; T, the vector β obtained from expression (13) satisfies it pffiffiffiffiffiffi Thðβ β Þ! Nð0; � Þ; (24) it it it � � � � 0 1 0 1 ðtÞ ðtÞ ðtÞ ðtÞ with � ¼ S L � S L , where S and L are matrices defined in ε ii ii ii ii i ii ii it the Appendix. The proof of this result follows from extending the results in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) to the presence of time-varying slope coefficients. Similarly, we show that the asymptotic distribution of the factor loading estimates is unaffected by including a set of observable covariates X with time-varying parameters β that vary smoothly over it it time. More formally, Proposition 4. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, for each s; t ¼ 1; . . . ; T, we have pffiffiffiffiffiffi ðsÞ 1 0 1 1 ThðΛ ½H � Λ Þ! Nð0;½Q � Ω ½Q � Þ; (25) is is is s " # T T 1 T P P P h 2 0 2 2h 0 with Ω ¼ lim k EðF F ε Þþ k k EðF F ε ε Þ . is q h;qs h;ts q iq it q iq t T h;qs T T!1 q¼1 q¼1 t¼qþ1 pffiffiffiffi These results allow us to show the N consistency of the common factors estimated in (17). Proposition 5. Under Assumptions A.2-A.6 and B.1, as N ! 1; the estimator (17) of the common factors satisfies � � pffiffiffiffi ðtÞ N F F H ! Nð0; � Þ; (26) t t F N N PP 1 1 1 1 1 0 with � ¼ ½� Q � Γ � Q , where Γ ¼ lim Λ Λ E½ε ε �. F tt tt it it jt t Λ t Λ t jt t t N N!1 i¼1 j¼1 14 A. ATAK ET AL. Proposition 6. Under Assumptions A.1-A.6 and B.1-B.4, as N; T ! 1; the estimator 0 0 0 0 0 0 � � b b b θ ¼ ½a β Λ � of θ ¼ ½a β Λ � obtained from the minimization problem τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is (20) satisfies that qffiffiffiffiffiffi ðqþ1Þ h qþ1 ðqþ1Þ e b e Th θ θ θ þ o ðh Þ ! Nð0; � Þ; (27) τ;is τ;is P τ is ðqþ 1Þ! h � � � �i 0 0 ðqþ1Þ ðqþ1Þ ðqþ1Þ �ð qþ1Þ with θ ¼ a μ β μ Λ μ and is τ;is qþ1 τ;is qþ1 τ;is qþ1 � 1 � 1 � ¼ τð1 τÞν ½Ω � Ω ½Ω � : τ 0 This result shows that the bias of the estimator of the quantile parameters decreases as one takes higher order local polynomial expansions of the functional coefficients in (19). Inference for this model is based on bootstrap implementation for panel data models with time-dependent data. Standard errors are estimated using bootstrap by resampling only from cross-sectional units with replacement as in Kapetanios (2008) and Galvao and Montes-Rojas (2015). See also Galvao et al. (2021) for a recent study that discusses the assumptions for asymptotic validity of the bootstrap in a similar framework. The following section explores the finite-sample performance of our two-stage esti- mation procedure. 4. Monte Carlo study Our Monte Carlo design is a variation of the Monte Carlo exercises proposed in Bai (2009), Harding and Lamarche (2014), and Su and Wang (2017). We are interested in showing the consistency of the parameter estimators under the presence of time-varying factor loadings. Consider the following data generating process with R ¼ 2 unknown factors: Y ¼ β þ β X þ Λ F þ Λ F þ 1þ �X þ γ F þ γ F ε : (28) it it it;1 1t it;2 2t it 1t 2t it 0 1 1 2 In this model as well as in the empirical application below we assume a set of common factors that is constant across quantiles. For this exercise the parameter of interest is the marginal effect on the conditional quantile, which corresponds to β ðτÞ ¼ β þ �Q ðτÞ. 1 1 The parameter � thus determines if there is heterogeneity across quantiles. For �¼ 0 we have a location-shift model while for �� 0 we have a location-scale shift model. The parameters γ and γ determine whether the factors also have an effect on the scale that 1 2 may potentially contaminate the estimators of the quantile marginal effects. We consider two distributions for the error term ε , Gaussian and standardized chi-squared with 1 it degree of freedom. For all models we fix β ¼ 0 and β ¼ 1, and we consider different 0 1 scenarios with �2 f0; 0:1g and ðγ ; γ Þ 2 fð0; 0Þ;ð0:1; 0:1Þg. For simplicity, we con- 1 2 sider X ,IID Nð0; 1Þ. it We generate the factors, j ¼ 1; 2, with the following model F ¼ ρ F þ η ; η ¼ ρ η þ e ; (29) j;t j;t 1 j;t f j;t j;t η j;t 1 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 15 where we assume for all cases that e are standard Gaussian independent random jt variables for i ¼ 1; . . . ; N, t ¼ 49; . . . ; 0; . . . ; T and j ¼ 1; 2. The common parameters are assumed ρ ¼ 0:90; ρ ¼ 0:25 as in Harding and Lamarche (2014). f η The time-varying factor loadings models for the common factors are DGP 1: Λ ,IID Nð0; 1Þ for j ¼ 1; 2; and DGP 2: Λ ¼ Λ ,IID Nð0; 1Þ for j ¼ 1; 2. DGP 1 it;j it;j i;j thus have factor loadings that vary across t and i while DGP 2 only varies across individuals. We study the finite-sample performance of two estimators of the slope parameters β . First, an estimator that considers time-varying factor loadings using the local estimation procedure developed in this paper, and denoted as β . In this case we are in fact estimating individual-specific coefficients (β , β and Λ for j ¼ 1; 2) for all it;j 0;it 1;it t ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; T. This estimator is thus the most demanding one. We will refer to this model as the local factor estimator. Second, we consider a model with time-invariant loadings, that is denoted as β . Here, we do not impose the time-varying local estimation procedure and, instead, we estimate a unique set of parameters (β , β and Λ for i;j 0 1 j ¼ 1; 2) for all t. The latter estimator will be referred to as the global factor estimator. In all cases we consider a fixed bandwidth of h ¼ h ¼ 1. In order to evaluate the performance of our estimators and for comparability pur- poses, we study bias and mean squared error (MSE) by comparing the estimates with the β ðτÞ parameter defined above. For the local factor estimator we compute the sample average across i and t of β for every simulation. For the global factor estimator we 1;it compute the sample average across i. The sample size of the different simulation experiments comprises all possible com- binations of N; T ¼ f20; 50; 100g. The number of Monte Carlo experiments is 200 in every case. Tables 1 and 2 report the simulation exercise results for the case with �¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0 for DGP1 and DGP2, respectively. In this case all coefficients should be 1 2 estimating the same value of 1 for all quantiles. Tables 3 and 4 report the simulation exercise results for the case with �¼ 0:1; γ ¼ γ ¼ 0 for DGP1 and DGP2, respectively; 1 2 Tables 5 and 6 study the case given by �¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0:1 for DGP1 and DGP2, 1 2 respectively. Importantly, the last two cases generate heterogeneity across quantiles such that the coefficient estimates are different across quantiles. First, note that there is no clear pattern for bias reduction when T or N increases leaving the other dimension constant. However, bias monotonically reduces when both N and T increase. There is, however, a mean square error (MSE) reduction when either N or T increases. These results provide empirical evidence on the consistency of the parameter estimators above as T and N increase. Second, the time-varying local estimator exhibits a larger MSE value than the global factor estimator. This result is expected as the local estimator is more demanding and uses fewer observations to estimate the para- meters. In contrast, the estimator offers additional flexibility as we can estimate time- varying coefficients. The ratios of the MSE performance of the two estimators are similar across specifications. Third, those simulation scenarios are given by an error term ε it following a chi-squared distribution show differences across quantiles for both estima- tors. One unexpected feature is that the MSE performance of τ ¼ 0:25 is worse than that of τ ¼ 0:75 for the local estimator. This may be the result of the estimated factors 16 A. ATAK ET AL. Table 1. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 1 it 20 20 −0.0360 0.0010 −0.0261 0.0055 −0.0303 0.0046 0.3681 0.0252 0.3527 0.0167 0.4850 0.0216 20 50 −0.0129 0.0003 −0.0154 −0.0007 −0.0142 0.0028 0.1010 0.0070 0.0994 0.0050 0.0943 0.0084 20 100 0.0060 0.0015 0.0145 0.0031 0.0141 0.0042 0.0333 0.0047 0.0376 0.0028 0.0283 0.0036 50 20 0.0088 −0.0098 0.0188 −0.0088 0.0184 −0.0080 0.1536 0.0125 0.1787 0.0083 0.1469 0.0099 50 50 −0.0140 −0.0012 −0.0148 0.0003 −0.0133 0.0009 0.0508 0.0034 0.0527 0.0027 0.0501 0.0036 50 100 0.0064 0.0012 0.0015 0.0004 0.0050 0.0020 0.0132 0.0016 0.0128 0.0011 0.0126 0.0011 100 20 0.0064 −0.0021 0.0065 0.0005 0.0135 0.0047 0.1263 0.0050 0.1027 0.0034 0.0936 0.0065 100 50 −0.0045 −0.0016 −0.0094 −0.0029 −0.0149 −0.0005 0.0184 0.0016 0.0168 0.0012 0.0191 0.0016 100 100 −0.0072 −0.0026 −0.0042 −0.0022 −0.0076 0.0005 0.0082 0.0008 0.0074 0.0005 0.0067 0.0007 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 2 it 20 20 −0.0177 0.0170 −0.0071 0.0141 −0.0080 0.0110 0.4007 0.0262 0.4420 0.0196 0.4676 0.0257 20 50 0.0330 −0.0013 0.0170 0.0035 0.0213 0.0108 0.1544 0.0077 0.1150 0.0049 0.1060 0.0070 20 100 0.0186 −0.0022 0.0125 0.0001 −0.0049 −0.0004 0.0906 0.0034 0.0987 0.0026 0.0486 0.0035 50 20 0.0351 −0.0015 0.0175 0.0030 0.0104 0.0031 0.1322 0.0095 0.1392 0.0071 0.1422 0.0103 50 50 0.0216 0.0017 0.0249 0.0022 0.0246 0.0030 0.0462 0.0031 0.0511 0.0024 0.0577 0.0032 50 100 0.0075 0.0002 0.0073 −0.0001 0.0106 0.0040 0.0147 0.0018 0.0144 0.0012 0.0156 0.0014 100 20 0.0173 −0.0034 0.0085 −0.0007 −0.0055 −0.0006 0.1131 0.0057 0.0972 0.0035 0.0797 0.0054 100 50 −0.0131 −0.0007 −0.0150 0.0032 −0.0137 −0.0004 0.0206 0.0014 0.0225 0.0010 0.0174 0.0017 100 100 0.0065 0.0017 0.0073 0.0026 0.0045 0.0002 0.0049 0.0007 0.0044 0.0005 0.0044 0.0007 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 17 Table 2. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,χ , DGP 1 it 20 20 −0.0295 0.0037 0.0182 0.0035 −0.0122 −0.0058 1.4004 0.0168 0.6702 0.0135 0.3696 0.0231 20 50 −0.0111 −0.0018 −0.0007 0.0015 0.0007 0.0070 0.0826 0.0054 0.0732 0.0040 0.0784 0.0055 20 100 0.0191 −0.0022 0.0262 −0.0014 0.0370 −0.0026 0.0482 0.0027 0.0505 0.0018 0.0336 0.0026 50 20 0.0293 0.0019 0.0209 0.0015 0.0218 −0.0008 0.2709 0.0068 0.2654 0.0049 0.2623 0.0061 50 50 −0.0081 0.0057 −0.0105 0.0033 −0.0085 0.0064 0.0346 0.0023 0.0377 0.0015 0.0362 0.0023 50 100 0.0151 0.0018 0.0101 0.0020 0.0028 0.0016 0.0116 0.0010 0.0112 0.0007 0.0121 0.0010 100 20 −0.0317 −0.0033 −0.0334 0.0003 −0.0302 0.0001 0.1769 0.0040 0.1805 0.0029 0.1825 0.0036 100 50 0.0097 −0.0013 0.0041 −0.0003 −0.0072 0.0022 0.0280 0.0011 0.0283 0.0007 0.0223 0.0012 100 100 0.0056 0.0009 0.0043 0.0004 −0.0015 −0.0003 0.0061 0.0005 0.0062 0.0004 0.0099 0.0005 ε ,χ , DGP 2 it 20 20 −0.0475 −0.0031 −0.0207 0.0029 0.0249 0.0077 0.3110 0.0225 0.3397 0.0154 0.4451 0.0216 20 50 0.0179 0.0084 0.0194 0.0045 0.0231 −0.0006 0.0832 0.0058 0.0959 0.0035 0.0938 0.0059 20 100 −0.0006 −0.0013 −0.0032 −0.0015 0.0004 0.0002 0.0353 0.0026 0.0354 0.0017 0.0510 0.0028 50 20 −0.0243 −0.0105 −0.0253 −0.0032 −0.0134 −0.0006 0.2504 0.0091 0.2696 0.0056 0.2395 0.0071 50 50 0.0063 −0.0015 −0.0034 0.0022 −0.0042 0.0028 0.0309 0.0025 0.0533 0.0016 0.0438 0.0023 50 100 −0.0170 0.0005 −0.0135 0.0001 −0.0105 0.0005 0.0116 0.0010 0.0116 0.0009 0.0148 0.0010 100 20 0.0009 0.0034 −0.0026 0.0028 0.0026 −0.0021 0.0983 0.0031 0.1261 0.0029 0.0895 0.0039 100 50 −0.0695 −0.0036 −0.0159 −0.0016 −0.0106 −0.0037 0.7384 0.0012 0.0121 0.0008 0.0129 0.0011 100 100 0.0005 −0.0014 −0.0001 0.0004 0.0000 −0.0018 0.0081 0.0007 0.0083 0.0004 0.0075 0.0005 18 A. ATAK ET AL. Table 3. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ 0:1; γ ¼ γ ¼ 0. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 1 it 20 20 0.0098 0.0354 −0.0505 −0.0026 −0.0753 −0.0374 0.4408 0.0318 0.4566 0.0237 0.3714 0.0249 20 50 0.0397 0.0138 −0.0184 −0.0103 −0.0889 −0.0349 0.3219 0.0282 0.3170 0.0245 0.3828 0.0269 20 100 0.0756 0.0213 0.0041 0.0004 −0.1157 −0.0244 0.3268 0.0234 0.2997 0.0154 0.2746 0.0287 50 20 0.0613 0.0321 0.0245 −0.0075 −0.0311 −0.0414 0.3470 0.0243 0.3390 0.0154 0.3849 0.0280 50 50 0.0786 0.0296 0.0126 0.0028 −0.0669 −0.0243 0.0681 0.0078 0.0752 0.0056 0.0947 0.0087 50 100 0.0681 0.0251 −0.0022 −0.0014 −0.0694 −0.0248 0.0681 0.0099 0.0732 0.0055 0.0809 0.0088 100 20 0.0619 0.0333 −0.0177 0.0023 −0.0873 −0.0357 0.0815 0.0092 0.0869 0.0071 0.1002 0.0148 100 50 0.0754 0.0286 0.0179 0.0029 −0.0540 −0.0249 0.0803 0.0087 0.1104 0.0061 0.1222 0.0132 100 100 0.0652 0.0247 −0.0015 0.0005 −0.0686 −0.0217 0.0308 0.0038 0.0255 0.0029 0.9163 0.0042 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 2 it 20 20 0.0716 0.0354 0.0367 −0.0040 −0.0595 −0.0401 0.0400 0.0048 0.0405 0.0026 0.0485 0.0048 20 50 0.0724 0.0337 0.0068 −0.0004 −0.0640 −0.0339 0.0322 0.0057 0.0357 0.0038 0.0585 0.0098 20 100 0.0408 0.0295 −0.0284 0.0020 −0.0888 −0.0254 0.0342 0.0059 0.0383 0.0043 0.0545 0.0094 50 20 0.0851 0.0246 0.0153 −0.0047 −0.0892 −0.0392 0.1974 0.0099 0.1305 0.0078 0.1730 0.0123 50 50 0.1059 0.0276 0.0018 0.0022 −0.0604 −0.0245 0.3655 0.0096 0.3506 0.0072 0.3184 0.0131 50 100 0.0662 0.0223 −0.0022 −0.0004 −0.0713 −0.0244 0.3033 0.0096 0.1910 0.0084 0.1797 0.0165 100 20 0.1031 0.0393 0.0330 0.0082 −0.0347 −0.0217 0.4136 0.0112 0.3090 0.0081 0.5705 0.0161 100 50 0.0584 0.0252 0.0062 −0.0024 −0.0609 −0.0323 0.0403 0.0043 0.0323 0.0025 0.0425 0.0044 100 100 0.0618 0.0224 −0.0053 −0.0020 −0.0719 −0.0244 0.3769 0.0039 0.1005 0.0020 0.0638 0.0034 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 19 Table 4. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ 0:1; γ ¼ γ ¼ 0. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 1 it 20 20 0.0098 0.0354 −0.0505 −0.0026 −0.0753 −0.0374 0.4408 0.0318 0.4566 0.0237 0.3714 0.0249 20 50 0.0397 0.0138 −0.0184 −0.0103 −0.0889 −0.0349 0.3219 0.0282 0.3170 0.0245 0.3828 0.0269 20 100 0.0756 0.0213 0.0041 0.0004 −0.1157 −0.0244 0.3268 0.0234 0.2997 0.0154 0.2746 0.0287 50 20 0.0613 0.0321 0.0245 −0.0075 −0.0311 −0.0414 0.3470 0.0243 0.3390 0.0154 0.3849 0.0280 50 50 0.0786 0.0296 0.0126 0.0028 −0.0669 −0.0243 0.0681 0.0078 0.0752 0.0056 0.0947 0.0087 50 100 0.0681 0.0251 −0.0022 −0.0014 −0.0694 −0.0248 0.0681 0.0099 0.0732 0.0055 0.0809 0.0088 100 20 0.0619 0.0333 −0.0177 0.0023 −0.0873 −0.0357 0.0815 0.0092 0.0869 0.0071 0.1002 0.0148 100 50 0.0754 0.0286 0.0179 0.0029 −0.0540 −0.0249 0.0803 0.0087 0.1104 0.0061 0.1222 0.0132 100 100 0.0652 0.0247 −0.0015 0.0005 −0.0686 −0.0217 0.0308 0.0038 0.0255 0.0029 0.9163 0.0042 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 2 it 20 20 0.0716 0.0354 0.0367 −0.0040 −0.0595 −0.0401 0.0400 0.0048 0.0405 0.0026 0.0485 0.0048 20 50 0.0724 0.0337 0.0068 −0.0004 −0.0640 −0.0339 0.0322 0.0057 0.0357 0.0038 0.0585 0.0098 20 100 0.0408 0.0295 −0.0284 0.0020 −0.0888 −0.0254 0.0342 0.0059 0.0383 0.0043 0.0545 0.0094 50 20 0.0851 0.0246 0.0153 −0.0047 −0.0892 −0.0392 0.1974 0.0099 0.1305 0.0078 0.1730 0.0123 50 50 0.1059 0.0276 0.0018 0.0022 −0.0604 −0.0245 0.3655 0.0096 0.3506 0.0072 0.3184 0.0131 50 100 0.0662 0.0223 −0.0022 −0.0004 −0.0713 −0.0244 0.3033 0.0096 0.1910 0.0084 0.1797 0.0165 100 20 0.1031 0.0393 0.0330 0.0082 −0.0347 −0.0217 0.4136 0.0112 0.3090 0.0081 0.5705 0.0161 100 50 0.0584 0.0252 0.0062 −0.0024 −0.0609 −0.0323 0.0403 0.0043 0.0323 0.0025 0.0425 0.0044 100 100 0.0618 0.0224 −0.0053 −0.0020 −0.0719 −0.0244 0.3769 0.0039 0.1005 0.0020 0.0638 0.0034 20 A. ATAK ET AL. Table 5. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ 0:1. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 τ ¼ 0:25 τ ¼ 0:5 τ ¼ 0:75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 1 it 20 20 0.0483 0.0088 0.0094 −0.0183 −0.0527 −0.0551 0.3497 0.0299 0.2694 0.0211 0.2821 0.0318 20 50 0.0827 0.0287 0.0023 −0.0030 −0.0732 −0.0261 0.1266 0.0076 0.0815 0.0063 0.0807 0.0088 20 100 0.0618 0.0194 −0.0002 −0.0020 −0.0663 −0.0253 0.0274 0.0041 0.0255 0.0026 0.0310 0.0042 50 20 0.0811 0.0357 0.0242 0.0039 −0.0502 −0.0242 0.1440 0.0115 0.1806 0.0094 0.1830 0.0105 50 50 0.0826 0.0264 0.0112 −0.0014 −0.0441 −0.0246 0.0875 0.0036 0.0307 0.0023 0.0290 0.0040 50 100 0.0600 0.0221 −0.0138 0.0005 −0.0815 −0.0255 0.0164 0.0018 0.0122 0.0008 0.0184 0.0020 100 20 0.0421 0.0452 −0.0164 0.0091 −0.0853 −0.0313 0.1163 0.0086 0.1127 0.0042 0.1156 0.0073 100 50 0.0521 0.0289 −0.0099 −0.0008 −0.0766 −0.0294 0.0412 0.0025 0.0391 0.0014 0.0326 0.0023 100 100 0.0543 0.0234 −0.0084 −0.0031 −0.0742 −0.0247 0.0110 0.0012 0.0069 0.0006 0.0130 0.0013 ε ,Nð0; 1Þ, DGP 2 it 20 20 0.0958 0.0361 0.0328 0.0070 −0.0296 −0.0261 0.4316 0.0276 0.3980 0.0188 0.4147 0.0214 20 50 0.0790 0.0259 0.0268 0.0008 −0.0236 −0.0396 0.1781 0.0076 0.1971 0.0056 0.2013 0.0095 20 100 0.0707 0.0256 −0.0089 0.0018 −0.0798 −0.0226 0.0328 0.0047 0.0293 0.0032 0.0366 0.0046 50 20 0.0762 0.0406 0.0172 −0.0045 −0.0512 −0.0331 0.1733 0.0102 0.1624 0.0077 0.1668 0.0116 50 50 0.0737 0.0275 0.0001 0.0031 −0.0760 −0.0262 0.0432 0.0038 0.0378 0.0023 0.0415 0.0039 50 100 0.0692 0.0290 0.0030 0.0006 −0.0703 −0.0267 0.0167 0.0024 0.0128 0.0010 0.0186 0.0022 100 20 0.1016 0.0305 0.0331 −0.0009 −0.0368 −0.0331 0.0970 0.0049 0.0828 0.0032 0.0836 0.0058 100 50 0.0788 0.0293 0.0022 0.0010 −0.0643 −0.0244 0.0300 0.0027 0.0225 0.0012 0.0243 0.0023 100 100 0.0737 0.0255 0.0072 −0.0004 −0.0639 −0.0257 0.0137 0.0015 0.0060 0.0006 0.0095 0.0015 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 21 Table 6. Monte Carlo simulations, ϕ ¼ γ ¼ γ ¼ :1. 1 2 Bias MSE τ ¼ :25 τ ¼ :5 τ ¼ :75 τ ¼ :25 τ ¼ :5 τ ¼ :75 b e b e b e b e b e b e N T β β β β β β β β β β β β 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ε ,χ , DGP 1 it 20 20 0.0422 −0.0353 0.0128 −0.0521 −0.0868 −0.0820 0.3387 0.0231 0.3161 0.0165 0.4824 0.0279 20 50 −0.0466 −0.0535 −0.0635 −0.0480 −0.1576 −0.0929 0.1308 0.0099 0.0978 0.0078 0.0985 0.0141 20 100 0.0261 −0.0543 −0.0133 −0.0427 −0.0964 −0.0855 0.1126 0.0065 0.1181 0.0038 0.1278 0.0094 50 20 −0.0159 −0.0457 −0.0348 −0.0522 −0.1200 −0.0991 0.2613 0.0109 0.5243 0.0082 0.5611 0.0180 50 50 −0.0196 −0.0534 −0.0512 −0.0436 −0.1536 −0.0860 0.0425 0.0053 0.0471 0.0035 0.0631 0.0095 50 100 −0.0069 −0.0584 −0.0291 −0.0446 −0.1145 −0.0801 0.0118 0.0047 0.1143 0.0027 0.1316 0.0075 100 20 −0.0214 −0.0425 −0.0495 −0.0436 −0.1318 −0.0915 0.0501 0.0061 0.0577 0.0046 0.0855 0.0124 100 50 −0.0180 −0.0583 −0.0493 −0.0481 −0.1304 −0.0865 0.0200 0.0048 0.0203 0.0032 0.0341 0.0086 100 100 −0.0074 −0.0572 −0.0503 −0.0478 −0.1382 −0.0870 0.0057 0.0039 0.0080 0.0027 0.0246 0.0082 ε ,χ , DGP 2 it 20 20 0.0015 −0.0512 −0.0190 −0.0390 −0.0332 −0.0811 0.3054 0.0252 0.2958 0.0131 3.1877 0.0237 20 50 −0.0190 −0.0497 −0.0488 −0.0368 −0.1300 −0.0793 0.0638 0.0085 0.0603 0.0059 0.0724 0.0120 20 100 0.0069 −0.0551 −0.0139 −0.0417 −0.1105 −0.0849 0.0442 0.0054 0.0573 0.0035 0.0479 0.0097 50 20 0.0010 −0.0484 −0.0333 −0.0397 −0.1631 −0.0857 0.1740 0.0115 0.1684 0.0075 0.1699 0.0153 50 50 −0.0277 −0.0575 −0.0600 −0.0425 −0.1505 −0.0849 0.0334 0.0060 0.0444 0.0033 0.0680 0.0094 50 100 −0.0254 −0.0658 −0.0647 −0.0485 −0.1521 −0.0870 0.0136 0.0057 0.0208 0.0032 0.0402 0.0086 100 20 −0.0374 −0.0458 −0.0648 −0.0451 −0.1398 −0.0925 0.1174 0.0065 0.1255 0.0052 0.1347 0.0129 100 50 −0.0172 −0.0549 −0.0482 −0.0443 −0.1424 −0.0872 0.0163 0.0042 0.0178 0.0029 0.0382 0.0088 100 100 −0.0056 −0.0580 −0.0398 −0.0460 −0.1230 −0.0838 0.0060 0.0039 0.0081 0.0025 0.0213 0.0075 22 A. ATAK ET AL. absorbing a more substantial portion of the variance in the quantile location with more probability mass. 5. Empirical application This section applies the above model to an empirical asset pricing context. In contrast to standard asset pricing models, we explore the distributional risk premia by fitting the above models to different quantiles of the distribution of excess returns. We are interested in assessing the effect of including unobserved local factors with time- varying factor loadings in standard asset pricing specifications. The methodology developed above also allows us to estimate dynamic parameter estimates measuring the sensitivity of the quantile process of excess returns to a set of idiosyncratic firm- specific factors that are combined with Fama and French (1993) three-factor model. 5.1. Data The set of firm-specific covariates X is obtained from a panel of U.S. firms and obtained it from Compustat Industrial dataset. The sample consists of annual CRSP/Compustat data from the years 1970 through 2011. Following standard practice, we exclude financial firms (SIC codes 6000–6999), regulated utilities (SIC codes 4900–4999), and non-profit organizations (SIC codes greater than or equal to 9000). We omit firm-years with a missing or negative value for fixed assets and sales, with a missing or less than ten million 1983 dollar book value of total assets, and with growth rates of fixed assets, sales, and the book value of total assets greater than 100%. We consider the following list of firm characteristics: MB denotes firms’ market- to-book ratio; LNTA denotes the log of the firm’s asset size; EBITTA denotes earnings before interest and taxes as a proportion of total assets; MDR denotes the market debt ratio, defined as the book value of debt over the market value of assets; and DEPTA denotes depreciation as a proportion of total assets. The set of covariates is completed by the following observable pricing factors taken from Kenneth French website. The common pricing factors are MKTRF, SMB and HML. The factor MKTRF is defined as a value-weighted average market portfolio return net of the risk-free asset. The risk-free rate is proxied by daily returns on the U.S. three-month Treasury bill. The factor SMB is a small-minus-big portfolio constructed as the difference between the returns on diversified portfolios of small and large asset size. The factor HML is high-minus-low portfolio constructed as the difference between the returns on diversified portfolios of high and small book-to- market equity. The firms’ excess returns are the annual excess return on assets computed over the annual interest rate offered by one-month U.S. Treasury bills. The final sample includes a balanced panel of 297 firms with 2 years of data. Although there is no consensus in the literature on the length of the time dimension; we acknowledge that the time dimension selection criteria might favor larger and more mature companies, which may lead to the results being valid only for large and mature companies. However, the average estimated effects from our sample are in line with the consensus in the literature, and thus, the results could be applied to all companies. The log of total assets is the only variable that is not a ratio, and is deflated to the 1983 dollar with the consumer price index obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 23 5.2. Empirical models In a similar spirit to Giovannetti (2013), Galvao et al. (2018) and Galvao et al. (2019), we propose a quantile process for modelling the distribution of excess returns. The objective of this study is to show if an empirical pricing strategy based on firm-specific variables coupled with unobserved quantile factors with time-varying loadings is able to explain the cross-section of excess returns on a set of U.S. firms. As a byproduct, we also study if this model adds predictive ability to the standard Fama-French three-factor model. The pricing factors of our baseline model are firm-specific financial ratios, see Kogan and Papanikolaou (2013) for a discussion of empirical asset pricing models using firm- specific variables. This approach has recently gained support due to the strong evidence of the co-movement in stock returns of firms with similar characteristics that is unrelated to their exposures to the market portfolio. Our baseline model is Q Y j X ; F ¼ X β þ F Λ ; i ¼ 1; . . . ; n; t ¼ 1; . . . ; T; (30) τ it it τ;it it τ;it τ;it τ;it with τ 2 ð0; 1Þ and R ¼ 2. We assume that the unobserved common factors for the quantile model are location shift transformations of the estimates of the mean factors F 1t and F . The shifts defining the quantile factors are captured by the values of the dynamic 2t intercepts a of the different quantile models. We estimate two versions of this model τ;it for τ 2 f0:10; 0:25; 0:50; 0:75; 0:90g. A first version considers global factors and uses the methodology proposed in Ando and Bai (2015) to estimate the factors, F , which are then used to estimate the set of parameters ðβ ; Λ Þ. The second version considers local τ;i factors and uses the methodology developed above to estimate the time-varying para- meters ðβ ; Λ Þ. Note that the loadings associated to the observable covariates do not τ;it τ;it only vary over time but also across individuals. We consider two models. Model 1 uses only firm-specific covariates, X ¼ ½MBR; EBITTA; MB; DEPTA; LNTA�. Model 2 aug- ments the above model by MKTRF, SMB, and HML. Standard errors are estimated using bootstrap by resampling only from cross-sectional units with replacement as in Kapetanios (2008) and Galvao and Montes-Rojas (2015) using 100 replications. In all cases the bandwidth parameter is set to 10. The results are reported in Tables 7–10. The results are an extension of the findings in Galvao et al. (2018). In this case, we incorporate the presence of unobserved common factors. Firm-specific covariates are Table 7. Model 1. Firm-specific quantile regression model with R ¼ 2 unobserved factors. Global factors with fixed loadings. Standard errors are in brackets. 0.10 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.90 CONST −8.912 −7.582 −5.427 −6.313 −4.827 (1.661) (1.100) (0.925) (1.112) (1.847) MDR 2.963 2.447 2.412 2.603 3.067 (0.379) (0.219) (0.189) (0.206) (0.321) EBITTA 0.806 0.211 −0.040 −0.193 −0.519 (0.388) (0.251) (0.264) (0.288) (0.475) MB −0.053 −0.118 −0.174 −0.123 0.006 (0.058) (0.046) (0.045) (0.055) (0.076) DEPTA −4.647 −4.734 −5.820 −7.949 −10.123 (2.178) (1.515) (1.314) (1.646) (2.515) LNTA 0.397 0.359 0.275 0.344 0.278 (0.086) (0.056) (0.046) (0.057) (0.098) 24 A. ATAK ET AL. Table 8. Model 1. Firm-specific quantile regression model with R ¼ 2 unobserved factors. Local factors with time-varying factor loadings. Standard errors are in brackets. 0.10 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.90 CONST −6.688 −4.522 −3.422 −1.886 −0.582 (0.921) (0.672) (0.606) (0.721) (1.119) MBR 2.514 2.185 2.344 2.605 2.869 (0.185) (0.138) (0.153) (0.201) (0.293) EBITTA 0.830 0.129 −0.122 −0.410 −0.454 (0.346) (0.234) (0.233) (0.277) (0.390) MB −0.024 −0.105 −0.116 −0.079 −0.005 (0.063) (0.046) (0.041) (0.045) (0.076) DEPTA −3.722 −5.923 −6.927 −8.828 −11.270 (1.818) (1.190) (1.131) (1.515) (2.445) LNTA 0.276 0.199 0.163 0.108 0.061 (0.045) (0.033) (0.030) (0.036) (0.056) Table 9. Model 2. Quantile regression model with R ¼ 2 unobserved global factors with fixed loadings. The model considers firm-specific covariates and Fama-French three-factor model. Standard errors are in brackets. 0.10 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.90 CONST −8.582 −5.759 −4.869 −4.649 −6.279 (1.420) (0.919) (0.729) (1.000) (1.981) MBR 2.386 2.095 2.093 2.330 2.640 (0.325) (0.198) (0.180) (0.214) (0.307) MB −0.129 −0.259 −0.391 −0.530 −0.260 (0.355) (0.218) (0.243) (0.255) (0.418) EBITTA −0.039 −0.112 −0.171 −0.072 0.027 (0.059) (0.045) (0.042) (0.053) (0.082) DEPTA −3.545 −4.978 −6.824 −7.539 −8.431 (1.982) (1.494) (1.382) (1.577) (2.596) LNTA 0.405 0.278 0.256 0.265 0.356 (0.075) (0.047) (0.039) (0.054) (0.104) MKTRF −0.510 −0.520 −0.615 −0.620 −0.620 0.062 0.048 0.043 0.057 0.094 SMB −0.840 −0.787 −0.740 −0.767 −0.797 0.107 0.074 0.063 0.070 0.123 HML −0.182 −0.189 −0.215 −0.212 −0.192 0.089 0.058 0.055 0.062 0.104 statistically significant in all models, and the model parameter estimates are similar across the different specifications of the empirical asset pricing model reported in Tables 7–10. The estimates reported for the model with local factors are averages across time and individuals of the parameter estimates of β for i ¼ 1; . . . ; N and t ¼ 1; . . . ; T. it Our empirical asset pricing model uncovers a positive exposure of firms’ excess returns to the market-to-book ratio (MDR) and the log of asset size (LNTA) and negative exposure to the market debt ratio (MB) and depreciation as a proportion of total assets (DEPTA). Earnings before interest and taxes as a proportion of total assets (EBITTA) have a positive effect on low quantiles and turn negative for τ ¼ 0:5 and beyond. The quantile parameter estimates are monotonically increasing on τ 2 ð0; 1Þ for LNTA and monotonically decreasing for DEPTA. All the coefficients are statistically significant at 5% significance levels. Tables 7–8 report the baseline case in expression (30) given by firm-specific covariates, Tables 9–10 report the pricing model augmented with Fama- French three-factor model. The results are also similar across specifications and JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 25 Table 10. Model 2: Quantile regression model with R ¼ 2 unobserved local factors with time-varying factor loadings. The model considers firm-specific covariates and Fama- French three-factor model. Standard errors are in brackets. 0.10 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.90 CONST −4.938 −3.503 −2.407 −1.710 −1.325 (0.788) (0.631) (0.548) (0.628) (1.021) MBR 2.319 1.988 2.020 2.222 2.267 (0.173) (0.135) (0.145) (0.170) (0.303) MB 0.081 −0.339 −0.478 −0.790 −0.511 (0.327) (0.224) (0.221) (0.238) (0.385) EBITTA −0.067 −0.127 −0.122 −0.065 0.026 (0.055) (0.038) (0.037) (0.045) (0.079) DEPTA −4.456 −6.037 −7.709 −9.996 −11.785 (1.927) (1.422) (1.211) (1.556) (2.256) LNTA 0.202 0.159 0.124 0.106 0.104 (0.037) (0.030) (0.026) (0.030) (0.049) MKTRF −0.516 −0.546 −0.588 −0.612 −0.636 0.070 0.051 0.049 0.065 0.100 SMB −0.724 −0.705 −0.716 −0.736 −0.677 0.121 0.095 0.077 0.086 0.135 HML −0.195 −0.221 −0.237 −0.231 −0.240 0.090 0.059 0.061 0.076 0.126 Figure 1. Model 2: Dynamics of β . 0.10 (blue), 0.25 (red), 0.50 (black), 0.75 (brown), and 0.90 (green) τ;t quantile coefficients with 95% confidence interval calculated with 200 bootstrap RTN α þ β MDR þ β EBITTA þ β MB þ β DEPTA þ i;tþ1 i i;t i;t i;t i;t it;MDR it;EBITTA it;MB it;DEPTA replications. β LNTA þ β MKTRF þ β SMB þ β HML þ ε it;LNTA i;t it;MKTRF i;t it;SMB i;t it;HML i;t i;tþ1 26 A. ATAK ET AL. Figure 2. Model 2 continued. Notes: 0.10 (blue), 0.25 (red), 0.50 (black), 0.75 (brown), and 0.90 (green) quantile coefficients with 95% confidence interval calculated with 200 bootstrap replications. RTN α þ β MDR þ β EBITTA þ β MB þ β DEPTA þ i;tþ1 i i;t i;t i;t i;t it;MDR it;EBITTA it;MB it;DEPTA β LNTA þ β MKTRF þ β SMB þ β HML þ ε i;t i;t i;t i;t i;tþ1 it;LNTA it;MKTRF it;SMB it;HML estimation methods. However, the magnitude of the model parameters changes signifi- cantly between the global and local factor estimation methods. The pricing model with local factors provides similar insights to the model with unobserved global factors but has the additional advantage of offering the possibility of studying the dynamics of the loadings β associated to each observable covariate. These τ;it dynamics are reported in Figures 1–2, corresponding to the local factor model with the augmented set of covariates in Table 10. Importantly, the model also allows the possibi- lity of studying the dynamics of the unobserved common factor loadings Λ , never- τ;it theless, we do not report these values as an interpretation of the results is difficult due to the lack of interpretation of the common factor estimates. Each panel reports five lines that reflect the dynamics of the parameters β over time. These estimates are constructed τ;t as the cross-sectional average of β for each t and the standard errors are calculated by τ;it bootstrap. The results show how the exposure of the excess returns to some covariates and factor models have evolved over time. The figures show that there was little variation in the average effects, and they are all within the 95% confidence interval of each other. One limitation in the analysis is that the time dimension (T ¼ 42) does not allow us to obtain a finer set of local estimates. JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 27 6. Conclusion This paper proposes a functional coefficient quantile regression model with time- varying factor loadings. Estimation of the quantile factors and factor loadings is done in two stages. First, we estimate the unobserved common factors from a linear factor mean-based model with exogenous covariates. In the second stage, we plug-in an affine transformation of the estimates of the common factors to obtain the quantile version of the factor model. This model requires both the number of individuals and the number of periods to grow to infinity. The number of individuals needs to diverge for the consistent estimation of the common factors in the first stage. Also, to consistently estimate the quantile factor loadings the number of time periods needs to diverge as well. As a byproduct, our model can capture dynamics and heterogeneity across individuals in both the quantile slope coefficients and the quantile factor loadings. The introduction of time-varying coefficients adds flexibility to standard factor model specifications that assume slope homogeneity as in Bai (2003, 2009) and slope heterogeneity as in Ando and Bai (2015). The model also extends the recent partial linear model of Su and Wang (2017) by considering the quantile process and including the presence of exogenous regressors. This model specification is applied in an empirical application to explain the distribu- tion of the excess returns for a cross-section of asset returns in the U.S. In contrast to standard asset pricing formulations, we consider firm-specific covariates as pricing factors and allow for the presence of two unobserved factors. The model provides satisfactory estimates of the sensitivity of the excess return to the pricing variables under both global (Ando & Bai, 2015) and local factor models. The main contribution of our methodology is to be able to estimate the dynamics of the slope coefficients (betas) for each asset and over time. By doing so, we can track the dynamic exposure of assets’ excess returns to the different financial ratios acting as pricing variables. Disclosure statement No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors. Notes on contributors Alev Atak has a PhD in Economics from Queen Mary, University of London. She works on econometrics and finance. Gabriel Montes-Rojas has a PhD in Economics from the University of Illinois at Urbana- Champaign. He especializes in econometric theory with works in quantile regression, panel data, and multivariate models. Jose Olmo has a PhD in Economics from Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. His research interests are in Financial and Applied Econometrics, and Financial Economics. Jose has also served in the editorial board of several academic journals. 28 A. ATAK ET AL. References Ando, T., & Bai, J. (2015). Asset pricing with a general multifactor structure. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 13(3), 556–604. https://doi.org/10.1093/jjfinec/nbu026 Ando, T., & Bai, J. (2020). Quantile co-movement in financial markets: A panel quantile model with unobserved heterogeneity. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 115(529), 266–279. https://doi.org/10.1080/01621459.2018.1543598 Bai, J. (2003). Inferential theory for factor models of large dimensions. Econometrica, 71(1), 135–171. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00392 Bai, J. (2009). Panel data models with interactive fixed effects. Econometrica, 77, 1229–1279. Bai, J., & Ng, S. (2002). Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models. Econometrica. Econometrica, 70(1), 191–221. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00273 Bates, B. J., Plagborg-Mø Ller, M., Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2013). Consistent factor estimation in dynamic factor models with structural instability. Journal of Econometrics, 177 (2), 289–304. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2013.04.014 Cai, Z. (2007). Trending time-varying coefficient time series models with serially correlated errors. Journal of Econometrics, 136(1), 163–188. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2005.08.004 Cai, Z., & Xiao, Z. (2012). Semiparametric quantile regression estimation in dynamic models with partially varying coefficients. Journal of Econometrics, 167(2), 413–425. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.jeconom.2011.09.025 Cai, Z., & Xu, X. (2008). Nonparametric quantile estimation for dynamic smooth coefficient models. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 103(484), 1595–1608. https://doi.org/ 10.1198/016214508000000977 Casas, I., Gao, J., Peng, B., & Xie, S. (2021). Time-varying income elasticities of healthcare expenditure for the OECD and Eurozone. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 36(3), 328–345. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.2809 Chaudhuri, P., Doksum, K., & Samarov, A. (1997). On average derivative quantile regression. Annals of Statistics, 25(2), 715–744. https://doi.org/10.1214/aos/1031833670 Chen, L., Dolado, J., & Gonzalo, J. (2021). Quantile factor models. Econometrica, 89(2), 875–910. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA15746 De Gooijer, J. G., & Zerom, D. (2003). On conditional density estimation. Statistica Neerlandica, 57(2), 159–176. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9574.00226 Eichler, M., Motta, G., & von Sachs, R. (2011). Fitting dynamic factor models to non-stationary time series. Journal of Econometrics, 163(1), 51–70. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2010.11.007 Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1), 3–56. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(93)90023-5 Fan, J., & Gijbels, I. (1996). Local polynomial modelling and its applications. Chapman & Hall. Galvao, A., Juhl, T., Montes-Rojas, G., & Olmo, J. (2018). Testing slope homogeneity in quantile regression panel data with an application to the cross-section of stock returns. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 16(2), 211–243. https://doi.org/10.1093/jjfinec/nbx016 Galvao, A., & Montes-Rojas, G. (2015). On bootstrap inference for quantile regression panel data: A Monte Carlo study. Econometrics , 3 (3), 654–666. https://doi.org/10.3390/ econometrics3030654 Galvao, A., Montes-Rojas, G., & Olmo, J. (2019). Tests of asset pricing with time-varying factor loads. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 34(5), 762–778. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.2687 Galvao, A., Parker, T., & Xiao, Z. 2021. Bootstrap inference for panel data quantile regression, https://arxiv.org/abs/2111.03626 . Giovannetti, B. C. (2013). Asset pricing under quantile utility maximization. Review of Financial Economics, 22(4), 169–179. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2013.05.008 Harding, M., & Lamarche, C. (2014). Estimating and testing a quantile regression model with interactive effects. Journal of Econometrics, 178, 101–113. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom. 2013.08.010 He, X., & Zhu, L. (2003). A lack-of-fit test for quantile regression. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 98(464), 1013–1022. https://doi.org/10.1198/016214503000000963 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 29 Horowitz, J. L., & Lee, S. (2005). Nonparametric estimation of an additive quantile regression model. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 100(472), 1238–1249. https://doi.org/10. 1198/016214505000000583 Kapetanios, G. A. (2008). Bootstrap procedure for panel datasets with many cross-sectional units. The Econometrics Journal, 11(2), 377–395. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1368-423X.2008.00243.x Kim, M. O. (2007). Quantile regression with varying coefficients. Annals of Statistics, 35(1), 92–108. https://doi.org/10.1214/009053606000000966 Koenker, R., & Bassett, G. S. (1978). Regression quantiles. Econometrica, 46(1), 33–50. https://doi. org/10.2307/1913643 Koenker, R., & Machado, J. A. F. (1999). Goodness of fit and related inference processes for quantile regression. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 94(448), 1296–1310. https:// doi.org/10.1080/01621459.1999.10473882 Koenker, R., & Xiao, Z. (2006). Quantile autoregression. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 101(475), 980–990. https://doi.org/10.1198/016214506000000672 Kogan, L., & Papanikolaou, D. (2013). Firm characteristics and stock returns: The role of investment-specific shocks. The Review of Financial Studies, 26(11), 2718–2759. https://doi. org/10.1093/rfs/hht026 Ma, S., Linton, O., & Gao, J. Estimation and inference in semiparametric quantile factor models. (2021). Journal of Econometrics, 222(1), 295–323. Part B. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom. 2020.07.003 Pagan, A. (1984). Econometric issues in the analysis of regressions with generated regressors. International Economic Review, 25(1), 221–247. https://doi.org/10.2307/2648877 Pelger, M., & Xiong, R. 2019. State-varying factor models of large dimensions. Papers 1807.02248v2, arXiv.org. 30 A. ATAK ET AL. Pesaran, M. H. (2006). Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a multifactor error structure. Econometrica, 74(4), 967–1012. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00692.x Portnoy, S. (1991). Asymptotic behavior of regression quantiles in nonstationary, dependent cases. Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 38(1), 100–113. https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-259X(91)90034-Y Song, M. 2013. Essays on large panel data analysis. Ph.D. thesis, Columbia University. Su, L., & Wang, X. (2017). On time-varying factor models: Estimation and testing. Journal of Econometrics, 198(1), 84–101. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2016.12.004 Wei, Y., & He, X. (2006). Conditional growth charts (with discussion). Annals of Statistics, 34(5), 2069–2097. https://doi.org/10.1214/009053606000000623 Yu, K., & Lu, Z. (2004). Local linear additive quantile regression. Scandinavian Journal of Statistics, 31(3), 333–346. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9469.2004.03_035.x Appendix Proof of Proposition 1. The proof of this proposition follows from an application of the results in Song (2013) and Ando and Ando and Bai (2015) to local principal components. The main difference is that we are considering local approximations using the kernels. � � ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Define Y ¼ k Y such that Y ¼ Y ; . . . ; Y is a T � 1 vector and Y ¼ it it h;ts i i1 iT � � � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Y ; . . . ; Y is a T � N matrix. Let X ¼ k X such that X ¼ X ; . . . ; X l;it 1 N l;it h;ts i 1;i d;i � � � � 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ and X ¼ X ; . . . ; X and ε ¼ k ε such that ε ¼ ε ; . . . ; ε is a T � 1 it it i i1 l;i l;i1 l;iT h;ts iT � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1=2 vector. Similarly, e ¼ k e such that e ¼ e ; . . . ; e is a T � 1 vector. Let it it h;ts i i1 iT ðsÞ 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 ðsÞ F ¼ k F such that F ¼ ðF ; . . . ; F Þ is a T � R matrix and Λ ¼ ðΛ ; . . . ; Λ Þ t t s 1s Ns h;ts 1 T be a R� N matrix. For each individual in the cross section, Equation 6 in vector form is ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Y ¼ X β þ F Λ þ e ; is i i i is and the OLS estimator of β is is 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β ¼ ðX M X Þ X M Y ; (A:1) ðsÞ ðsÞ is i i i i b b F F such that 0 1 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ X M ðsÞ X X M ðsÞ h i i i i B b C b ðsÞ F F ðsÞ β β ¼ @ A F Λ þ e : is is is T T ðsÞ ðsÞ X M X ðsÞ i i Then, under assumptions A.2 and A.4, it follows that is positive definite. Now, using a similar decomposition to Proposition 1 of Song (2013), we have � � 1 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ X M F Λ ¼ L β β þ o ð1Þ; ðsÞ is p i iq;T is is T F T N q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ � � X M X ðsÞ q i 1 ðsÞ Λ Λ b 0 s F s where L ¼ a and a ¼ Λ Λ . Thus, iq iq qs iq;T T is N JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 31 " # h i � � 1 0 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b β β ¼ S L β β þ X M ðsÞ e þ o ð1Þ; is is iT iq;T is is i i NT T F q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ X M X ðsÞ i i ðsÞ with S ¼ . Then, iT T � � 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ S L ðβ β Þ ¼ X M ðsÞ e þ o ð1Þ; i i iT iT is is NT T F such that � � 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β β ¼ S L X M ðsÞ e þ o ð1Þ: is is iT iT i i NT T ðsÞ ðsÞ Now, the quantities S and L satisfy that iT iT h i p 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ S ! S ; lim k E X M X ðsÞ ðsÞ h;ts it iT ii it F H T!1 t t t¼1 and T N h i XX 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ L ! L ; lim k a E X M ðsÞ ðsÞ X ; h;ts iq it iT ii it F H T!1 t t NT NT t¼1 q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ such that L ! L as N; T ! 1. � � NT iT ii m jt sj Furthermore, note that e ¼ ε þ d þ o , with ε the errors of the mean regression it it it P it m ðqÞ m ðqÞ P P β q Λ q t s t s is is model in assumption A.1, and d ¼ X ð Þ þ F ð Þ , for any fixed s; t 2 ½T�. it it t q! T q! T q¼1 q¼1 Therefore, � � 1 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β β ¼ S L X M ðsÞ ε þ o ð1Þ; as T ! 1: (A:2) is is ii ii i i T F Now, taking the maximum over i 2 ½N� and s 2 ½T�, we obtain � � 1 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ max jjβ β jj � max jj S L jj max jj X M ðsÞ ε jj: (A:3) ii ii i i is is fi2½N�;s2½T�g fi2½N�;s2½T�g fi2½N�;s2½T�g F � � ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Finally, noting that max jj S L jj ¼ Oð1Þ and max jj X M ðsÞ ε jj ¼ o ð1Þ ii ii i i fi2½N�;s2½T�g fi2½N�;s2½T�g as T ! 1, the result in the proposition follows. ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ� b b b b b Proof of Proposition 2. Let Y ¼ Y X β and Y ¼ ½Y ; . . . ; Y � be i i i 1 N is ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ defined as in the text and define also Y ¼ Y X β . It follows from (14) that i i i is 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ b b b b b b ðNTÞ F Y Y ¼ F V . Note also that Y ¼ F Λ þ e X , with X ¼ NT t t t tβ tβ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b ½X ðβ β Þ; . . . ; X ðβ β Þ� a 1� N vector. 1t 1s 1s Nt Ns Ns Then, 32 A. ATAK ET AL. 1 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� 1 ðsÞ b b b b b F F H ¼ F Y Y ½V � F H t t t q q q NT NT q¼1 T h ih i ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b ¼ F F Λ þ e X F Λ þ e X ½V � F H : s s q q q t t NT t qβ qβ NT q¼1 This expression can be decomposed as T h ih i ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b ¼ F F Λ þ e F Λ þ e ½V � F H (A:4) s s q q q t t t NT NT q¼1 h i ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 b b F F Λ þ e X ½V � (A:5) q q q qβ NT NT q¼1 T h i ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b F X F Λ þ e ½V � (A:6) q qβ t t NT NT q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b þ F X X ½V � : (A:7) qβ qβ NT NT q¼1 pffiffiffiffi 1=2 Theorem 3.1 in Su and Wang (2017) shows that expression (A.4) multiplied by Nk converges h;ts ðsÞ 1 0 1 ðsÞ 1 0 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ in distribution to Nð0; V Q Γ Q V Þ, where H ¼ ðN Λ Λ ÞðT F F Þ½V � ; V is the s st s s s s s s NT 1=2 1=2 diagonal matrix consisting of the eigenvalues of � � � in descending order; Γ is the F s Λ Λ s s 1=2 1=2 0 1 corresponding normalized eigenvector matrix such that Γ Γ ¼ I , and Q ¼ V Γ � . s R s s s s Λ pffiffiffiffi s 1=2 To complete the proof we need to show that the remaining terms multiplied by Nk are h;ts ðsÞ o ð1Þ as N; T ! 1, with h ! 0. First, we show that V ! V as N; T ! 1. To do this, we P s NT ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� b b b decompose the elements of the matrix V given by Y Y for i; j ¼ 1; . . . ; N. More i j NT NT formally, 1 1 ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ b b b b Y Y ¼ ½Y X ðβ β Þ�½Y X ðβ β Þ� i j i i is is j j js js NT NT ðsÞ ðsÞ b b þ X ðβ β Þðβ β Þ X ¼ A þ A þ A þ A : 1 2 3 4 i is is js js j NT 0 0 0 1 1 1 ðsÞ� ðsÞ� ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� 0 ðsÞ b b ¼ Y Y X ðβ β ÞY Y ðβ β Þ X i j i is is j i js js j NT NT NT From Proposition 1, it follows that max jjβ β jj ¼ o ð1Þ, as T ! 1. Then, A ! 0, for P j it it fi2½N�;s2½T�g ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ� ðsÞ� j ¼ 2; 3; 4, as N; T ! 1, such that V ¼ V þ o ð1Þ, with V ¼ Y Y as defined in the NT NT NT i j NT ðsÞ text below Equation 14. Then, it follows that V ¼ V þ o ð1Þ. Therefore, using Assumption A.3 s P NT (ii) we have inf V > 0. Then, we need to prove that s2½T� s h i pffiffiffiffi 0 1=2 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Nk F F Λ þ e X ¼ o ð1Þ: (A:8) s P h;ts q q q qβ NT q¼1 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 33 � � m ðqÞ m ðqÞ P P jt sj β q Λ q X F it is t is Note also that e ¼ ε þ d þ o , where d ¼ ðt sÞ þ ðt sÞ , for any it it it P it T T q! T q! q¼1 q¼1 fixed s; t 2 ½T�. Then, the expression on the left hand side of (A.8) satisfies that ! ! T T X X � � � � 1 1 1 1 1=2 1=2 ðsÞ 0 ðsÞ 0 b b pffiffiffiffi F k k F Λ þ ε X þpffiffiffiffi F k k F Λ þ d X þ o ð1Þ: h;qs q s q h;qs q s q P q h;ts qβ q h;ts qβ T T N N q¼1 q¼1 (A:9) Now, noting that X ¼ o ð1Þ, for q ¼ 1; . . . ; T, and applying the law of large numbers with qβ P N; T ! 1, we obtain condition (A.8). Applying the same arguments to expressions (A.6) and (A.7), we obtain the consistency of the ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ 1 0 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ local factors to rotated versions of F given by H ¼ ðN Λ Λ ÞðT F F ÞðV Þ . t s NT Proof of Proposition 3. The proof of this proposition follows from the proof of Proposition 1 and the application of the results in Song (2013) and Ando and Bai (2015) to local principal components. For each individual in the cross section, Equation 6 in vector form is ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Y ¼ X β þ F Λ þ e ; is i i i is and the OLS estimator of β is is 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ β ¼ ðX M X Þ X M Y ; (A:10) ðsÞ ðsÞ is i i i i b b F F such that 0 1 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ � � X M ðsÞ X X M ðsÞ h i pffiffiffiffiffiffi i i i pffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffi B b C b ðsÞ F F ðsÞ Th β β ¼ ThF Λ þ The : @ A is is is i T T Applying the results in the proof of Proposition 1, we have " # pffiffiffi � � h i N � � pffiffiffiffiffiffi X pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1 0 1 h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b Th β β ¼ S L Th β β þpffiffiffiffi X M ðsÞ e : i i is is iT iq;T is is q¼1 b b b We are interested in the asymptotic distribution of the entire vector β ¼ ðβ ; . . . ; β Þ . The above s 1s Ns equation implies, stacking over i " # pffiffiffi h i pffiffiffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1 h 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ b b Thðβ β Þ ¼ S L Thðβ β Þþpffiffiffiffi X M ðsÞ e ; s s T T s s ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ with S and L block-diagonal matrices with elements S and L . Then, T T iT iT pffiffiffi � � pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1 h 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ pffiffiffiffi S L Thðβ β Þ ¼ X M ðsÞ e ; T T s s T F such that 34 A. ATAK ET AL. pffiffiffi � � pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1 h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Thðβ β Þ ¼ S L pffiffiffiffi X M ðsÞ ε þ o ð1Þ; (A:11) s s T T � � jt sj given that e ¼ ε þ d þ o . Furthermore, from Proposition 2, we have that it it it P ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ F ¼ F H þ o ð1Þ. Then, 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðF H ÞðF H Þ ðsÞ ðsÞ H H ðsÞ ðsÞ M ðsÞ ¼ I F H ð Þ H F þ o ð1Þ ¼ I þ o ð1Þ ¼ M ðsÞ ðsÞ þ o ð1Þ T P T P P F H T T ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ F F , with H an orthogonal rotation matrix and ¼ I . Therefore, pffiffiffi pffiffiffi 0 0 h h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ pffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffi X M ðsÞ e ¼ X M ðsÞ ðsÞ ε þ o ð1Þ: i i i F H i T F T Now, using Assumption A.6, pffiffiffi h d ðsÞ ðsÞ pffiffiffiffi X M ε ! Nð0; � Þ; ðsÞ ðsÞ i F H i i h i T T P P h 0 with � ¼ lim k k E X M ðsÞ ðsÞ ε ε M ðsÞ ðsÞ X . ε h;ts h;τs it iτ iτ i it T F H F H t t τ τ T!1 t¼1 τ¼1 p p ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ Furthermore, each block S and L satisfies that S ! S and L ! L . Then, stacking iT iT iT ii iT ii ðsÞ ðsÞ over all the individuals, we define S and L block-diagonal matrices, such that it follows that pffiffiffiffiffiffi Thðβ β Þ! Nð0; � Þ; s s s � � � � 1 1 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ with � ¼ S L � S L . □ β ε Proof of Proposition 4. The proof of this result follows closely the proof of Theorem 3.2 ðsÞ� 1 ðsÞ b b b in Su and Wang (2017). It follows from (15) that Λ ¼ T F Y . Then, replacing in is this expression, we obtain ðsÞ� ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ^ ^ ^ Λ ¼ T F ½Y X ðβ β Þ�: (A:12) is i i is is Operating with this expression, we obtain 0 0 ðsÞ� ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b b Λ ¼ T F Y T F X ðβ β Þ; (A:13) is i i is is 0 0 0 ðsÞ� 1 ðsÞ 1=2 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ with T F Y ¼ ½H � Λ þ T H F ε þ o ððThÞ Þ. Under assumption A.3 iii), is P i i qffiffiffi ðsÞ h ðsÞ F ε ! Nð0; Ω Þ, with is " # T T 1 T P P P h 2 0 2 2h 0 Ω ¼ lim k EðF F ε Þþ k k EðF F ε ε Þ . Then, is q h;qs h;ts q iq it h;qs q iq t T T T!1 q¼1 q¼1 t¼qþ1 rffiffiffiffi h 0 0 ðsÞ 1 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ 0 H F ε ! Nð0;½Q � Ω ½Q � Þ: is s ðsÞ 1=2 1 ðsÞ b It remains to see that T F X ðβ β Þ ¼ o ððThÞ Þ as T ! 1. Using expression (A.11), i is is pffiffiffiffiffiffi and multiplying by Th, this expression can be rearranged as JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 35 pffiffiffi T T X X pffiffiffiffiffiffi h 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b b b pffiffiffiffi F X ðβ β Þ ¼ T F X Thðβ β Þ iq iq q iq iq q iq iq q¼1 q¼1 " # pffiffiffi � � T 1 0 0 1 h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ¼ T F X S L pffiffiffiffi X M ε þ o ð1Þ : ðsÞ q iq iT iT q q q¼1 Therefore, the right hand side of the expression is equal to " # pffiffiffi � � 1 T T X X 0 0 0 1 h ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 ðsÞ b b S L T F X pffiffiffiffi X M ε þ T F X o ð1Þ : ðsÞ iT iT q iq q q q iq q¼1 q¼1 T T P p P 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 1 ðsÞ 0 Under assumption A.4 iv), T F X ! lim T k E½H F X � ¼ Oð1Þ. This implies h;qs iq iq q T!1 q¼1 q¼1 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 1 that T F X o ð1Þ ¼ o ð1Þ. Furthermore, S L ! S L . Now we need to show q P P iq iT iT ii ii q¼1 T pffiffi 0 0 ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 h pffiffiffi that T F X X M ε ¼ o ð1Þ. To show this, from A.6, it follows that q q q ðsÞ P iq T F q¼1 � � pffiffi pffiffi ðsÞ ðsÞ h h pffiffiffi pffiffiffi X M ε ¼ z þ o , with z a zero-mean normal random variable with variance � . q ðsÞ q q P q ε T T ðsÞ ðsÞ Then, applying the law of large numbers and the law of iterated expectations to T F X z , q q iq q¼1 T T P p P ðsÞ ðsÞ 1 1 0 it follows that T F X z ! lim T k E½F X E½ε j F ; X ��. Finally, by assumption q q h;qs iq iq q iq iq q T!1 q¼1 q¼1 A.2 i), this quantity converges to zero in probability. Proof of Proposition 5. For convenience, we reproduce the analytical expression of the estimators: N N N � � X X X 0 0 � 1 b b b b b b b F ¼ Λ Λ Λ Y ¼ S Λ Y X β ; (A:14) it it it it it t it it it Λ;t N i¼1 i¼1 i¼1 1 0 b b where S ¼ N Λ Λ . Then, replacing in the expression, we obtain it i¼1 it Λ;t N N h i X X 1 1 0 1 � 1 b b b b b F ¼ S Λ Y S Λ X ðβ β Þ ;F þ F : (A:15) it it it a;t b;t t it it it b b Λ;t Λ;t N N i¼1 i¼1 The first term F has been analyzed in Su and Wang (2017) and satisfies that a;t 0 1 ðtÞ 0 1 ðtÞ 1 F H F ¼ S ½H � Λ ε þ o N : a;t it it p Λ;t N i¼1 1=2 Under assumption A3 i) S ¼ � þ OðN Þ as N ! 1, where � is an R� R diagonal Λ Λ s s Λ;t 1=2 0 matrix. Under assumption A.3 ii) it holds that N Λ ε ! Nð0; Γ Þ for each s; t, where t st pffiffiffiffi P P 0 N N 1 ðtÞ 0 Γ ¼ lim N Λ Λ E½ε ε �. Then, NðF H F Þ converges in distribution st N!1 is it jt a;t i¼1 j¼1 js t pffiffiffiffi 1 1 1 1 to Nð0; � Þ, with � ¼ ½� Q � Γ ½� Q �. Now, it remains to see that NF ! 0 as F F tt b;t t t Λ t Λ t t t N ! 0. To show this, note that 36 A. ATAK ET AL. pffiffiffiffi X b b NF ¼ S pffiffiffiffi Λ X ðβ β Þ (A:16) b;t it it it it Λ;t i¼1 � � 1 1 1 0 ðtÞ ðtÞ 1 ðtÞ ðtÞ pffiffiffiffi ¼ S Λ X S L X M ðtÞ ε þ o ð1Þ: (A:17) it it P iT iT Λ;t N T N F i¼1 0 p P 1 ðtÞ ðtÞ 0 By the law of large numbers, we have X M ðtÞ ε ! lim k E½X M ðtÞ ε �. Then, applying h;τt t t ðtÞ F H b τ T!1 τ¼1 1 ðtÞ the law of iterated expectations, under assumption A.2 (i), it follows that X M ðtÞ ε ¼ o ð1Þ as t P 1=2 T ! 1. Furthermore, noting that S ¼ � þ OðN Þ as N ! 1 and Λ;t ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ ðsÞ S L ! S L , we obtain the desired result. □ ii ii iT N iT Proof of Proposition 6. This proof is based on Theorem 1 of Cai and Xu (2008). The main difference is that we replace the observable covariates X by estimated common factors F such that the quantile factor model of interest is Y ¼ Z θ þ w ; (A:18) it it τ;it τ;it ðtÞ � with w ¼ ε ðF F H ÞΛ . τ;it τ;it t t τ;it Following Cai and Xu (2008), we consider a local polynomial expansion of the quantile parameters θ by θ . To simplify the proof, we consider a local linear approximation such τ;it τ;it h� �� � � �i 0 0 ð1Þ ð1Þ ð1Þ that θ ¼ a þ a ðu u Þ β þ β ðu u Þ Λ þ Λ ðu u Þ , that can be τ;it τ;is t s t s τ;is t s τ;is τ;is τ;is τ;is h i � 0 reparametrized as θ ¼ ðα þ α ðu u ÞÞ η þ η ðu u Þ ð� þ �ðu u ÞÞ , and mini- τ;it 0 1 t s t s 0 1 t s 0 1 mize the following local objective function: � � T � � u u t s ρ Y Z θ k : it it τ;it h t¼1 � � � � T T P P b b u u � 1ðY δ < Y < Y þδ Þ u u 1 0 t 1 it T it it T 0 t b b Let Ω ¼ Z Z k and Ω ¼ Z Z k , for some δ ! 0 as t t T T t T 2T t e e e e h h h h t¼1 t¼1 T ! 1; 1ð�Þ is an indicator function and Y is the prediction of the quantile model evaluated at u. it These sample covariance matrices are consistent estimators of Ω and Ω defined above. e b b b Furthermore, let U ¼ ðu u Þ=h, Z ¼ ½1 X F U X U F U �, t s it t th it th t th it th e e w ¼ Y Z θ , and D ¼ diagðI ; hI Þ, with I as the identity matrix of dimen- τ;it it it τ;it 1þdþR 1þdþR 1þdþR sion 1þ dþ R, and let qffiffiffiffiffiffi ð0Þ ð1Þ ð1Þ �ð 1Þ 0 � 0 0 0 γ ¼ Th D ½α a ðη β Þ ð� Λ Þ α a ðη β Þ ð� Λ Þ�: 0 τ;is 0 1 1 it 0 τ;is τ;is τ;is 1 τ;is τ;is The above minimization problem can be rewritten as � � ρ w pffiffiffiffiffiffi Z γ k U : (A:19) τ;it h τ it it th t¼1 Th Using the same steps as in Cai and Xu (2008), we derive a local Bahadur representation of b γ such it that JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS 37 � 1 T � � ½Ω � b γ ¼ pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðw ÞZ k U þ o ð1Þ τ τ;it P it it e e h th Th t¼1 with Ψ ðxÞ ¼ τ 1ðx< 0Þ. Now, after simple algebra, we decompose this expression in four terms as T � � b X ½Ω � pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε ÞZ k U (A:20) τ τ;it it e e h th Th t¼1 T � � � � b X ½Ω � � � þ pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε Þ Z Z k U (A:21) τ τ;it it it e e h th Th t¼1 � 1 � � � � ½Ω � � � þ pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðw Þ Ψ ðε Þ Z Z k U (A:22) τ τ;it τ τ;it it it e e h th Th t¼1 � 1 T � � b X ½Ω � pffiffiffiffiffiffi þ Ψ ðw Þ Ψ ðε Þ Z k U : (A:23) τ τ;it τ τ;it it e e h th Th t¼1 Under assumptions B.1-B.4, Cai and Xu (2008) show that expression (A.20) converges in dis- 1 1 � � tribution to Nð0; � Þ, with � ¼ τð1 τÞν ½Ω � Ω ½Ω � . In particular, to compute the asymp- τ τ 0 totic variance we rely on the α mixing condition B3 that limits the amount of serial dependence. More specifically, 1 h i E ðτ 1ðy � τ j Z ÞÞðτ 1ðy � τ j Z ÞÞZ Z ¼ it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼ 1 1 h i 0 2 0 τð1 τÞE½Z Z � 2τ E Z Z þ it it it i;tþs s¼1 1 h i 2 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z ÞZ Z : it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼1 The last term can be expressed as 1 1 h i h i X X 2 0 2 0 2 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ Z Z þ 2τ E Z Z : it it i;tþs i;tþs it it i;tþs i;tþs s¼1 s¼1 � � Now, noting that E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ j Z ¼ it it i;tþs i;tþs it � � E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ it it i;tþs i;tþs the above expression is 1 1 h i h i X X � �� 2 0 2 0 2 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ E Z Z þ 2τ E Z Z : it it i;tþs i;tþs it it i;tþs i;tþs s¼1 s¼1 Furthermore, applying Cauchy-Schwarz inequality to the first term, we have 38 A. ATAK ET AL. h i 2 0 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ Z Z � it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼1 1 1 h i X X � � 2 2 0 E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ E Z Z : it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼1 s¼1 Finally, using the α mixing condition on fZ ; ε g in B3, we obtain it it � � E 1ðy � τ j Z Þ1ðy � τ j Z Þ τ ! 0 it it i;tþs i;tþs s¼1 h i and E Z Z <1. Therefore, it s¼1 i;tþs 1 h i E ðτ 1ðy � τ j Z ÞÞðτ 1ðy � τ j Z ÞÞZ Z ¼ it it i;tþs i;tþs it i;tþs s¼ 1 1 h i 1 h i X X 0 2 0 2 0 τð1 τÞE½Z Z � 2τ E Z Z þ 2τ E Z Z ¼ τð1 τÞΩ: (A:24) it it it it i;tþs i;tþs s¼1 s¼1 The same derivations apply to Ω such that expression (A.20) converges to 1 1 � � τð1 τÞν ½Ω � Ω ½Ω � . For expression (A.21), we note that � 1 � � � � ½Ω � � � pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε Þ Z Z k U τ τ;it it it e e h th Th t¼1 � 1 h i � � ½Ω � ðtÞ ðtÞ b b ¼ pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε Þ 0 0 ðF F H Þ 0 0 ðF F H ÞU k U ; τ τ;it t t t t h e e th th Th t¼1 ðtÞ 1=2 with 0 denoting a 1� d vector. Now, using Proposition 5, F F H ¼ O N , as N ! 1. t t p pffiffiffiffi ðtÞ Define f ¼ NðF F H Þ. Then, t t t h i � � b X ½Ω � pffiffiffiffiffiffi Ψ ðε Þ 0 0 f 0 0 f U k U ; pffiffiffiffi τ it t t e e e th h th N Th t¼1 that converges to zero in probability as N; T ! 1. To show this, consider the element sffiffiffiffiffiffi T � � 1 T � � b X e X ½Ω � Th½Ω � pffiffiffiffiffiffi k U Ψ ðε Þf ¼ k U Ψ ðε Þf þ o ð1Þ: τ it t τ it t P pffiffiffiffi e e e e h th h th N e Th N Th t¼1 t¼1 � � Under the law of large numbers, it follows that k U Ψ ðε Þf ¼ O ð1Þ. Then, the above τ it t P e e h th Th t¼1 Th expression converges to zero if ! 0. ðtÞ � � b b Now, the consistency of F to F H , as N ! 1, implies that Z Z ¼ o ð1Þ and t t P it it w ε ¼ o ð1Þ. Then, expressions (A.22) and (A.23) converge to zero in probability, and τ;it τ;it P the asymptotic result in Proposition 6 follows. □

Journal

Journal of Applied EconomicsTaylor & Francis

Published: Dec 31, 2023

Keywords: Quantile factor model; time-varying factor loadings; partially linear regression model; panel data

References