Get 20M+ Full-Text Papers For Less Than $1.50/day. Start a 14-Day Trial for You or Your Team.

Learn More →

Labor Market Performance of Latin American and Caribbean Immigrants in Spain

Labor Market Performance of Latin American and Caribbean Immigrants in Spain jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 233 Journal of Applied Economics. Vol XIII, No. 2 (November 2010), 233-261 LABOR MARKET PERFORMANCE OF LATIN AMERICAN AND CARIBBEAN IMMIGRANTS IN SPAIN José Ignacio Antón*, Rafael Muñoz de Bustillo and Miguel Carrera University of Salamanca Submitted May 2009; accepted May 2010 This paper analyzes the wage differentials in Spain between local and foreign employees from Latin America and the Caribbean. It also explores the earnings gap between Latin American employees and other groups of foreign workers from both developing and developed countries. The study is based on the Wage Structure Survey 2006, which is the first nationally representative sample of both foreign and Spanish employees. Using the Machado-Mata econometric procedure, earnings differentials across the whole wage distribution are decomposed into a component related to observable characteristics and another associated to different returns to such endowments. First, we find that, in absolute terms, the earnings differential between Latin American and Caribbean immigrants and natives that is not explained by observable characteristics increases across the wage distribution. While the large gap at the top might be mainly explained by problems of transferability of skills among immigrants, the low differential at the bottom is likely to be related to the compressive effect exerted by labor market institutions such as the minimum wage and collective agreements. A quite similar pattern is observed when they are compared with developed countries´ workers. Secondly, there does not seem to be a significant wage gap between Latin American and the rest of foreign employees from developing countries, possibly because immigrants are largely employed in low-skill jobs where Spanish proficiency is not an essential asset. JEL classification codes: J71, F22 Key words: immigration, wage differentials, Latin America, Spain, quantile regression * José-Ignacio Antón (corresponding autor): Departamento de Economía Aplicada, Campus Unamuno, 37007 Salamanca, Spain, janton@usal.es. Rafael Muñoz de Bustillo: bustillo@usal.es. Miguel Carrera: mcarrera@usal.es. A previous version of this paper was presented at the Seminar Series of the Institute of Global Studies of the University of Gothenburg (Sweden) in April 2009. We thank two anonymous referees and the editor for their helpful comments, which have contributed to substantially improve this work. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 234 Journal of Applied Economics I. Introduction th Migration flows between America and Spain since the 16 century clearly illustrate how paradoxical history might be. When some Latin American and Caribbean countries were hosting thousands of Spaniards at the beginning and in the middle of the last century -among them, some of the most renowned Spanish intellectuals in history-, few people could even imagine that the situation would be exactly the opposite at the st beginning of the 21 century, with almost 2 million Latin American and Caribbean people (more than one third of Spain’s foreign population) migrated to Spain in search of better economic opportunities. In many cases, these migrants were descendents th of Spanish exiles or economic migrants to America in the 20 century. The aim of this paper is to assess how these Latin American and Caribbean immigrants fare in the Spanish labor market compared to both native-born employees and other foreign workers, particularly in terms of earnings. This topic is important for several reasons. First of all, labor market performance of Latin American and Caribbean immigrants has not received much attention outside the United States. Second, apart from the existence of a common language and shared cultural values, the interest of the Spanish case derives not only from the impressive increase in immigration flows experienced by the country during the last decade, but also from the Spaniards’ surprisingly negative attitudes towards immigrants according to opinion polls. For example, in 2006, in a period of economic boom, Spaniards considered immigration as the most important problem faced by the country, well above unemployment and housing (CIS 2006). In addition, most studies on earnings differentials between immigrants and locals are focused on Anglo-Saxon and Nordic countries, as well as Central Europe and Benelux, which have been the main host countries in the OECD until recently. In 1950 the GDP per capita of Argentina and Uruguay was twice that of Spain, while the Venezuelan per person income was three times higher than the Spanish one (Maddison 2001). It is worth mentioning that according to sociological surveys (CIS 2003), Spaniards tend to exhibit several prejudices against Latin American migrants. For example, 45% of Spaniards interviewed in 2003 by the Spanish Center of Sociological Research, when asked about what characteristics best define Latin American and Caribbean People, answered that Latin Americans were authoritarian (rather than democratic); 26% of surveyed locals described them as lazy (rather than industrious) and 57%, as conservative people (rather than progressive). In addition, according to the Eurobarometer 71.2, an opinion survey carried out by the European Union authorities, 66% of Spaniards thought that discrimination on grounds of ethnic origin (which in Spain is almost a synonym of immigration from developing countries) is fairly widespread or very widespread in the country in 2009 (European Commission 2009). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 235 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants With that objective, we use a recently released earnings survey containing, for the first time, sufficient observations from immigrants. Using the Machado-Mata econometric decomposition (Machado and Mata 2005), we split the earnings gaps between Latin American employees and other workers across the whole wage distribution into a first component associated with observable endowments and a second one capturing the differential unexplained by these observable socio- demographic characteristics (or, in other words, the differential returns to such endowments). We find that, once human capital endowments are controlled for, the earnings gap between Latin Americans and both Spaniards and foreign workers from developed countries increases across the wage distribution, while there is no substantial earnings gap between employees from Latin America and the Caribbean and other workers from developing countries. The rest of the article is organized in four parts as follows. In Section II, we present the literature review and a brief historical background of immigration flows. Section III provides a description of the methodology and the database used in the paper. Our results are discussed in Section IV, while the last section summarizes and discusses the main findings of the research. II. Literature review and historical background Though immigration and the labor market is a popular area of economic research, most such work has focused on world migration as a whole or on specific countries, such as the United States, Germany, Canada or Sweden, which have often provided academics with large and comprehensive datasets. To our knowledge, Latin American and Caribbean immigration has received scant attention outside the United States, where, among others, the studies of Gammage and Schmitt (2004) and Rivera-Batiz (2007) can be highlighted. The former finds substantial earnings differentials between male and female Central American migrants, while the latter analyzes average wage gaps between Latin American and native-born workers. There is plenty of evidence suggesting the existence of wage differentials between locals and migrants once we control for observable characteristics in international case studies, although there is no consistent pattern across countries. For example, the pay disadvantage faced by foreign-born workers is concentrated mainly at the bottom of earnings distribution in Sweden according to Hammarstedt and Shukur (2006 and 2007) But it is roughly constant according to Albrecht, Björklund and Vroman (2003). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 236 Journal of Applied Economics and the U.K. (Hunt 2008), while it increases along with wages in the U.S. and Australia (Chiswick, Le and Miller 2008). Apart from the role of human capital stocks, there are several reasons that can contribute to explain the earnings gap between migrants and natives. First, the main source of these differentials might be associated with the limited transferability of immigrants’ skills, that is, education and training acquired abroad would not be recognized in the same way in the host country. This fact would result in occupational segregation and higher levels of over-education among foreign workers than among natives (Chiswick and Miller, 2008 and 2009). The recent work of Sanromà, Ramos and Simón (2009) for Spain, which find that human capital acquired in the host country yields higher returns than those accumulated in the country of origin, also supports such a statement. This factor might be also linked to the existence of differences in the quality of education or the absence of information on this issue for employers. If this argument applies, the immigrant-native wage gap at the top of the wage distribution should be larger than at the bottom since the jobs associated with the higher part of the earnings distribution usually demand higher qualifications. A second broad group of explanations for the existence of different returns to endowments comes from the theories of labor market discrimination or, in more general terms, differential treatment by employers. Their point of departure is Becker’s (1957) view based on employer’s tastes: some employers dislike people from other ethnic groups (modeled as a utility loss derived from hiring them) and, in competitive labor markets, if the share of prejudiced employers is sufficiently large, foreign workers might earn a lower wage than locals. Theories of statistical discrimination also offer a framework for understanding the existence of wage gaps between natives and immigrants based on the lack of information or informational asymmetries (Arrow 1973; Phelps 1972). If there is no perfect information on certain characteristics of immigrants (for example, quality of education) or firms have less knowledge of them, employers will tend to base their hiring and pay decisions on the observable characteristics of the workers, like the ethnic group they belong to. For example, it is worth mentioning that in the Spanish rental housing market, there is evidence that, ceteris paribus, migrants receive a differential treatment by landlords (Bosch, Carnero and Farré 2009). In the case of Spain, where immigrants from developing countries represent the exception in an otherwise ethnically homogenous society, the hypothesis of discrimination based on racial issues might have some room. See Arrow (1998) for a comprehensive and didactic review. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 237 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Another interesting and more recent perspective of looking at this issue is the idea of monopsonistic discrimination, inspired by Joan Robinson’s (1933) work on imperfect markets. Drawing on the idea of dynamic labor market monopsony, it is argued that workers’ labor supply to the firm (different from the labor supply to the market) might not be completely elastic because of job search frictions, heterogeneous preferences among workers or mobility costs (Burdett and Mortensen 1998). In this context, if it differs across groups, a profit-maximizing employer can exploit this fact by paying less to the group with the lower labor supply elasticity for the firm, other things being equal. There is a growing body of empirical literature showing the potential of this approach in explaining the lower wages received by women (Mannning 2003, and Barth and Dale-Olsen 2009), Afro-American workers (Raphael and Riker 1999) and undocumented employees (Hotchkiss and Quispe-Agnoli 2009). Considering that Spanish immigrants might have lower reservation wages (for instance, because of a lower access to contributory unemployment benefits based on previous labor market experience) and the excess of labor supply that has characterized the national labor market for many years, monopsonistic discrimination might play a role in explaining the existence of wage differentials between migrants and locals in Spain. Regarding the historical background of immigration in Spain, although this country was traditionally a country of emigrants (Latin American and Caribbean countries being their main hosts), since the middle 90s, in barely a decade, Spain has become one of the largest recipient countries of the European continent. The explosion of Latin American emigration to Spain is basically linked to the poor economic performance in Latin America in that period (often referred as the “lost half-decade”) and to the remarkable economic recovery from the 1992-1993 world economic crisis in Spain. Those two factors, together with a shared language and cultural values, definitely played an important role in explaining how migration th flowed in the opposite direction of what it was until the middle of the 20 century. In fact, the proportion of population born abroad rose from less than 2% in 1996 to roughly 12% in 2008, which made Spain the country undergoing the third largest increase in non-native population in the European Union (EU) during the last decade, after Greece and Ireland (Eurostat 2006). According to OECD statistics, nowadays the unemployment rate in Spain is the highest in the European st Union (20% in the 1 quarter 2010) and was 8.5% in 2006. Furthermore, the proportion of over-qualified workers is remarkably high, as around 35% of males and 40% of females reported having jobs where their skills were underutilized (Budría and Moro 2006). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 238 Journal of Applied Economics In terms of Latin American and Caribbean immigrants, the figures are even more impressive, since according to OECD and Eurostat data, in 2008 two out of three foreigners from Latin American and Caribbean countries living in a country of the European Union were located in Spain. As a result, according to the 2009 Local Population Register, 1,800,000 Latin American and Caribbean people presently live in Spain, accounting for almost one out of three foreigners living in this country. The most extensively represented countries among Latin American and Caribbean immigrants in Spain are Ecuador (21%), Colombia (16%), Bolivia and Argentina (both around 10% of total Latin American migrants). In spite of this relative novelty of immigration flows to Spain, there is some literature dealing with the labor market integration of foreign workers, although without making any distinction by nationality. The pioneering work of Dolado, Jimeno and Duce (1997) points out a negligible effect of migration on labor market outcomes at the beginning of the nineties, when the intensity of immigrations flows was very low. More recent research exploiting several data sources –among others, the Spanish Wage Structure Survey 2002, which does not offer coverage of small firms– reports similar findings for the second half of the nineties (Carrasco, Jimeno and Ortega 2008). Other researchers have focused on employment outcomes and occupational segregation of foreign workers, documenting different patterns of labor market integration among foreign-born workers depending both on socio- economic characteristics and country of origin (Amuedo-Dorantes and De la Rica 2007; Simón, Sanromá and Ramos 2008). These relatively poor employment outcomes, however, tend to eventually improve with the years of residence in Spain (Fernández and Ortega 2008). Finally, the work of Canal-Domínguez and Rodríguez- Gutiérrez (2008) aims to study wage differences between natives and foreigners in Spain, finds a substantial pay gap not explained by observable characteristics and which does not rise across the wage distribution, as in the case of highly educated women –the so-called glass ceiling phenomenon- (De la Rica, Dolado and Llorens 2008). This paper is the first one to specifically address the study of wage differentials faced by Latin American and Caribbean immigrants in the Spanish labour market. Furthermore, it includes several additional insights with respect to previous works on Spanish immigration commented above. This work is based on the Wage Structure Survey 2006, which, as it is explained in Section III, is more appropriate to carry out this sort of study than those used in previous works. In addition, we compute standard errors for wage differentials across the earnings distribution that allows determining if such gaps are statistically significant. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 239 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants III. Empirical strategy and data A. Data Previous studies of immigrant-native wage differentials have been constrained by serious data limitations, which, to some extent, are linked to the novelty of the immigration phenomenon in Spain. However, it should not be neglected that Spain is a step behind other OECD countries regarding data sources for analyzing labor market and social outcomes. This work is based on the Wage Structure Survey 2006 (WSS), released by the Spanish National Statistics Institute in December 2008. The WSS has several advantages over previous databases. Firstly, while neither the European Community Household Panel nor the Social Statistics on Living Conditions or SILC (the household surveys containing information on labor income from the middle- nineties), provide a large enough and representative sample of foreign workers, the WSS includes a sample of local and foreign-born employees representative at national level and whose size can be considered appropriate for analysing foreigners’ outcomes in isolation. For example, we have more than 10,000 employees born outside the EU, a sample size higher than the whole SILC. In addition, the WSS is based on administrative registers of employers, which is likely to increase the reliability of wage data. Secondly, the WSS 2006 overcomes the evident limitations of the previous wave of the survey, carried out in 2002. The WSS 2002 only contains information on workplaces with ten or more employees, an important shortcoming considering the undeniable relevance of small firms in Spain, where, according to the 2007 Observatory of European Small and Medium Enterprises Survey, more than 40% of total salaried workers are employed in firms with less than ten workers, being one of the countries where small and medium enterprises account for a largest share of employment in the European Union. This shortcoming might be especially problematic, since, according to data from the 2006 SILC, foreign workers are over-represented in small firms: while roughly 40% of native employees work in enterprises with ten or less employees, the proportion of immigrants in these types of firms is above 55%. Therefore, it is possible there is a selection bias, which, if based on unobservable characteristics or observable covariates not included in Details on sample design and questionnaires can be found at the website of the Spanish National Statistics Institute. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 240 Journal of Applied Economics econometric analyses of wages, will lead to inconsistent estimation of the effect of human capital endowments on wages. We limit our analyses to men between 25 and 55 years old for two different reasons. The first one is related to the double negative effect faced by foreign women in their double condition as females and immigrants. Second, as our database only contains information on employees (not considering unemployed or self-employed population), there is likely to be some selection bias based on unobservable characteristics. By restricting our analysis to the group with higher employment rates (males), we try to minimize this bias. A final point that requires some discussion is the definition of immigrant. The common approach in the economic literature is, when possible, to consider as immigrants those born abroad, since naturalization rules can differ depending on the country of birth because of the existence of special agreements with former colonies and so on. This is, for example, the case of most Latin American workers living in Spain. Unfortunately, this variable is not available in our database, so we have to use citizenship as a proxy for immigrant status. Fortunately, this issue does not have relevant implications in the Spanish case for several reasons. First, immigration in Spain is quite recent and has been concentrated in the last few years, which means that only a limited share of immigrants could have obtained the Spanish citizenship. Second, naturalization does not imply losing the first nationality in the case of Latin American immigrants, as there are international agreements allowing people from that region to have a double nationality. Third, using the micro-data of the Spanish Labor Force Survey from 2006 nd (2 quarter), which contains information on both country of birth and nationality (but not wages), the correlation among the working age population between having a foreign nationality and being born abroad is above 90%. The focus of the paper is on how Latin American and Caribbean immigrants fare in terms of earnings with respect to locals in Spain. Nevertheless, we also compare them with two other groups of foreigners. First, we contrast Latin Americans to those foreigners from geographical regions that on average have a lower level of development than Spain (European countries not belonging the EU-25, Oceania, Asia and Africa). Then, in order to study the specificity of the results found for Latin Americans, we also consider those workers coming from developed countries (among which EU-25 citizens mean 95% of total immigrants). In the European Union, natives tend to associate the concept of migrant with people from poorer This issue has been documented and studied by, among others, Beach and Worswick (1993), Shamsuddin (1998) and Kim (2002). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 241 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants countries, not from other rich EU members, whose citizens resemble nationals very much (Brücker et al. 2002). Actually, this second group includes a high share of retirees looking for a milder climate and a relevant presence of expatriates with a relatively very high qualifications and standard of life (they may receive pluses in their salaries due to their status as expatriates) from the myriad EU multinationals in Spain. Those predominantly Caucasian retirees and workers from EU countries are very far from the common image in Spain of an immigrant. Our sample comprises almost 98,000 observations, of which around 90,000 correspond to Spaniards and approximately 7,900 to foreign workers, with nearly 2,700 employees with citizenship of a Latin American or Caribbean country, roughly 3,500 from other developing countries and around 1,600 from developed countries. B. The Machado-Mata decomposition The seminal contributions made by Oaxaca (1973) and Blinder (1973) propose a relatively simple econometric technique to decompose the average gap into a component related to observable endowments and another one associated with differences in returns to observed characteristics. The main shortcoming of this approach is related to the fact that the gap in a certain outcome between two groups is likely not to be constant across the whole distribution of such outcome. For example, a null mean gap can be simply the average of large gaps of different signs at the tails, which obviously have very different policy implications than the absence of such gap. Several approaches have been proposed to address this issue and compute the gaps conditioned on observable characteristics across the whole wage distribution. We follow the approach firstly proposed by Machado and Mata (2005), though we apply their method following the slightly modified but equivalent version suggested by Albrecht, Björklund and Vroman (2003) and De la Rica, Dolado and Llorens (2008). The basic idea is to construct the counterfactual immigrant’s wage distribution that would exist in the hypothetical case that immigrants’ characteristics were remunerated exactly with the returns locals get for their endowments. In more detail, the procedure unfolds as follows: Other ways of analyzing unexplained wage gaps across the whole distribution have been proposed by DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux (1996), based on semiparametric estimation methods, and Gardeazábal and Ugidos (2005) and Melly (2006) using quantile regression. We evaluate the gap at natives’ coefficients, as De la Rica, Dolado and Llorens (2008) do when they address gender discrimination. On the contrary, Albrecht, Björklund and Vroman (2003) use the potentially jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 242 Journal of Applied Economics (1) Estimate quantile regressions for 99 percentiles using the native-born employees’ dataset. (2) For each quantile, take a draw from the locals’ sample and compute the predicted n n log wage for native-born employees at each quantile q, i.e., x b (q). Repeat the m n process for the immigrants’ database, calculating the predicted log wage x b (q). (3) Repeat step (2) M times and, in this way, obtain a counterfactual distribution of immigrants that reflects their remunerations as if they were paid as locals and the predicted distribution of immigrants retaining their characteristics and specific returns. Following Albrecht, van Vuuren and Vroman (2009), M is set to 100. (4) Profiting from the linearity of quantile regression, calculate the counterfactual m n m m gap, that is, the wage differential associated with coefficients, as x b (q) - x b (q). One task seldom addressed in Spanish literature is the computation of standard errors or interval confidence for the counterfactual gap, a non-negligible issue in order to test if gaps at different quantiles are significantly different from zero. Two different ways have been proposed in the literature: bootstrapping or deriving an asymptotic expression for the covariance matrix (Albrecht, van Vuuren and Vroman, 2009). To compute bootstrapped standard errors with large samples might be computationally cumbersome, so we have used the latter procedure, which, as far as we know has only been implemented by Albrecht and his co-authors. The relevant issue here is to compute the variance of the difference between the predicted quantiles of the unconditional counterfactual distributions. According to Albrecht, Van Vueren and Vroman (2009), the variance of θθ ()qq − () is given by mn m ⎧⎧ ⎫ 1 qq () 1 − q(1 1 − q) qq () 1 − Var[] θθ () q−= () q ⎨ + − 2 ⎬ . (1) mn m 2 2 99 M ⎪ fq θ () fq θ () fq[]θθ ()f[ ()q] ⎪ [] [] ⎩ mn mn m m ⎭ nn mn mm This variance can be consistently estimated using the predicted quantiles, θ (q) mm mn == xb () q and θ () q xb () q –which Albrecht and his co-authors prove to be mn discriminated group (in their work, women) as the reference group. Using this alternative assumption, we obtained qualitatively similar results. Estimates are available from the authors on request. We applied a slightly modified version of Machado-Mata’s method, as they take random draws from a uniform distribution between 0 and 1. Both approaches are equivalent in large samples. De la Rica, Dolado and Llorens’s (2008) work is a remarkable exception to this trend. For example, with our database, it took us more than two hours to run the model in Stata once. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 243 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants consistent estimators of the true quantiles θ (q) and θ (q)– and estimating by kernel m mn density f (·) and f (·), which represents the density functions of the counterfactual mn m distributions evaluated at each percentile. Obviously, the population density functions are not known; however, as long as the sample is large, it is possible to estimate them using kernel density methods. Note that standard errors for the difference ˆ ˆ between θθ ()qq and () will be larger, since they are not correlated and, hence, mn the covariance is null. The procedure described above allows us to compute not only the estimated gap at each quantile, but also to determine if those differentials are statistically significant. Regarding quantile regressions, following Koenker (2005), the model to be estimated can be expressed in the following way: Yq ()=+ xβε () q () q , (2) where Y denotes monthly gross wages (in logs), x includes a set of employee’s observable characteristics, β(q) is the parameter to be estimated, which captures th the proportional wage change in the q quantile conditional on x and ε (q)is a disturbance satisfying E (ε (q) | x) = 0. Therefore, one can write conditional population quantiles Quant (Y | X = x) as Quant (| Y X== x) xβ(q). (3) The β can be consistently estimated by minimizing the sum of weighted absolute deviations using q and 1-q as weighting factors for positive and negative errors, respectively. Finally, the set of covariates includes age, squared age, education, tenure, firm size, dummies for sector of activity of the firm and regional dummies. For comparative purposes, we also perform the standard Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition of differences in mean wages. Taking Spaniards as the reference group, the mean wage gap can be expressed as follows: nm nnmmnnmnm nm m Y −= Y x b − xb = x b − xb + xb − xb , (4) ()() OLS OLS OLS OLS O OLS OLS where b denotes the Ordinary Least Squares coefficients. The second term in the OLS parenthesis captures the differences in mean wages not explained by observable characteristics. Particularly, we use a Gaussian kernel and the optimal bandwidth suggested by Silverman (1986). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 244 Journal of Applied Economics We proceed in two steps: first, we analyze the wage differentials between native and Latin American and Caribbean employees; second, we determine if there is a significant gap between Latin American and Caribbean and other immigrant’s earnings, considering the latter as the reference group. IV. Results A. Descriptive statistics The main descriptive statistics of the sample used in the analysis are reproduced in Table 1. They basically indicate that foreign employees are not a homogeneous set. Immigrants from Latin America and the Caribbean receive wages substantially lower than locals and foreigners from developed countries, while the gap with respect to other immigrants from developing countries is very narrow. They are younger and have lower human capital stocks –educational level and tenure- than nationals. In addition, compared to local employees, they tend to concentrate more in small and medium-size firms than local employees. Regarding differences between Latin American and Caribbean employees and other foreigners from developing countries, the most relevant one refers to schooling, showing the former a higher educational level than the latter. It is also worth mentioning that the proportion of foreign workers from developed countries who hold a university degree is three times higher than among Latin American and Caribbean workers and even larger than among local ones. This large percentage of highly educated people might be associated with the presence of foreigners from developed countries in managerial positions, which are usually referred as expatriates rather than migrants. B. Econometric results th th th th th Selected quantile regressions (at the 10 , 25 , 50 , 75 and 90 percentiles) and OLS estimates for Spaniards, Latin American and Caribbean immigrants, other immigrants from developing countries and foreign workers from developed countries are presented, for simplicity, in Tables A1-A4 of the Appendix respectively. Here, we focus on the estimates of the wage gap associated with differences in returns, which are computed following the method described above and presented in Table 2 and Figures 1, 2 and 3. These figures also show both the raw and counterfactual mean gap obtained using the Oaxaca-Blinder approach. The counterfactual gap is significantly different from zero across the whole jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 245 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table 1. Descriptive statistics Spanish employees Latin American Other foreign employees Other foreign employees and Caribbean employees from developing countries from developed countries Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation Hourly gross wage 11.96 8.07 8.35 4.97 8.24 4.87 12.25 10.85 (euros) Hourly gross wage (in 2.34 0.51 2.03 0.40 2.02 0.39 2.30 0.58 logs) Age 38.48 8.42 36.13 7.46 35.76 7.15 37.35 7.93 Education Less than primary 0.0673 0.2505 0.1618 0.3684 0.2404 0.4274 0.1161 0.3205 education Primary education 0.1955 0.3966 0.3460 0.4758 0.3697 0.4828 0.2598 0.4386 Lower secondary 0.2892 0.4534 0.2679 0.4429 0.2593 0.4383 0.1993 0.3996 education Upper secondary 0.2558 0.4363 0.1458 0.3530 0.0890 0.2847 0.1858 0.3891 education University 0.1922 0.3940 0.0785 0.2690 0.0417 0.1999 0.2390 0.4266 Tenure 7.15 8.20 1.49 1.90 1.72 2.75 2.48 3.84 Firm size Less than 50 0.5874 0.4923 0.5714 0.4950 0.5898 0.4919 0.4853 0.4999 employees Between 50 and 199 0.1891 0.3916 0.2567 0.4369 0.2835 0.4508 0.3246 0.4684 employees 200 employees or 0.2235 0.4166 0.1719 0.3773 0.1267 0.3327 0.1901 0.3925 more Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 246 Journal of Applied Economics distribution in all cases. In general terms, our results point out three stylized facts. First, the existence of increasing wage differentials between Spanish and Latin American and Caribbean employees across the distribution conditioned on endowments; pointing to the presence of a sort of glass ceiling similar to those described for female workers (Figure 1). Although all the theoretical explanations suggested in Section II might have some role in accounting for the existence of earnings differentials between migrants and locals, this particular pattern –a gap that grows across the wage distribution- deserves further comment. On the one hand, the increase in the gap across the distribution might respond to a limited transferability of skills acquired in the country of origin, a circumstance that is more likely to appear the higher the skill level required for a job. If a certain job at the bottom of the distribution demands very basic skills, it is quite likely that the possibility of non-transferability will be very remote and the opposite applies to the top of the earnings distribution. Particularly, the research work of Sanromà, Ramos and Simón (2009) documents well how schooling levels obtained abroad are not as profitable as human capital acquired in Spain and also that their work experience at home is not valued as it would have been if they had been acquired in the host country. In contrast, at the bottom, the gap is very small, which might be explained by the effect of the existing labor market institutions. Among them is the potential role played by the national statutory minimum wage. This tool would act as a lower wage limit, a floor irrespectively of other considerations. Those workers with almost no qualifications Figure 1. Wage gaps between Spanish and Latin American and Caribbean employees in Spain (2006) 0,6 0,5 0,4 0,3 0,2 0,1 0,0 0 10203040 5060 70 80 90 100 Percentile Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw mean gap Counterfactual mean gap Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. Log wage gap jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 247 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table 2. Estimated raw and counterfactual wage gaps by percentile Percentile Spanish – Latin American and Latin American and Caribbean – other foreign Foreign employees from developed countries – Caribbean employees employees from developing countries Latin American and Caribbean employees Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw gap Counterfactual gap *** *** *** *** th 10 0.1227 0.0206 0.0041 -0.0002 0.0601 0.0640 (0.0071) (0.0004) (0.0058) (0.0003) (0.0070) (0.0012) th *** *** *** *** *** *** 25 0.1939 0.0514 0.0106 0.0108 0.1212 0.1082 (0.0066) (0.0010) (0.0047) (0.0002) (0.0062) (0.0009) th *** *** *** *** *** 50 0.3204 0.1121 0.0059 0.0065 0.2364 0.1487 (0.0072) (0.0015) (0.0052) (0.0001) (0.0076) (0.0009) *** *** *** *** *** th 75 0.4324 0.1852 -0.0055 0.0049 0.4198 0.2154 (0.0097) (0.0017) (0.0085) (0.0002) (0.0119) (0.0015) th *** *** *** *** *** 90 0.4763 0.2312 -0.0175 -0.0235 0.5344 0.2725 (0.0143) (0.0002) (0.0132) (0.0007) (0.0161) (0.0013) *** *** *** *** Mean gap (OLS) 0.3102 0.1089 -0.0024 -0.0023 0.2766 0.1994 (0.0080) (0.0078) 0.0054 (0.0102) (0.0163) (0.0169) *** ** * Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 248 Journal of Applied Economics would be pushed up in terms of wage in comparison to the wage they would receive in the absence of a minimum wage. It is worth mentioning that the minimum wage has been rising considerably in Spain since 2004. For example, in real terms, it was raised by more than 10% between 2004 and 2006 and by more than 20% from 2004 to 2009, reaching 633 euros a month in 2010 (21 euros a day). Collective bargaining agreements, which cover both unionized and non-unionized workers in Spain, could have a similar effect at the former part of the distribution by setting wage floors in some sectors of activity higher than the national minimum wage. These elements of the institutional framework might be contributing to the existence of a lower gap at the bottom by imposing minimum earnings thresholds. Although the remunerations set by the minimum wage and collective agreements also affect native men, the higher concentration of immigrant men from developing countries at the lower-end of the wage distribution allows this group to profit more from the effects of these institutions. In the second place, when Latin American and Caribbean workers are compared to other foreigners from developing countries, both raw and counterfactual wage gaps are tiny (Figure 2), suggesting that they experience quite similar difficulties in the Spanish labor market, Spanish language proficiency not meaning a significant advantage in terms of earnings. This can be linked to the fact that most immigrants are employed in low-skill jobs. Lastly, we compare the wage gap between Latin American and Caribbean employees and foreigners from developed countries, which, as mentioned, are essentially citizens from other rich EU countries (Figure 3). The raw mean gap is quite similar to the differential found with respect to Spaniards but the counterfactual mean gap is almost twice. As in Figure 1, the counterfactual differential increases across the wage distribution and is even larger than in the comparison with natives. In fact, if we compare locals and this group of workers from developed countries we find that, other things being equal, they are paid roughly as nationals up to the th 70 percentile but they receive higher wages than them at the top of the earnings distribution. This pattern is consistent with the interpretation of the most skilled part of this group as expatriate workers. This result is coherent with the finding of Saint-Paul (2008), who reports the existence of a positive wage premium for European-born workers in the United States, a result probably driven by unobservable differences in the quality of education. The results derived from the comparison between local and foreign workers from developed countries can be directly inferred from looking at Figures 1 and 3. Nevertheless, detailed results, not included here for brevity, are available from the authors upon request. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 249 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Figure 2. Wage gaps between Latin American and Caribbean and other foreign employees from developing countries in Spain (2006) 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0 102030405060708090 100 -0.1 Percentile Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw mean gap Counterfactual mean gap Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. Figure 3. Wage gaps between Latin American and Caribbean and foreign employees from developed countries in Spain (2006) 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0 102030405060708090 100 0.1 Percentile Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw mean gap Counterfactual mean gap Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. Log wage gap Log wage gap jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 250 Journal of Applied Economics In order to do some robustness checks, we have repeated the analysis using hourly gross wages excluding bonuses and gross monthly wages. The results reported above hold for these alternative definitions of the dependent variable, also pointing to the existing of a wage penalty with respect to nationals for Latin American and Caribbean immigrants that is not explained by human capital endowments and that increases across the earnings distribution. These results are available from the authors upon request. V. Conclusions Latin American and Caribbean immigration has become an increasingly important phenomenon in Spain, a country of emigrants until not so long ago. In this paper, we have analyzed the native-immigrant wage gap across the whole distribution using the M-M decomposition. The main contribution of the paper has been to address this issue for the first time using a representative survey of the employed population. In addition, standard errors for counterfactual gaps have been estimated, a task not addressed by previous research on the topic in Spain or in most other national case studies. There are three main findings in this paper. First, the existence of an important glass ceiling for Latin Americans and Caribbeans living in Spain, that is, a wage gap that significantly grows across the earnings distribution. This pattern is consistent with the effect of labor market institutions (mainly minimum wages and collective agreements) at the bottom and the consequences of the eventually limited transferability of human capital accumulated in the country of origin and the existence of obstacles for migrants in accessing high occupational levels. Second, there are no important differences between wages earned by Latin American and Caribbean workers and other foreign employees from developing countries, which suggests that proficiency in Spanish might not be a very valuable asset in the labor market for foreigners, as long as they are employed in low-skill jobs. Finally, when compared to EU-25-born workers, Latin American and Caribbean employees face a similar earnings disadvantage when compared to locals, the gap being even larger at the top. It is well-documented that immigrants are usually employed in jobs involving harder tasks or worse working conditions (Orrenious and Zavodny 2009), which can contribute to the reduction of observed wage gaps if the principle of compensating differentials (at least partially) applies and detailed information on job characteristics is not available for researchers. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 251 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Appendix Table A1. OLS and quantile regression estimates for male Spanish employees (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 *** *** *** *** *** *** Age 0.045 0.029 0.033 0.038 0.044 0.052 (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) *** *** *** *** *** *** Squared age 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.001 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Education (less than primary education=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** Primary education 0.052 0.044 0.044 0.043 0.065 0.054 (0.006) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.010) (0.014) Lower secondary 0.064 0.053 0.049 0.056 0.078 0.067 *** *** *** *** *** *** education (0.006) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.009) (0.014) Upper secondary 0.218 0.149 0.170 0.201 0.250 0.252 *** *** *** *** *** *** education (0.006) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.010) (0.014) *** *** *** *** *** *** University education 0.500 0.315 0.397 0.493 0.575 0.589 (0.007) (0.008) (0.008) (0.007) (0.010) (0.015) *** *** *** *** *** *** Tenure 0.012 0.012 0.012 0.012 0.011 0.009 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 252 Journal of Applied Economics Table A1 (continued). OLS and quantile regression estimates for male Spanish employees (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Firm size (less than 50 employees=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** 50-199 employees 0.137 0.110 0.125 0.159 0.163 0.135 (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.007) *** *** *** *** *** *** 200 or more employees 0.234 0.224 0.250 0.262 0.249 0.210 (0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.008) Observations 89,694 89,694 89,694 89,694 89,694 89,694 R 0.356 0.165 0.206 0.240 0.222 0.197 Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. McFadden R reported in quantile regressions. An intercept, eleven dummies for sector of activity of the firm and seventeen regional dummies are also included *** ** * in all regressions. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 253 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table A2. OLS and quantile regression estimates for male Latin American and Caribbean employees (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 ** ** ** Age 0.019 0.016 0.007 0.018 0.020 0.014 (0.009) (0.007) (0.007) (0.008) (0.013) (0.018) ** ** ** Squared age 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Education (less than primary education=0) *** * ** ** Primary education 0.062 0.030 0.034 0.047 0.051 0.046 (0.020) (0.018) (0.018) (0.019) (0.031) (0.043) Lower secondary 0.068 0.007 0.037 0.056 0.080 0.060 *** * *** ** education (0.021) (0.019) (0.018) (0.020) (0.032) (0.044) Upper secondary 0.096 0.018 0.052 0.078 0.089 0.077 *** ** *** ** education (0.027) (0.022) (0.022) (0.023) (0.037) (0.052) *** *** *** *** *** *** University education 0.313 0.115 0.157 0.255 0.374 0.481 (0.041) (0.029) (0.028) (0.029) (0.046) (0.067) *** *** *** *** *** Tenure 0.027 0.003 0.011 0.024 0.033 0.061 (0.006) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.005) (0.005) jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 254 Journal of Applied Economics Table A2 (continued). OLS and quantile regression estimates for male Latin American and Caribbean employees (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Firm size (less than 50 employees=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** 50-199 employees 0.086 0.041 0.039 0.058 0.125 0.135 (0.017) (0.015) (0.014) (0.015) (0.025) (0.035) *** *** *** *** *** *** 200 or more employees 0.258 0.090 0.125 0.242 0.346 0.473 (0.025) (0.018) (0.018) (0.019) (0.031) (0.044) Observations 2,688 2,688 2,688 2,688 2,688 2,688 R 0.198 0.104 0.082 0.102 0.149 0.197 Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. McFadden R reported in quantile regressions. An intercept, eleven dummies for sector of activity of the firm and seventeen regional dummies are also included *** ** * in all regressions. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 255 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table A3. OLS and quantile regression estimates for other male foreign employees from developing countries (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Age -0.002 -0.005 -0.003 0.002 0.004 0.007 (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.011) (0.015) Squared age 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Education (less than primary education=0) *** ** ** ** ** Primary education 0.051 0.036 0.024 0.032 0.056 0.073 (0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.014) (0.023) (0.031) *** Lower secondary 0.020 0.007 0.022 0.040 -0.007 0.012 education (0.016) (0.017) (0.016) (0.015) (0.024) (0.032) *** ** *** *** *** ** 0.089 0.060 0.067 0.070 0.075 0.112 Upper secondary education (0.024) (0.023) (0.022) (0.020) (0.033) (0.046) *** ** *** *** ** *** University education 0.258 0.070 0.077 0.209 0.310 0.504 (0.048) (0.031) (0.030) (0.028) (0.046) (0.058) *** *** *** *** *** *** Tenure 0.017 0.011 0.012 0.014 0.023 0.027 (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003) jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 256 Journal of Applied Economics Table A3 (continued). OLS and quantile regression estimates for other male foreign employees from developing countries (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Firm size (less than 50 employees=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** 50-199 employees 0.133 0.067 0.060 0.112 0.184 0.223 (0.015) (0.014) (0.013) (0.012) (0.020) (0.026) *** *** *** *** *** *** 200 or more employees 0.185 0.096 0.099 0.155 0.244 0.275 (0.021) (0.021) (0.018) (0.017) (0.029) (0.039) Observations 3,552 3,552 3,552 3,552 3,552 3,552 R 0.145 0.090 0.062 0.067 0.114 0.145 Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. McFadden R reported in quantile regressions. An intercept, eleven dummies for sector of activity of the firm and seventeen regional dummies are also included *** ** * in all regressions. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 257 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table A4. OLS and quantile regression estimates for other male foreign employees from developed countries (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90th *** * *** *** *** *** Age 0.067 0.024 0.033 0.039 0.051 0.087 (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.014) (0.016) (0.026) *** * *** *** *** *** Squared age -0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.001 -0.001 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Education (less than primary education=0) Primary education 0.034 -0.032 0.029 0.007 0.052 0.119 (0.032) (0.038) (0.035) (0.042) (0.050) (0.075) Lower secondary -0.017 -0.028 -0.011 -0.041 -0.001 0.077 education (0.036) (0.042) (0.038) (0.044) (0.053) (0.079) *** ** *** *** *** 0.143 0.006 0.083 0.162 0.174 0.236 Upper secondary education (0.041) (0.045) (0.040) (0.046) (0.055) (0.083) *** *** *** *** *** *** University education 0.529 0.334 0.406 0.573 0.608 0.659 (0.048) (0.050) (0.043) (0.049) (0.058) (0.090) *** *** *** *** *** *** Tenure 0.032 0.024 0.025 0.033 0.029 0.036 (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.005) jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 258 Journal of Applied Economics Table A4 (continued). OLS and quantile regression estimates for other male foreign employees from developed countries (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Firm size (less than 50 employees=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** 50-199 employees 0.170 0.147 0.128 0.138 0.170 0.234 (0.027) (0.025) (0.024) (0.028) (0.034) (0.049) *** *** *** *** *** 200 or more employees 0.152 0.195 0.193 0.180 0.144 0.082 (0.033) (0.032) (0.029) (0.035) (0.043) (0.065) Observations 1,636 1,636 1,636 1,636 1,636 1,636 R 0.422 0.179 0.210 0.273 0.317 0.319 Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. McFadden R reported in quantile regressions. An intercept, eleven dummies for sector of activity of the firm and seventeen regional dummies are also included *** ** * in all regressions. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 259 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants References Albrecht, James, Anders Björklund, and Susan Vroman (2003), Is there a glass ceiling in Sweden?, Journal of Labor Economics 21: 145-77. Albrecht, James, Aico van Vuuren, and Susan Vroman (2009), Counterfactual distributions with sample selection adjustments: Econometric theory and an application to the Netherlands, Labour Economics 16: 383-96. Amuedo-Dorantes, Catalina, and Sara De la Rica (2007), Labor market assimilation of recent immigrants in Spain, British Journal of Industrial Relations 45: 257-284. Arrow, Kenneth J. (1973), The theory of discrimination, in O. Ashenfelter and A. Rees, eds., Discrimination in labor markets, Princeton, Princeton University Press. Barth, Eerling, and Harald Dale-Olsen (2009), Monopsonistic discrimination, worker turnover and the gender wage gap, Labour Economics 16: 589-97. Beach, Charles M., and Christopher Worswick (1993), Is there a double-negative effect on the earnings of immigrant women?, Canadian Public Policy-Analyse de Politiques 19: 36-53. Becker, Gary S. (1957), The economics of discrimination, Chicago, Chicago University Press. Blinder, Alan S. (1973), Wage discrimination: reduced form and structural estimates, Journal of Human Resources 8: 436-55. Budría, Santiago, and Ana Isabel Moro (2008), Education, educational mismatch, and wage inequality: Evidence for Spain, Economics of Education Review 27: 332-41. Bosch, Mariano, María de los Ángeles Carnero, and Lidia Farré (2009), Information and discrimination in the rental housing market: Evidence from a field experiment, Working Paper 2009-21, IVIE. Brücker, Herbert, Gil S. Epstein, Barry McCormick, Gilles Saint-Paul, Alessandra Venturini, and Klaus Zimmermann (2002), Welfare state provision, in T. Boeri, G.H. Hanson and B. McCormick, eds., Immigration policy and the welfare system, London, Oxford University Press. Burdett, Kenneth, and Dale T. Mortensen (1998), Wage differentials, employer size, and unemployment, International Economic Review 39: 257-73. Canal-Domínguez, Juan Francisco, and César Rodríguez-Gutiérrez (2008), Analysis of wage differences between native and immigrant workers in Spain, Spanish Economic Review 10: 109-34. Carrasco, Raquel, Juan Francisco Jimeno, and Carolina Ortega (2008), The effect of immigration on labor market performance of native-born workers: Some evidence for Spain, Journal of Population Economics 21: 627-48. Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas (CIS) (2003), Barómetro de noviembre, Estudio 2545, Madrid, CIS. Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas (CIS) (2006), Barómetro de septiembre, Estudio 2654, Madrid, CIS. Chiswick, Barry, and Paul W. Miller (2008), Why is the payoff to schooling smaller for immigrants, Labour Economics 15: 1317-40. Chiswick, Barry, and Paul W. Miller (2009), The international transferability of immigrants’ human capital, Economics of Education Review 28: 162-69. Chiswick, Barry, Anh T. Le, and Paul W. Miller (2008), How immigrants fare across the earnings distribution in Australia and the United States, Industrial and Labor Relations Review 61: 353-73. De la Rica, Sara, Juan José Dolado, and Vanesa Llorens (2008), Ceilings or floors? Gender wage gaps by education in Spain, Journal of Population Economics 21: 751-76. DiNardo, John, Nichole M. Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux (1996), Labor market institutions and the distribution of wages, 1973-1992: A semiparametric approach, Econometrica 64: 1001-44. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 260 Journal of Applied Economics Dolado, Juan José, Juan Francisco Jimeno, and Rosa Duce (1997), Los efectos de la inmigración sobre la demanda de trabajo cualificado vs. Poco cualificado: evidencia para España, Cuadernos Económicos del ICE 64: 11-29. European Commission (2009), Discrimination in the EU in 2009, Report 317, European Commission. Available at http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/eb_special_en.htm [last accessed: May 29, 2010]. Eurostat (2006), Non-national populations in the EU Member States, Statistics in focus 8/2006. Fernández, Cristina, and Carolina Ortega (2008), Labor market assimilation of immigrants in Spain: Employment at the expense of bad job-matches, Spanish Economic Review 10: 83-107. Gammage, Sarah, and John Schmitt (2004): Los inmigrantes mexicanos, salvadoreños y dominicanos en el mercado laboral estadounidense: Las brechas de género en los años 1990 y 2000, Series Estudios y Prospectivas 20, Mexico, CEPAL. Gardeazábal, Javier, and Arantza Ugidos (2005), Gender discrimination at quantiles, Journal of Population Economics 18: 165 -179. Hammarstedt, Mats, and Ghazi Shukur (2006), Immigrants’ relative earnings in Sweden -a cohort analysis, Labour 20: 285-323. Hammarstedt, Mats, and Ghazi Shukur (2007), Immigrants’ relative earnings in Sweden -a quantile regression approach, International Journal of Manpower 28: 456-73. Hotchkiss, Julie L., and Myriam Quispe-Agnoli (2009), Employer monopsony power in the labor market for undocumented workers, Working Paper 14, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. Hunt, Priscillia (2008), Are immigrants so stuck to the floor that the ceiling is irrelevant?, Research Paper 838, Department of Economics, University of Warwick. Kim, Marlene (2002), Has the race penalty for black women disappeared?, Feminist Economics 8: 115-24. Koenker, Roger (2005), Quantile regression, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Machado, José A.F., and José Mata (2005), Counterfactual decomposition of changes in wage distributions using quantile regresión, Journal of Applied Econometrics 20: 445-65. Maddison, Angus (2001), The world economy: A millennial perspective, Paris, OECD. Manning, Alan (2003), Monopsony in motion: Imperfect competition in labor markets, Princeton, Princeton University Press. Melly, Blaise (2006), Decomposition of differences in distribution using quantile regression, Labour Economics 12: 577-90. Oaxaca, Ronald L. (1973), Male-female wage differentials in urban labor markets, International Economic Review 14: 673-709. Orrenious, Pia M., and Madeline Zavodny (2009), Do immigrants work in riskier job?, Working Paper 901, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. Phelps, Edmund S. (1972), The statistical theory of racism and sexism, American Economic Review 62: 659-61. Raphael, Steven, and David A. Riker (1999), Geographic mobility, race, and wage differentials, Journal of Urban Economics 45: 17-46. Rivera-Batiz, Francisco L. (2007), How do migrants from Latin America and the Caribbean fare in the US labour market?, World Economy 30: 1399-429. Robinson, Joan V. (1933), The economics of imperfect competition, London, MacMillan. Saint-Paul, Gilles (2008), Brain drain: Some evidence from European expatriates in the United States, CESifo Forum 3: 19-27. Sanromá, Esteban, Raúl Ramos, and Hipólito Simón (2009), Immigrant wages in the Spanish labour market. Does the origin of human capital matter?, Discussion Paper 4157, Institute for the Study of Labor. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 261 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Shamsuddin, Abul F.M. (1998), The double negative effect on the earnings of foreign-born females in Canada, Applied Economics 30: 1187-201. Silverman, Bernard W. (1986), Density estimation, London, Chapman and Hall. Simón, Hipólito, Esteban Sanromà, and Raúl Ramos (2008), Labour segregation and immigrant and native-born wage distributions in Spain: An analysis using matched employer-employee data, Spanish Economic Review 10: 135-68. http://www.deepdyve.com/assets/images/DeepDyve-Logo-lg.png Journal of Applied Economics Taylor & Francis

Labor Market Performance of Latin American and Caribbean Immigrants in Spain

Labor Market Performance of Latin American and Caribbean Immigrants in Spain

Abstract

This paper analyzes the wage differentials in Spain between local and foreign employees from Latin America and the Caribbean. It also explores the earnings gap between Latin American employees and other groups of foreign workers from both developing and developed countries. The study is based on the Wage Structure Survey 2006, which is the first nationally representative sample of both foreign and Spanish employees. Using the Machado-Mata econometric procedure, earnings differentials across...
Loading next page...
 
/lp/taylor-francis/labor-market-performance-of-latin-american-and-caribbean-immigrants-in-i54EvVUdva
Publisher
Taylor & Francis
Copyright
© 2010 Taylor and Francis Group, LLC
ISSN
1667-6726
eISSN
1514-0326
DOI
10.1016/S1514-0326(10)60011-6
Publisher site
See Article on Publisher Site

Abstract

jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 233 Journal of Applied Economics. Vol XIII, No. 2 (November 2010), 233-261 LABOR MARKET PERFORMANCE OF LATIN AMERICAN AND CARIBBEAN IMMIGRANTS IN SPAIN José Ignacio Antón*, Rafael Muñoz de Bustillo and Miguel Carrera University of Salamanca Submitted May 2009; accepted May 2010 This paper analyzes the wage differentials in Spain between local and foreign employees from Latin America and the Caribbean. It also explores the earnings gap between Latin American employees and other groups of foreign workers from both developing and developed countries. The study is based on the Wage Structure Survey 2006, which is the first nationally representative sample of both foreign and Spanish employees. Using the Machado-Mata econometric procedure, earnings differentials across the whole wage distribution are decomposed into a component related to observable characteristics and another associated to different returns to such endowments. First, we find that, in absolute terms, the earnings differential between Latin American and Caribbean immigrants and natives that is not explained by observable characteristics increases across the wage distribution. While the large gap at the top might be mainly explained by problems of transferability of skills among immigrants, the low differential at the bottom is likely to be related to the compressive effect exerted by labor market institutions such as the minimum wage and collective agreements. A quite similar pattern is observed when they are compared with developed countries´ workers. Secondly, there does not seem to be a significant wage gap between Latin American and the rest of foreign employees from developing countries, possibly because immigrants are largely employed in low-skill jobs where Spanish proficiency is not an essential asset. JEL classification codes: J71, F22 Key words: immigration, wage differentials, Latin America, Spain, quantile regression * José-Ignacio Antón (corresponding autor): Departamento de Economía Aplicada, Campus Unamuno, 37007 Salamanca, Spain, janton@usal.es. Rafael Muñoz de Bustillo: bustillo@usal.es. Miguel Carrera: mcarrera@usal.es. A previous version of this paper was presented at the Seminar Series of the Institute of Global Studies of the University of Gothenburg (Sweden) in April 2009. We thank two anonymous referees and the editor for their helpful comments, which have contributed to substantially improve this work. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 234 Journal of Applied Economics I. Introduction th Migration flows between America and Spain since the 16 century clearly illustrate how paradoxical history might be. When some Latin American and Caribbean countries were hosting thousands of Spaniards at the beginning and in the middle of the last century -among them, some of the most renowned Spanish intellectuals in history-, few people could even imagine that the situation would be exactly the opposite at the st beginning of the 21 century, with almost 2 million Latin American and Caribbean people (more than one third of Spain’s foreign population) migrated to Spain in search of better economic opportunities. In many cases, these migrants were descendents th of Spanish exiles or economic migrants to America in the 20 century. The aim of this paper is to assess how these Latin American and Caribbean immigrants fare in the Spanish labor market compared to both native-born employees and other foreign workers, particularly in terms of earnings. This topic is important for several reasons. First of all, labor market performance of Latin American and Caribbean immigrants has not received much attention outside the United States. Second, apart from the existence of a common language and shared cultural values, the interest of the Spanish case derives not only from the impressive increase in immigration flows experienced by the country during the last decade, but also from the Spaniards’ surprisingly negative attitudes towards immigrants according to opinion polls. For example, in 2006, in a period of economic boom, Spaniards considered immigration as the most important problem faced by the country, well above unemployment and housing (CIS 2006). In addition, most studies on earnings differentials between immigrants and locals are focused on Anglo-Saxon and Nordic countries, as well as Central Europe and Benelux, which have been the main host countries in the OECD until recently. In 1950 the GDP per capita of Argentina and Uruguay was twice that of Spain, while the Venezuelan per person income was three times higher than the Spanish one (Maddison 2001). It is worth mentioning that according to sociological surveys (CIS 2003), Spaniards tend to exhibit several prejudices against Latin American migrants. For example, 45% of Spaniards interviewed in 2003 by the Spanish Center of Sociological Research, when asked about what characteristics best define Latin American and Caribbean People, answered that Latin Americans were authoritarian (rather than democratic); 26% of surveyed locals described them as lazy (rather than industrious) and 57%, as conservative people (rather than progressive). In addition, according to the Eurobarometer 71.2, an opinion survey carried out by the European Union authorities, 66% of Spaniards thought that discrimination on grounds of ethnic origin (which in Spain is almost a synonym of immigration from developing countries) is fairly widespread or very widespread in the country in 2009 (European Commission 2009). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 235 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants With that objective, we use a recently released earnings survey containing, for the first time, sufficient observations from immigrants. Using the Machado-Mata econometric decomposition (Machado and Mata 2005), we split the earnings gaps between Latin American employees and other workers across the whole wage distribution into a first component associated with observable endowments and a second one capturing the differential unexplained by these observable socio- demographic characteristics (or, in other words, the differential returns to such endowments). We find that, once human capital endowments are controlled for, the earnings gap between Latin Americans and both Spaniards and foreign workers from developed countries increases across the wage distribution, while there is no substantial earnings gap between employees from Latin America and the Caribbean and other workers from developing countries. The rest of the article is organized in four parts as follows. In Section II, we present the literature review and a brief historical background of immigration flows. Section III provides a description of the methodology and the database used in the paper. Our results are discussed in Section IV, while the last section summarizes and discusses the main findings of the research. II. Literature review and historical background Though immigration and the labor market is a popular area of economic research, most such work has focused on world migration as a whole or on specific countries, such as the United States, Germany, Canada or Sweden, which have often provided academics with large and comprehensive datasets. To our knowledge, Latin American and Caribbean immigration has received scant attention outside the United States, where, among others, the studies of Gammage and Schmitt (2004) and Rivera-Batiz (2007) can be highlighted. The former finds substantial earnings differentials between male and female Central American migrants, while the latter analyzes average wage gaps between Latin American and native-born workers. There is plenty of evidence suggesting the existence of wage differentials between locals and migrants once we control for observable characteristics in international case studies, although there is no consistent pattern across countries. For example, the pay disadvantage faced by foreign-born workers is concentrated mainly at the bottom of earnings distribution in Sweden according to Hammarstedt and Shukur (2006 and 2007) But it is roughly constant according to Albrecht, Björklund and Vroman (2003). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 236 Journal of Applied Economics and the U.K. (Hunt 2008), while it increases along with wages in the U.S. and Australia (Chiswick, Le and Miller 2008). Apart from the role of human capital stocks, there are several reasons that can contribute to explain the earnings gap between migrants and natives. First, the main source of these differentials might be associated with the limited transferability of immigrants’ skills, that is, education and training acquired abroad would not be recognized in the same way in the host country. This fact would result in occupational segregation and higher levels of over-education among foreign workers than among natives (Chiswick and Miller, 2008 and 2009). The recent work of Sanromà, Ramos and Simón (2009) for Spain, which find that human capital acquired in the host country yields higher returns than those accumulated in the country of origin, also supports such a statement. This factor might be also linked to the existence of differences in the quality of education or the absence of information on this issue for employers. If this argument applies, the immigrant-native wage gap at the top of the wage distribution should be larger than at the bottom since the jobs associated with the higher part of the earnings distribution usually demand higher qualifications. A second broad group of explanations for the existence of different returns to endowments comes from the theories of labor market discrimination or, in more general terms, differential treatment by employers. Their point of departure is Becker’s (1957) view based on employer’s tastes: some employers dislike people from other ethnic groups (modeled as a utility loss derived from hiring them) and, in competitive labor markets, if the share of prejudiced employers is sufficiently large, foreign workers might earn a lower wage than locals. Theories of statistical discrimination also offer a framework for understanding the existence of wage gaps between natives and immigrants based on the lack of information or informational asymmetries (Arrow 1973; Phelps 1972). If there is no perfect information on certain characteristics of immigrants (for example, quality of education) or firms have less knowledge of them, employers will tend to base their hiring and pay decisions on the observable characteristics of the workers, like the ethnic group they belong to. For example, it is worth mentioning that in the Spanish rental housing market, there is evidence that, ceteris paribus, migrants receive a differential treatment by landlords (Bosch, Carnero and Farré 2009). In the case of Spain, where immigrants from developing countries represent the exception in an otherwise ethnically homogenous society, the hypothesis of discrimination based on racial issues might have some room. See Arrow (1998) for a comprehensive and didactic review. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 237 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Another interesting and more recent perspective of looking at this issue is the idea of monopsonistic discrimination, inspired by Joan Robinson’s (1933) work on imperfect markets. Drawing on the idea of dynamic labor market monopsony, it is argued that workers’ labor supply to the firm (different from the labor supply to the market) might not be completely elastic because of job search frictions, heterogeneous preferences among workers or mobility costs (Burdett and Mortensen 1998). In this context, if it differs across groups, a profit-maximizing employer can exploit this fact by paying less to the group with the lower labor supply elasticity for the firm, other things being equal. There is a growing body of empirical literature showing the potential of this approach in explaining the lower wages received by women (Mannning 2003, and Barth and Dale-Olsen 2009), Afro-American workers (Raphael and Riker 1999) and undocumented employees (Hotchkiss and Quispe-Agnoli 2009). Considering that Spanish immigrants might have lower reservation wages (for instance, because of a lower access to contributory unemployment benefits based on previous labor market experience) and the excess of labor supply that has characterized the national labor market for many years, monopsonistic discrimination might play a role in explaining the existence of wage differentials between migrants and locals in Spain. Regarding the historical background of immigration in Spain, although this country was traditionally a country of emigrants (Latin American and Caribbean countries being their main hosts), since the middle 90s, in barely a decade, Spain has become one of the largest recipient countries of the European continent. The explosion of Latin American emigration to Spain is basically linked to the poor economic performance in Latin America in that period (often referred as the “lost half-decade”) and to the remarkable economic recovery from the 1992-1993 world economic crisis in Spain. Those two factors, together with a shared language and cultural values, definitely played an important role in explaining how migration th flowed in the opposite direction of what it was until the middle of the 20 century. In fact, the proportion of population born abroad rose from less than 2% in 1996 to roughly 12% in 2008, which made Spain the country undergoing the third largest increase in non-native population in the European Union (EU) during the last decade, after Greece and Ireland (Eurostat 2006). According to OECD statistics, nowadays the unemployment rate in Spain is the highest in the European st Union (20% in the 1 quarter 2010) and was 8.5% in 2006. Furthermore, the proportion of over-qualified workers is remarkably high, as around 35% of males and 40% of females reported having jobs where their skills were underutilized (Budría and Moro 2006). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 238 Journal of Applied Economics In terms of Latin American and Caribbean immigrants, the figures are even more impressive, since according to OECD and Eurostat data, in 2008 two out of three foreigners from Latin American and Caribbean countries living in a country of the European Union were located in Spain. As a result, according to the 2009 Local Population Register, 1,800,000 Latin American and Caribbean people presently live in Spain, accounting for almost one out of three foreigners living in this country. The most extensively represented countries among Latin American and Caribbean immigrants in Spain are Ecuador (21%), Colombia (16%), Bolivia and Argentina (both around 10% of total Latin American migrants). In spite of this relative novelty of immigration flows to Spain, there is some literature dealing with the labor market integration of foreign workers, although without making any distinction by nationality. The pioneering work of Dolado, Jimeno and Duce (1997) points out a negligible effect of migration on labor market outcomes at the beginning of the nineties, when the intensity of immigrations flows was very low. More recent research exploiting several data sources –among others, the Spanish Wage Structure Survey 2002, which does not offer coverage of small firms– reports similar findings for the second half of the nineties (Carrasco, Jimeno and Ortega 2008). Other researchers have focused on employment outcomes and occupational segregation of foreign workers, documenting different patterns of labor market integration among foreign-born workers depending both on socio- economic characteristics and country of origin (Amuedo-Dorantes and De la Rica 2007; Simón, Sanromá and Ramos 2008). These relatively poor employment outcomes, however, tend to eventually improve with the years of residence in Spain (Fernández and Ortega 2008). Finally, the work of Canal-Domínguez and Rodríguez- Gutiérrez (2008) aims to study wage differences between natives and foreigners in Spain, finds a substantial pay gap not explained by observable characteristics and which does not rise across the wage distribution, as in the case of highly educated women –the so-called glass ceiling phenomenon- (De la Rica, Dolado and Llorens 2008). This paper is the first one to specifically address the study of wage differentials faced by Latin American and Caribbean immigrants in the Spanish labour market. Furthermore, it includes several additional insights with respect to previous works on Spanish immigration commented above. This work is based on the Wage Structure Survey 2006, which, as it is explained in Section III, is more appropriate to carry out this sort of study than those used in previous works. In addition, we compute standard errors for wage differentials across the earnings distribution that allows determining if such gaps are statistically significant. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 239 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants III. Empirical strategy and data A. Data Previous studies of immigrant-native wage differentials have been constrained by serious data limitations, which, to some extent, are linked to the novelty of the immigration phenomenon in Spain. However, it should not be neglected that Spain is a step behind other OECD countries regarding data sources for analyzing labor market and social outcomes. This work is based on the Wage Structure Survey 2006 (WSS), released by the Spanish National Statistics Institute in December 2008. The WSS has several advantages over previous databases. Firstly, while neither the European Community Household Panel nor the Social Statistics on Living Conditions or SILC (the household surveys containing information on labor income from the middle- nineties), provide a large enough and representative sample of foreign workers, the WSS includes a sample of local and foreign-born employees representative at national level and whose size can be considered appropriate for analysing foreigners’ outcomes in isolation. For example, we have more than 10,000 employees born outside the EU, a sample size higher than the whole SILC. In addition, the WSS is based on administrative registers of employers, which is likely to increase the reliability of wage data. Secondly, the WSS 2006 overcomes the evident limitations of the previous wave of the survey, carried out in 2002. The WSS 2002 only contains information on workplaces with ten or more employees, an important shortcoming considering the undeniable relevance of small firms in Spain, where, according to the 2007 Observatory of European Small and Medium Enterprises Survey, more than 40% of total salaried workers are employed in firms with less than ten workers, being one of the countries where small and medium enterprises account for a largest share of employment in the European Union. This shortcoming might be especially problematic, since, according to data from the 2006 SILC, foreign workers are over-represented in small firms: while roughly 40% of native employees work in enterprises with ten or less employees, the proportion of immigrants in these types of firms is above 55%. Therefore, it is possible there is a selection bias, which, if based on unobservable characteristics or observable covariates not included in Details on sample design and questionnaires can be found at the website of the Spanish National Statistics Institute. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 240 Journal of Applied Economics econometric analyses of wages, will lead to inconsistent estimation of the effect of human capital endowments on wages. We limit our analyses to men between 25 and 55 years old for two different reasons. The first one is related to the double negative effect faced by foreign women in their double condition as females and immigrants. Second, as our database only contains information on employees (not considering unemployed or self-employed population), there is likely to be some selection bias based on unobservable characteristics. By restricting our analysis to the group with higher employment rates (males), we try to minimize this bias. A final point that requires some discussion is the definition of immigrant. The common approach in the economic literature is, when possible, to consider as immigrants those born abroad, since naturalization rules can differ depending on the country of birth because of the existence of special agreements with former colonies and so on. This is, for example, the case of most Latin American workers living in Spain. Unfortunately, this variable is not available in our database, so we have to use citizenship as a proxy for immigrant status. Fortunately, this issue does not have relevant implications in the Spanish case for several reasons. First, immigration in Spain is quite recent and has been concentrated in the last few years, which means that only a limited share of immigrants could have obtained the Spanish citizenship. Second, naturalization does not imply losing the first nationality in the case of Latin American immigrants, as there are international agreements allowing people from that region to have a double nationality. Third, using the micro-data of the Spanish Labor Force Survey from 2006 nd (2 quarter), which contains information on both country of birth and nationality (but not wages), the correlation among the working age population between having a foreign nationality and being born abroad is above 90%. The focus of the paper is on how Latin American and Caribbean immigrants fare in terms of earnings with respect to locals in Spain. Nevertheless, we also compare them with two other groups of foreigners. First, we contrast Latin Americans to those foreigners from geographical regions that on average have a lower level of development than Spain (European countries not belonging the EU-25, Oceania, Asia and Africa). Then, in order to study the specificity of the results found for Latin Americans, we also consider those workers coming from developed countries (among which EU-25 citizens mean 95% of total immigrants). In the European Union, natives tend to associate the concept of migrant with people from poorer This issue has been documented and studied by, among others, Beach and Worswick (1993), Shamsuddin (1998) and Kim (2002). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 241 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants countries, not from other rich EU members, whose citizens resemble nationals very much (Brücker et al. 2002). Actually, this second group includes a high share of retirees looking for a milder climate and a relevant presence of expatriates with a relatively very high qualifications and standard of life (they may receive pluses in their salaries due to their status as expatriates) from the myriad EU multinationals in Spain. Those predominantly Caucasian retirees and workers from EU countries are very far from the common image in Spain of an immigrant. Our sample comprises almost 98,000 observations, of which around 90,000 correspond to Spaniards and approximately 7,900 to foreign workers, with nearly 2,700 employees with citizenship of a Latin American or Caribbean country, roughly 3,500 from other developing countries and around 1,600 from developed countries. B. The Machado-Mata decomposition The seminal contributions made by Oaxaca (1973) and Blinder (1973) propose a relatively simple econometric technique to decompose the average gap into a component related to observable endowments and another one associated with differences in returns to observed characteristics. The main shortcoming of this approach is related to the fact that the gap in a certain outcome between two groups is likely not to be constant across the whole distribution of such outcome. For example, a null mean gap can be simply the average of large gaps of different signs at the tails, which obviously have very different policy implications than the absence of such gap. Several approaches have been proposed to address this issue and compute the gaps conditioned on observable characteristics across the whole wage distribution. We follow the approach firstly proposed by Machado and Mata (2005), though we apply their method following the slightly modified but equivalent version suggested by Albrecht, Björklund and Vroman (2003) and De la Rica, Dolado and Llorens (2008). The basic idea is to construct the counterfactual immigrant’s wage distribution that would exist in the hypothetical case that immigrants’ characteristics were remunerated exactly with the returns locals get for their endowments. In more detail, the procedure unfolds as follows: Other ways of analyzing unexplained wage gaps across the whole distribution have been proposed by DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux (1996), based on semiparametric estimation methods, and Gardeazábal and Ugidos (2005) and Melly (2006) using quantile regression. We evaluate the gap at natives’ coefficients, as De la Rica, Dolado and Llorens (2008) do when they address gender discrimination. On the contrary, Albrecht, Björklund and Vroman (2003) use the potentially jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 242 Journal of Applied Economics (1) Estimate quantile regressions for 99 percentiles using the native-born employees’ dataset. (2) For each quantile, take a draw from the locals’ sample and compute the predicted n n log wage for native-born employees at each quantile q, i.e., x b (q). Repeat the m n process for the immigrants’ database, calculating the predicted log wage x b (q). (3) Repeat step (2) M times and, in this way, obtain a counterfactual distribution of immigrants that reflects their remunerations as if they were paid as locals and the predicted distribution of immigrants retaining their characteristics and specific returns. Following Albrecht, van Vuuren and Vroman (2009), M is set to 100. (4) Profiting from the linearity of quantile regression, calculate the counterfactual m n m m gap, that is, the wage differential associated with coefficients, as x b (q) - x b (q). One task seldom addressed in Spanish literature is the computation of standard errors or interval confidence for the counterfactual gap, a non-negligible issue in order to test if gaps at different quantiles are significantly different from zero. Two different ways have been proposed in the literature: bootstrapping or deriving an asymptotic expression for the covariance matrix (Albrecht, van Vuuren and Vroman, 2009). To compute bootstrapped standard errors with large samples might be computationally cumbersome, so we have used the latter procedure, which, as far as we know has only been implemented by Albrecht and his co-authors. The relevant issue here is to compute the variance of the difference between the predicted quantiles of the unconditional counterfactual distributions. According to Albrecht, Van Vueren and Vroman (2009), the variance of θθ ()qq − () is given by mn m ⎧⎧ ⎫ 1 qq () 1 − q(1 1 − q) qq () 1 − Var[] θθ () q−= () q ⎨ + − 2 ⎬ . (1) mn m 2 2 99 M ⎪ fq θ () fq θ () fq[]θθ ()f[ ()q] ⎪ [] [] ⎩ mn mn m m ⎭ nn mn mm This variance can be consistently estimated using the predicted quantiles, θ (q) mm mn == xb () q and θ () q xb () q –which Albrecht and his co-authors prove to be mn discriminated group (in their work, women) as the reference group. Using this alternative assumption, we obtained qualitatively similar results. Estimates are available from the authors on request. We applied a slightly modified version of Machado-Mata’s method, as they take random draws from a uniform distribution between 0 and 1. Both approaches are equivalent in large samples. De la Rica, Dolado and Llorens’s (2008) work is a remarkable exception to this trend. For example, with our database, it took us more than two hours to run the model in Stata once. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 243 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants consistent estimators of the true quantiles θ (q) and θ (q)– and estimating by kernel m mn density f (·) and f (·), which represents the density functions of the counterfactual mn m distributions evaluated at each percentile. Obviously, the population density functions are not known; however, as long as the sample is large, it is possible to estimate them using kernel density methods. Note that standard errors for the difference ˆ ˆ between θθ ()qq and () will be larger, since they are not correlated and, hence, mn the covariance is null. The procedure described above allows us to compute not only the estimated gap at each quantile, but also to determine if those differentials are statistically significant. Regarding quantile regressions, following Koenker (2005), the model to be estimated can be expressed in the following way: Yq ()=+ xβε () q () q , (2) where Y denotes monthly gross wages (in logs), x includes a set of employee’s observable characteristics, β(q) is the parameter to be estimated, which captures th the proportional wage change in the q quantile conditional on x and ε (q)is a disturbance satisfying E (ε (q) | x) = 0. Therefore, one can write conditional population quantiles Quant (Y | X = x) as Quant (| Y X== x) xβ(q). (3) The β can be consistently estimated by minimizing the sum of weighted absolute deviations using q and 1-q as weighting factors for positive and negative errors, respectively. Finally, the set of covariates includes age, squared age, education, tenure, firm size, dummies for sector of activity of the firm and regional dummies. For comparative purposes, we also perform the standard Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition of differences in mean wages. Taking Spaniards as the reference group, the mean wage gap can be expressed as follows: nm nnmmnnmnm nm m Y −= Y x b − xb = x b − xb + xb − xb , (4) ()() OLS OLS OLS OLS O OLS OLS where b denotes the Ordinary Least Squares coefficients. The second term in the OLS parenthesis captures the differences in mean wages not explained by observable characteristics. Particularly, we use a Gaussian kernel and the optimal bandwidth suggested by Silverman (1986). jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 244 Journal of Applied Economics We proceed in two steps: first, we analyze the wage differentials between native and Latin American and Caribbean employees; second, we determine if there is a significant gap between Latin American and Caribbean and other immigrant’s earnings, considering the latter as the reference group. IV. Results A. Descriptive statistics The main descriptive statistics of the sample used in the analysis are reproduced in Table 1. They basically indicate that foreign employees are not a homogeneous set. Immigrants from Latin America and the Caribbean receive wages substantially lower than locals and foreigners from developed countries, while the gap with respect to other immigrants from developing countries is very narrow. They are younger and have lower human capital stocks –educational level and tenure- than nationals. In addition, compared to local employees, they tend to concentrate more in small and medium-size firms than local employees. Regarding differences between Latin American and Caribbean employees and other foreigners from developing countries, the most relevant one refers to schooling, showing the former a higher educational level than the latter. It is also worth mentioning that the proportion of foreign workers from developed countries who hold a university degree is three times higher than among Latin American and Caribbean workers and even larger than among local ones. This large percentage of highly educated people might be associated with the presence of foreigners from developed countries in managerial positions, which are usually referred as expatriates rather than migrants. B. Econometric results th th th th th Selected quantile regressions (at the 10 , 25 , 50 , 75 and 90 percentiles) and OLS estimates for Spaniards, Latin American and Caribbean immigrants, other immigrants from developing countries and foreign workers from developed countries are presented, for simplicity, in Tables A1-A4 of the Appendix respectively. Here, we focus on the estimates of the wage gap associated with differences in returns, which are computed following the method described above and presented in Table 2 and Figures 1, 2 and 3. These figures also show both the raw and counterfactual mean gap obtained using the Oaxaca-Blinder approach. The counterfactual gap is significantly different from zero across the whole jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 245 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table 1. Descriptive statistics Spanish employees Latin American Other foreign employees Other foreign employees and Caribbean employees from developing countries from developed countries Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation Hourly gross wage 11.96 8.07 8.35 4.97 8.24 4.87 12.25 10.85 (euros) Hourly gross wage (in 2.34 0.51 2.03 0.40 2.02 0.39 2.30 0.58 logs) Age 38.48 8.42 36.13 7.46 35.76 7.15 37.35 7.93 Education Less than primary 0.0673 0.2505 0.1618 0.3684 0.2404 0.4274 0.1161 0.3205 education Primary education 0.1955 0.3966 0.3460 0.4758 0.3697 0.4828 0.2598 0.4386 Lower secondary 0.2892 0.4534 0.2679 0.4429 0.2593 0.4383 0.1993 0.3996 education Upper secondary 0.2558 0.4363 0.1458 0.3530 0.0890 0.2847 0.1858 0.3891 education University 0.1922 0.3940 0.0785 0.2690 0.0417 0.1999 0.2390 0.4266 Tenure 7.15 8.20 1.49 1.90 1.72 2.75 2.48 3.84 Firm size Less than 50 0.5874 0.4923 0.5714 0.4950 0.5898 0.4919 0.4853 0.4999 employees Between 50 and 199 0.1891 0.3916 0.2567 0.4369 0.2835 0.4508 0.3246 0.4684 employees 200 employees or 0.2235 0.4166 0.1719 0.3773 0.1267 0.3327 0.1901 0.3925 more Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 246 Journal of Applied Economics distribution in all cases. In general terms, our results point out three stylized facts. First, the existence of increasing wage differentials between Spanish and Latin American and Caribbean employees across the distribution conditioned on endowments; pointing to the presence of a sort of glass ceiling similar to those described for female workers (Figure 1). Although all the theoretical explanations suggested in Section II might have some role in accounting for the existence of earnings differentials between migrants and locals, this particular pattern –a gap that grows across the wage distribution- deserves further comment. On the one hand, the increase in the gap across the distribution might respond to a limited transferability of skills acquired in the country of origin, a circumstance that is more likely to appear the higher the skill level required for a job. If a certain job at the bottom of the distribution demands very basic skills, it is quite likely that the possibility of non-transferability will be very remote and the opposite applies to the top of the earnings distribution. Particularly, the research work of Sanromà, Ramos and Simón (2009) documents well how schooling levels obtained abroad are not as profitable as human capital acquired in Spain and also that their work experience at home is not valued as it would have been if they had been acquired in the host country. In contrast, at the bottom, the gap is very small, which might be explained by the effect of the existing labor market institutions. Among them is the potential role played by the national statutory minimum wage. This tool would act as a lower wage limit, a floor irrespectively of other considerations. Those workers with almost no qualifications Figure 1. Wage gaps between Spanish and Latin American and Caribbean employees in Spain (2006) 0,6 0,5 0,4 0,3 0,2 0,1 0,0 0 10203040 5060 70 80 90 100 Percentile Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw mean gap Counterfactual mean gap Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. Log wage gap jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 247 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table 2. Estimated raw and counterfactual wage gaps by percentile Percentile Spanish – Latin American and Latin American and Caribbean – other foreign Foreign employees from developed countries – Caribbean employees employees from developing countries Latin American and Caribbean employees Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw gap Counterfactual gap *** *** *** *** th 10 0.1227 0.0206 0.0041 -0.0002 0.0601 0.0640 (0.0071) (0.0004) (0.0058) (0.0003) (0.0070) (0.0012) th *** *** *** *** *** *** 25 0.1939 0.0514 0.0106 0.0108 0.1212 0.1082 (0.0066) (0.0010) (0.0047) (0.0002) (0.0062) (0.0009) th *** *** *** *** *** 50 0.3204 0.1121 0.0059 0.0065 0.2364 0.1487 (0.0072) (0.0015) (0.0052) (0.0001) (0.0076) (0.0009) *** *** *** *** *** th 75 0.4324 0.1852 -0.0055 0.0049 0.4198 0.2154 (0.0097) (0.0017) (0.0085) (0.0002) (0.0119) (0.0015) th *** *** *** *** *** 90 0.4763 0.2312 -0.0175 -0.0235 0.5344 0.2725 (0.0143) (0.0002) (0.0132) (0.0007) (0.0161) (0.0013) *** *** *** *** Mean gap (OLS) 0.3102 0.1089 -0.0024 -0.0023 0.2766 0.1994 (0.0080) (0.0078) 0.0054 (0.0102) (0.0163) (0.0169) *** ** * Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 248 Journal of Applied Economics would be pushed up in terms of wage in comparison to the wage they would receive in the absence of a minimum wage. It is worth mentioning that the minimum wage has been rising considerably in Spain since 2004. For example, in real terms, it was raised by more than 10% between 2004 and 2006 and by more than 20% from 2004 to 2009, reaching 633 euros a month in 2010 (21 euros a day). Collective bargaining agreements, which cover both unionized and non-unionized workers in Spain, could have a similar effect at the former part of the distribution by setting wage floors in some sectors of activity higher than the national minimum wage. These elements of the institutional framework might be contributing to the existence of a lower gap at the bottom by imposing minimum earnings thresholds. Although the remunerations set by the minimum wage and collective agreements also affect native men, the higher concentration of immigrant men from developing countries at the lower-end of the wage distribution allows this group to profit more from the effects of these institutions. In the second place, when Latin American and Caribbean workers are compared to other foreigners from developing countries, both raw and counterfactual wage gaps are tiny (Figure 2), suggesting that they experience quite similar difficulties in the Spanish labor market, Spanish language proficiency not meaning a significant advantage in terms of earnings. This can be linked to the fact that most immigrants are employed in low-skill jobs. Lastly, we compare the wage gap between Latin American and Caribbean employees and foreigners from developed countries, which, as mentioned, are essentially citizens from other rich EU countries (Figure 3). The raw mean gap is quite similar to the differential found with respect to Spaniards but the counterfactual mean gap is almost twice. As in Figure 1, the counterfactual differential increases across the wage distribution and is even larger than in the comparison with natives. In fact, if we compare locals and this group of workers from developed countries we find that, other things being equal, they are paid roughly as nationals up to the th 70 percentile but they receive higher wages than them at the top of the earnings distribution. This pattern is consistent with the interpretation of the most skilled part of this group as expatriate workers. This result is coherent with the finding of Saint-Paul (2008), who reports the existence of a positive wage premium for European-born workers in the United States, a result probably driven by unobservable differences in the quality of education. The results derived from the comparison between local and foreign workers from developed countries can be directly inferred from looking at Figures 1 and 3. Nevertheless, detailed results, not included here for brevity, are available from the authors upon request. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 249 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Figure 2. Wage gaps between Latin American and Caribbean and other foreign employees from developing countries in Spain (2006) 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0 102030405060708090 100 -0.1 Percentile Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw mean gap Counterfactual mean gap Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. Figure 3. Wage gaps between Latin American and Caribbean and foreign employees from developed countries in Spain (2006) 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0 102030405060708090 100 0.1 Percentile Raw gap Counterfactual gap Raw mean gap Counterfactual mean gap Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. Log wage gap Log wage gap jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 250 Journal of Applied Economics In order to do some robustness checks, we have repeated the analysis using hourly gross wages excluding bonuses and gross monthly wages. The results reported above hold for these alternative definitions of the dependent variable, also pointing to the existing of a wage penalty with respect to nationals for Latin American and Caribbean immigrants that is not explained by human capital endowments and that increases across the earnings distribution. These results are available from the authors upon request. V. Conclusions Latin American and Caribbean immigration has become an increasingly important phenomenon in Spain, a country of emigrants until not so long ago. In this paper, we have analyzed the native-immigrant wage gap across the whole distribution using the M-M decomposition. The main contribution of the paper has been to address this issue for the first time using a representative survey of the employed population. In addition, standard errors for counterfactual gaps have been estimated, a task not addressed by previous research on the topic in Spain or in most other national case studies. There are three main findings in this paper. First, the existence of an important glass ceiling for Latin Americans and Caribbeans living in Spain, that is, a wage gap that significantly grows across the earnings distribution. This pattern is consistent with the effect of labor market institutions (mainly minimum wages and collective agreements) at the bottom and the consequences of the eventually limited transferability of human capital accumulated in the country of origin and the existence of obstacles for migrants in accessing high occupational levels. Second, there are no important differences between wages earned by Latin American and Caribbean workers and other foreign employees from developing countries, which suggests that proficiency in Spanish might not be a very valuable asset in the labor market for foreigners, as long as they are employed in low-skill jobs. Finally, when compared to EU-25-born workers, Latin American and Caribbean employees face a similar earnings disadvantage when compared to locals, the gap being even larger at the top. It is well-documented that immigrants are usually employed in jobs involving harder tasks or worse working conditions (Orrenious and Zavodny 2009), which can contribute to the reduction of observed wage gaps if the principle of compensating differentials (at least partially) applies and detailed information on job characteristics is not available for researchers. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 251 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Appendix Table A1. OLS and quantile regression estimates for male Spanish employees (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 *** *** *** *** *** *** Age 0.045 0.029 0.033 0.038 0.044 0.052 (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) *** *** *** *** *** *** Squared age 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.001 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Education (less than primary education=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** Primary education 0.052 0.044 0.044 0.043 0.065 0.054 (0.006) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.010) (0.014) Lower secondary 0.064 0.053 0.049 0.056 0.078 0.067 *** *** *** *** *** *** education (0.006) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.009) (0.014) Upper secondary 0.218 0.149 0.170 0.201 0.250 0.252 *** *** *** *** *** *** education (0.006) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.010) (0.014) *** *** *** *** *** *** University education 0.500 0.315 0.397 0.493 0.575 0.589 (0.007) (0.008) (0.008) (0.007) (0.010) (0.015) *** *** *** *** *** *** Tenure 0.012 0.012 0.012 0.012 0.011 0.009 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 252 Journal of Applied Economics Table A1 (continued). OLS and quantile regression estimates for male Spanish employees (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Firm size (less than 50 employees=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** 50-199 employees 0.137 0.110 0.125 0.159 0.163 0.135 (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.007) *** *** *** *** *** *** 200 or more employees 0.234 0.224 0.250 0.262 0.249 0.210 (0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.008) Observations 89,694 89,694 89,694 89,694 89,694 89,694 R 0.356 0.165 0.206 0.240 0.222 0.197 Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. McFadden R reported in quantile regressions. An intercept, eleven dummies for sector of activity of the firm and seventeen regional dummies are also included *** ** * in all regressions. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 253 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table A2. OLS and quantile regression estimates for male Latin American and Caribbean employees (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 ** ** ** Age 0.019 0.016 0.007 0.018 0.020 0.014 (0.009) (0.007) (0.007) (0.008) (0.013) (0.018) ** ** ** Squared age 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Education (less than primary education=0) *** * ** ** Primary education 0.062 0.030 0.034 0.047 0.051 0.046 (0.020) (0.018) (0.018) (0.019) (0.031) (0.043) Lower secondary 0.068 0.007 0.037 0.056 0.080 0.060 *** * *** ** education (0.021) (0.019) (0.018) (0.020) (0.032) (0.044) Upper secondary 0.096 0.018 0.052 0.078 0.089 0.077 *** ** *** ** education (0.027) (0.022) (0.022) (0.023) (0.037) (0.052) *** *** *** *** *** *** University education 0.313 0.115 0.157 0.255 0.374 0.481 (0.041) (0.029) (0.028) (0.029) (0.046) (0.067) *** *** *** *** *** Tenure 0.027 0.003 0.011 0.024 0.033 0.061 (0.006) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.005) (0.005) jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 254 Journal of Applied Economics Table A2 (continued). OLS and quantile regression estimates for male Latin American and Caribbean employees (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Firm size (less than 50 employees=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** 50-199 employees 0.086 0.041 0.039 0.058 0.125 0.135 (0.017) (0.015) (0.014) (0.015) (0.025) (0.035) *** *** *** *** *** *** 200 or more employees 0.258 0.090 0.125 0.242 0.346 0.473 (0.025) (0.018) (0.018) (0.019) (0.031) (0.044) Observations 2,688 2,688 2,688 2,688 2,688 2,688 R 0.198 0.104 0.082 0.102 0.149 0.197 Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. McFadden R reported in quantile regressions. An intercept, eleven dummies for sector of activity of the firm and seventeen regional dummies are also included *** ** * in all regressions. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:13 PM Página 255 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table A3. OLS and quantile regression estimates for other male foreign employees from developing countries (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Age -0.002 -0.005 -0.003 0.002 0.004 0.007 (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.011) (0.015) Squared age 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Education (less than primary education=0) *** ** ** ** ** Primary education 0.051 0.036 0.024 0.032 0.056 0.073 (0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.014) (0.023) (0.031) *** Lower secondary 0.020 0.007 0.022 0.040 -0.007 0.012 education (0.016) (0.017) (0.016) (0.015) (0.024) (0.032) *** ** *** *** *** ** 0.089 0.060 0.067 0.070 0.075 0.112 Upper secondary education (0.024) (0.023) (0.022) (0.020) (0.033) (0.046) *** ** *** *** ** *** University education 0.258 0.070 0.077 0.209 0.310 0.504 (0.048) (0.031) (0.030) (0.028) (0.046) (0.058) *** *** *** *** *** *** Tenure 0.017 0.011 0.012 0.014 0.023 0.027 (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003) jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 256 Journal of Applied Economics Table A3 (continued). OLS and quantile regression estimates for other male foreign employees from developing countries (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Firm size (less than 50 employees=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** 50-199 employees 0.133 0.067 0.060 0.112 0.184 0.223 (0.015) (0.014) (0.013) (0.012) (0.020) (0.026) *** *** *** *** *** *** 200 or more employees 0.185 0.096 0.099 0.155 0.244 0.275 (0.021) (0.021) (0.018) (0.017) (0.029) (0.039) Observations 3,552 3,552 3,552 3,552 3,552 3,552 R 0.145 0.090 0.062 0.067 0.114 0.145 Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. McFadden R reported in quantile regressions. An intercept, eleven dummies for sector of activity of the firm and seventeen regional dummies are also included *** ** * in all regressions. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 257 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Table A4. OLS and quantile regression estimates for other male foreign employees from developed countries (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90th *** * *** *** *** *** Age 0.067 0.024 0.033 0.039 0.051 0.087 (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.014) (0.016) (0.026) *** * *** *** *** *** Squared age -0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.001 -0.001 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Education (less than primary education=0) Primary education 0.034 -0.032 0.029 0.007 0.052 0.119 (0.032) (0.038) (0.035) (0.042) (0.050) (0.075) Lower secondary -0.017 -0.028 -0.011 -0.041 -0.001 0.077 education (0.036) (0.042) (0.038) (0.044) (0.053) (0.079) *** ** *** *** *** 0.143 0.006 0.083 0.162 0.174 0.236 Upper secondary education (0.041) (0.045) (0.040) (0.046) (0.055) (0.083) *** *** *** *** *** *** University education 0.529 0.334 0.406 0.573 0.608 0.659 (0.048) (0.050) (0.043) (0.049) (0.058) (0.090) *** *** *** *** *** *** Tenure 0.032 0.024 0.025 0.033 0.029 0.036 (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.005) jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 258 Journal of Applied Economics Table A4 (continued). OLS and quantile regression estimates for other male foreign employees from developed countries (2006) OLS Coefficients of quantile regressions by percentile th th th th th coefficients 10 25 50 75 90 Firm size (less than 50 employees=0) *** *** *** *** *** *** 50-199 employees 0.170 0.147 0.128 0.138 0.170 0.234 (0.027) (0.025) (0.024) (0.028) (0.034) (0.049) *** *** *** *** *** 200 or more employees 0.152 0.195 0.193 0.180 0.144 0.082 (0.033) (0.032) (0.029) (0.035) (0.043) (0.065) Observations 1,636 1,636 1,636 1,636 1,636 1,636 R 0.422 0.179 0.210 0.273 0.317 0.319 Notes: Standard errors between parentheses. McFadden R reported in quantile regressions. An intercept, eleven dummies for sector of activity of the firm and seventeen regional dummies are also included *** ** * in all regressions. significant at 1% significant at 5% significant at 10%. Source: authors’ analysis from WSS 2006. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 259 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants References Albrecht, James, Anders Björklund, and Susan Vroman (2003), Is there a glass ceiling in Sweden?, Journal of Labor Economics 21: 145-77. Albrecht, James, Aico van Vuuren, and Susan Vroman (2009), Counterfactual distributions with sample selection adjustments: Econometric theory and an application to the Netherlands, Labour Economics 16: 383-96. Amuedo-Dorantes, Catalina, and Sara De la Rica (2007), Labor market assimilation of recent immigrants in Spain, British Journal of Industrial Relations 45: 257-284. Arrow, Kenneth J. (1973), The theory of discrimination, in O. Ashenfelter and A. Rees, eds., Discrimination in labor markets, Princeton, Princeton University Press. Barth, Eerling, and Harald Dale-Olsen (2009), Monopsonistic discrimination, worker turnover and the gender wage gap, Labour Economics 16: 589-97. Beach, Charles M., and Christopher Worswick (1993), Is there a double-negative effect on the earnings of immigrant women?, Canadian Public Policy-Analyse de Politiques 19: 36-53. Becker, Gary S. (1957), The economics of discrimination, Chicago, Chicago University Press. Blinder, Alan S. (1973), Wage discrimination: reduced form and structural estimates, Journal of Human Resources 8: 436-55. Budría, Santiago, and Ana Isabel Moro (2008), Education, educational mismatch, and wage inequality: Evidence for Spain, Economics of Education Review 27: 332-41. Bosch, Mariano, María de los Ángeles Carnero, and Lidia Farré (2009), Information and discrimination in the rental housing market: Evidence from a field experiment, Working Paper 2009-21, IVIE. Brücker, Herbert, Gil S. Epstein, Barry McCormick, Gilles Saint-Paul, Alessandra Venturini, and Klaus Zimmermann (2002), Welfare state provision, in T. Boeri, G.H. Hanson and B. McCormick, eds., Immigration policy and the welfare system, London, Oxford University Press. Burdett, Kenneth, and Dale T. Mortensen (1998), Wage differentials, employer size, and unemployment, International Economic Review 39: 257-73. Canal-Domínguez, Juan Francisco, and César Rodríguez-Gutiérrez (2008), Analysis of wage differences between native and immigrant workers in Spain, Spanish Economic Review 10: 109-34. Carrasco, Raquel, Juan Francisco Jimeno, and Carolina Ortega (2008), The effect of immigration on labor market performance of native-born workers: Some evidence for Spain, Journal of Population Economics 21: 627-48. Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas (CIS) (2003), Barómetro de noviembre, Estudio 2545, Madrid, CIS. Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas (CIS) (2006), Barómetro de septiembre, Estudio 2654, Madrid, CIS. Chiswick, Barry, and Paul W. Miller (2008), Why is the payoff to schooling smaller for immigrants, Labour Economics 15: 1317-40. Chiswick, Barry, and Paul W. Miller (2009), The international transferability of immigrants’ human capital, Economics of Education Review 28: 162-69. Chiswick, Barry, Anh T. Le, and Paul W. Miller (2008), How immigrants fare across the earnings distribution in Australia and the United States, Industrial and Labor Relations Review 61: 353-73. De la Rica, Sara, Juan José Dolado, and Vanesa Llorens (2008), Ceilings or floors? Gender wage gaps by education in Spain, Journal of Population Economics 21: 751-76. DiNardo, John, Nichole M. Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux (1996), Labor market institutions and the distribution of wages, 1973-1992: A semiparametric approach, Econometrica 64: 1001-44. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 260 Journal of Applied Economics Dolado, Juan José, Juan Francisco Jimeno, and Rosa Duce (1997), Los efectos de la inmigración sobre la demanda de trabajo cualificado vs. Poco cualificado: evidencia para España, Cuadernos Económicos del ICE 64: 11-29. European Commission (2009), Discrimination in the EU in 2009, Report 317, European Commission. Available at http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/eb_special_en.htm [last accessed: May 29, 2010]. Eurostat (2006), Non-national populations in the EU Member States, Statistics in focus 8/2006. Fernández, Cristina, and Carolina Ortega (2008), Labor market assimilation of immigrants in Spain: Employment at the expense of bad job-matches, Spanish Economic Review 10: 83-107. Gammage, Sarah, and John Schmitt (2004): Los inmigrantes mexicanos, salvadoreños y dominicanos en el mercado laboral estadounidense: Las brechas de género en los años 1990 y 2000, Series Estudios y Prospectivas 20, Mexico, CEPAL. Gardeazábal, Javier, and Arantza Ugidos (2005), Gender discrimination at quantiles, Journal of Population Economics 18: 165 -179. Hammarstedt, Mats, and Ghazi Shukur (2006), Immigrants’ relative earnings in Sweden -a cohort analysis, Labour 20: 285-323. Hammarstedt, Mats, and Ghazi Shukur (2007), Immigrants’ relative earnings in Sweden -a quantile regression approach, International Journal of Manpower 28: 456-73. Hotchkiss, Julie L., and Myriam Quispe-Agnoli (2009), Employer monopsony power in the labor market for undocumented workers, Working Paper 14, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. Hunt, Priscillia (2008), Are immigrants so stuck to the floor that the ceiling is irrelevant?, Research Paper 838, Department of Economics, University of Warwick. Kim, Marlene (2002), Has the race penalty for black women disappeared?, Feminist Economics 8: 115-24. Koenker, Roger (2005), Quantile regression, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Machado, José A.F., and José Mata (2005), Counterfactual decomposition of changes in wage distributions using quantile regresión, Journal of Applied Econometrics 20: 445-65. Maddison, Angus (2001), The world economy: A millennial perspective, Paris, OECD. Manning, Alan (2003), Monopsony in motion: Imperfect competition in labor markets, Princeton, Princeton University Press. Melly, Blaise (2006), Decomposition of differences in distribution using quantile regression, Labour Economics 12: 577-90. Oaxaca, Ronald L. (1973), Male-female wage differentials in urban labor markets, International Economic Review 14: 673-709. Orrenious, Pia M., and Madeline Zavodny (2009), Do immigrants work in riskier job?, Working Paper 901, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. Phelps, Edmund S. (1972), The statistical theory of racism and sexism, American Economic Review 62: 659-61. Raphael, Steven, and David A. Riker (1999), Geographic mobility, race, and wage differentials, Journal of Urban Economics 45: 17-46. Rivera-Batiz, Francisco L. (2007), How do migrants from Latin America and the Caribbean fare in the US labour market?, World Economy 30: 1399-429. Robinson, Joan V. (1933), The economics of imperfect competition, London, MacMillan. Saint-Paul, Gilles (2008), Brain drain: Some evidence from European expatriates in the United States, CESifo Forum 3: 19-27. Sanromá, Esteban, Raúl Ramos, and Hipólito Simón (2009), Immigrant wages in the Spanish labour market. Does the origin of human capital matter?, Discussion Paper 4157, Institute for the Study of Labor. jaeXIII_2:jaeXIII_2 11/3/10 5:14 PM Página 261 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants Shamsuddin, Abul F.M. (1998), The double negative effect on the earnings of foreign-born females in Canada, Applied Economics 30: 1187-201. Silverman, Bernard W. (1986), Density estimation, London, Chapman and Hall. Simón, Hipólito, Esteban Sanromà, and Raúl Ramos (2008), Labour segregation and immigrant and native-born wage distributions in Spain: An analysis using matched employer-employee data, Spanish Economic Review 10: 135-68.

Journal

Journal of Applied EconomicsTaylor & Francis

Published: Nov 1, 2010

Keywords: J71; F22; immigration; wage differentials; Latin America; Spain; quantile regression

References