Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
C. Harvey, B. Dickson, C. Kormos (2010)
Opportunities for achieving biodiversity conservation through REDDConservation Letters, 3
(2006)
Protected area funding in Indonesia: a study implemented under the Programmes of Work on
N. Sasaki, F. Putz (2009)
Critical need for new definitions of “forest” and “forest degradation” in global climate change agreementsConservation Letters, 2
(2010)
World Development Indicators
C. Stickler, D. Nepstad, M. Coe, D. Mcgrath, H. Rodrigues, W. Walker, B. Soares-Filho, E. Davidson (2009)
The potential ecological costs and cobenefits of REDD: a critical review and case study from the Amazon regionGlobal Change Biology, 15
J.G. Bertault, P. Sist (1997)
An experimental comparison of different harvesting intensities with reduced‐impact and conventional logging in East Kalimantan, IndonesiaConserv. Biol., 94
(2002)
Simple measures with substantial impact: implementing RIL in one forest concession in East Kalimantan
D. Lindenmayer, K. Hulvey, R. Hobbs, M. Colyvan, A. Felton, H. Possingham, W. Steffen, K. Wilson, Kara Youngentob, P. Gibbons (2012)
Avoiding bio‐perversity from carbon sequestration solutionsConservation Letters, 5
Thomas Brooks, Thomas Brooks, Thomas Brooks, R. Mittermeier, G. Fonseca, G. Fonseca, J. Gerlach, M. Hoffmann, John Lamoreux, C. Mittermeier, J. Pilgrim, A. Rodrigues (2006)
Global Biodiversity Conservation PrioritiesScience, 313
Jonah Busch, F. Godoy, W. Turner, C. Harvey (2011)
Biodiversity co‐benefits of reducing emissions from deforestation under alternative reference levels and levels of financeConservation Letters, 4
T. Gardner, N. Burgess, N. Aguilar-Amuchastegui, J. Barlow, E. Berenguer, T. Clements, F. Danielsen, J. Ferreira, W. Foden, V. Kapos, S. Khan, A. Lees, Luke Parry, R. Roman-Cuesta, C. Schmitt, N. Strange, I. Theilade (2012)
A framework for integrating biodiversity concerns into national REDD+ programmesBiological Conservation, 154
A. Espinola‐Arredondo, F. Munoz‐Garcia (2011)
Free‐riding in international environmental agreements: A signaling approach to non‐enforceable treatiesConserv. Lett., 23
O. Venter, W. Laurance, T. Iwamura, K. Wilson, R. Fuller, H. Possingham (2009)
Harnessing Carbon Payments to Protect BiodiversityScience, 326
J. Caldecott, L. Miles (2005)
World Atlas of Great Apes and their Conservation
Kerrie Wilson, Erik Meijaard, SIMON Drummond, H. Grantham, Luigi Boitani, G. Catullo, Lenny Christie, Rona Dennis, I. Dutton, A. Falcucci, Luigi Maiorano, Hugh Possingham, C. Rondinini, Will Turner, Oscar Venter, Matthew Watts (2010)
Conserving biodiversity in production landscapes.Ecological applications : a publication of the Ecological Society of America, 20 6
(2008)
Consolidation report: reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation in Indonesia. Forest Research and Development Agency, Indonesian Ministry of Forestry
Matthew Watts, I. Ball, Romola Stewart, C. Klein, K. Wilson, C. Steinback, R. Lourival, L. Kircher, H. Possingham (2009)
Marxan with Zones: Software for optimal conservation based land- and sea-use zoningEnviron. Model. Softw., 24
A. Moilanen, K. Wilson, H. Possingham (2009)
Spatial conservation prioritization: Quantitative methods and computational toolsEnvironmental Conservation, 36
S. Pimm, G. Russell, J. Gittleman, Thomas Brooks (1995)
The Future of BiodiversityScience, 269
L. Miles, V. Kapos (2008)
Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation: Global Land-Use ImplicationsScience, 320
M. Bode, W. Probert, W. Turner, K. Wilson, O. Venter (2010)
Conservation Planning with Multiple Organizations and ObjectivesConservation Biology, 25
Soong Lee (2010)
World development indicators 2010
Ana Espínola‐Arredondo, Félix Muñoz-García (2011)
Free-riding in international environmental agreements: A signaling approach to non-enforceable treatiesJournal of Theoretical Politics, 23
(2010)
2009 consolidated financial reportBioscience
(2010)
The Nature Conservancy – Landscape High Conservation Value Mapping
N. Myers, R. Mittermeier, C. Mittermeier, G. Fonseca, J. Kent (2000)
Biodiversity hotspots for conservation prioritiesNature, 403
(2010)
The Nature Conservancy -Landscape High Conservation Value Mapping & Recommended Management for East Kalimantan with special focus on Berau and East Kutai Regencies
S. Wich, E. Meijaard, A. Marshall, Simon Husson, M. Ancrenaz, R. Lacy, C. Schaik, J. Sugardjito, T. Simorangkir, K. Traylor‐Holzer, M. Doughty, J. Supriatna, Rona Dennis, M. Gumal, C. Knott, I. Singleton (2008)
Distribution and conservation status of the orang-utan (Pongo spp.) on Borneo and Sumatra: how many remain?Oryx, 42
O. Venter, H. Possingham, L. Hovani, S. Dewi, B. Griscom, G. Paoli, Phillip Wells, K. Wilson (2013)
Using systematic conservation planning to minimize REDD+ conflict with agriculture and logging in the tropicsConservation Letters, 6
O. Venter, L. Koh (2012)
Reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation (REDD+): game changer or just another quick fix?Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences, 1249
A. Knight, R. Cowling, M. Rouget, A. Balmford, A. Lombard, B. Campbell (2008)
Knowing But Not Doing: Selecting Priority Conservation Areas and the Research–Implementation GapConservation Biology, 22
(2006)
Protected area funding in Indonesia : a study implemented under the Programmes of Work on Protected Areas of the Seventh Meeting of the Conference of Parties on the Convention on Biological Diversity
Marvin Siegel (2010)
2009 financial report.Journal of infusion nursing : the official publication of the Infusion Nurses Society, 33 4
A. Grainger, Douglas Boucher, P. Frumhoff, W. Laurance, T. Lovejoy, J. Mcneely, M. Niekisch, P. Raven, N. Sodhi, O. Venter, S. Pimm (2009)
Biodiversity and REDD at CopenhagenCurrent Biology, 19
S. Dewi, A. Ekadinata, Z. Said, F. Pambudhi (2010)
Berau, East Kalimantan: estimation of LULUCF carbon emissions of Berau district, East KalimantanCurr. Biol.
(2008)
Distribution and conservation status of the orang-utan (Pongo spp.) on Borneo and Sumatra: how many remain? Oryx
P. Armsworth, Isla Fishburn, Z. Davies, Jennifer Gilbert, Natasha Leaver, K. Gaston (2012)
The Size, Concentration and Growth of Biodiversity-Conservation Nonprofits, 62
F. Putz, K. Redford (2009)
Dangers of carbon-based conservationGlobal Environmental Change-human and Policy Dimensions, 19
(2002)
Wild Money: the human rights consequences of illegal logging and corruption in Indonesia's forestry sector
J. Bertault, P. Sist (1997)
An experimental comparison of different harvesting intensities with reduced-impact and conventional logging in East Kalimantan, IndonesiaForest Ecology and Management, 94
J. Busch, F. Godoy, W.R. Turner, C.A. Harvey (2011)
Biodiversity co‐benefits of reducing emissions from deforestation under alternative reference levels and levels of financeJ. Theor. Politics, 4
F. Putz, P. Zuidema, T. Synnott, M. Peña-Claros, M. Pinard, D. Sheil, J. Vanclay, P. Sist, S. Gourlet‐Fleury, B. Griscom, John Palmer, R. Zagt (2012)
Sustaining conservation values in selectively logged tropical forests: the attained and the attainableConservation Letters, 5
Ruslandi, O. Venter, F. Putz (2011)
Overestimating conservation costs in Southeast AsiaFrontiers in Ecology and the Environment, 9
B. Strassburg, A. Rodrigues, M. Gusti, A. Balmford, S. Fritz, M. Obersteiner, R. Turner, T. Brooks (2012)
Impacts of incentives to reduce emissions from deforestation on global species extinctionsNature Climate Change, 2
Reduced impact timber harvesting in the tropical natural forest of Indonesia. Forest harvesting case study 11
consolidated financial report
(2009)
Dangers of carbon-based conservation. Global Environ. Chang-Human Policy Dimen
Alexander James (1999)
A Global Review of Protected Area Budgets and Staff
W. Laurance (2007)
Have we overstated the tropical biodiversity crisis?Trends in ecology & evolution, 22 2
(2005)
World Atlas of Great Apes
W. Laurance (2007)
A New Initiative to Use Carbon Trading for Tropical Forest ConservationBiotropica, 39
Introduction Tropical forests are among the planet's most important biological treasures (Wilson ; Myers et al . ), but rampant deforestation is eroding this biome (Pimm et al . ; Laurance ). Biodiversity actors, including nongovernmental organizations, bilateral aid, and multilateral groups, are an integral part of the response to this tropical forest crisis (Armsworth et al . ), and together generate more than USD $6 billion annually to protect imperiled species and ecosystems (James et al . ). Presently, a new mechanism and an additional set of actors are emerging to finance the conservation and management of tropical forests. These actors are supported by the carbon payment mechanism termed REDD+ (Reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation, plus the conservation, sustainable management and enhancement of forest carbon stocks; Venter & Koh ). Early commitments of “fast‐start financing” for REDD+ currently total about US$4.5 billion, but future funds could eclipse current spending: The Green Climate Fund alone could raise up to $100 billion annually by 2020, a portion of which could be used for REDD+. The scale of these investments would fundamentally change conservation in the tropics (Venter et al . ; Busch et al . ). In response to this opportunity, a suite of studies have suggested ways to secure and enhance positive outcomes for biodiversity from REDD+. Recommendations include monitoring biodiversity outcomes (Lindenmayer et al . ), drafting policy safeguards for biodiversity (Grainger et al . ; Putz & Redford ; Harvey et al . ), changing technical definitions to the benefit of biodiversity (Sasaki & Putz ), outlining biodiversity friendly management interventions (Stickler et al . ; Gardner et al . ), and ensuring the widest adoption of REDD+ measures (Busch et al . ; Strassburg et al . ). All of these suggestions are aimed at influencing the design and implementation of REDD+ policies. At its core, however, REDD+ must remain a carbon‐focused mechanism, and its ability to adopt these policy suggestions may therefore remain limited. In stark contrast with the efforts to influence REDD+ policy, conservation science and theory has yet to explore how biodiversity actors could instead adapt their policy and behavior in response to the presence of REDD+ actors and opportunities. Most conservation agencies undertake a systematic planning process to identify priority areas and actions that ensure their limited resources deliver the greatest benefits (Brooks et al . ; Moilanen et al . ). There are a number of conceivable ways that biodiversity actors could adapt their business‐as‐usual policy of prioritizing investments in light of emerging REDD+ schemes. For instance, it has been suggested that biodiversity actors could engage REDD+ actors by co‐investing in forest protection (Venter et al . ). On the other hand, biodiversity actors could allow forests with high carbon content to be protected by REDD+, and then optimize their investments for biodiversity by focusing on high biodiversity but low‐carbon areas (Miles & Kapos ), which resembles a free‐riding strategy (Bode et al . ; Espinola‐Arredondo & Munoz‐Garcia ). Here, we critically assess the expected outcomes for biodiversity under five scenarios of a biodiversity actor adapting its prioritization policy in light of REDD+. We focus on a regional‐scale case study in the Berau regency in Indonesian Borneo. We simulate the effects of different interactive behaviors on emissions reductions and biodiversity conservation using a prioritization tool developed for the purpose of conservation planning in Berau (Venter et al . ), and additional data on the distribution of biodiversity features in Berau (Paoli & Wells ). Methods This section introduces the Berau case study, and then details the biodiversity features considered and the prioritization approach we use to explore policy scenarios. For a more detailed account of Berau and the prioritization approach see (Venter et al . ). Berau case study A landscape‐scale REDD+ program, dubbed The Berau Forest Carbon Program (BFCP), is developing in Berau. Also, The Nature Conservancy (TNC), one of the world's largest nongovernment conservation organizations, is active in Berau, both supporting the BFCP and investing independently in conservation outcomes. The regency of Berau covers 2.2 million hectares and is divided into three land designation classes: (1) protected forest, (2) production forest, which includes natural forest timber harvesting and monoculture timber plantations, and (3) land designated for conversion to agriculture (Web Figure 1a). There are five landscape‐scale management strategies being considered by the BFCP and TNC in Berau. In existing protected areas, Strategy (1) improve land management to reduce illegal logging, forest conversion and fire. In production forest, Strategy (2) implement reduced impact logging (RIL) techniques and Strategy (3) set aside some areas for carbon storage. In areas designated for agriculture, Strategy (4) retire oil palm permits in high carbon or biodiversity areas and Strategy (5) identify alternative sites for oil palm permits that are both agriculturally suitable, and low in carbon or biodiversity. A spatially explicit approach was developed to help prioritize among these five strategies and across locations in Berau (Venter et al . ). The approach uses the decision support software Marxan with Zones (Watts et al . ) to identify a spatial network of conservation actions that minimizes the costs of meeting prespecified planning targets (Moilanen et al . ). The basic spatial units for the analysis are 28,059 equal area hexagonal planning units measuring 1 km across. Where planning units were bisected by a land management boundary, such as an oil palm permit, the planning unit was split in two along that boundary. Marxan with Zones identifies which of the five strategies should be applied in each planning unit, based on the quantity of each conservation feature present in each planning unit (WebTable 1, WebFigure 2c‐g), constraints on the strategies that can be deployed in each planning unit (WebFigure 2a), and the costs of applying each strategy in each planning unit. We estimated the opportunity, start‐up, and ongoing management costs of the five REDD+ strategies (Table , WebFigure 2b). When calculating the opportunity costs for lands leased for private use, we included the opportunity costs of lost employment, lost tax revenues, and lost profits to the permit holder. For lands without private use rights, we included lost employment and tax revenues that could be derived if a permit were to be granted. We did not account for the displacement or “leakage” of competing land uses into areas not covered by conservation strategies. Data inputs used to calculate the start‐up, opportunity and ongoing management costs of REDD+ strategies being considered by the Berau Forest Carbon Partnership. All values given as a onetime upfront cost in 2009 US$. We calculated opportunity costs as the net present value from 30 years of lost profits using a discount rate of 10.5%, one typically used by Indonesian companies (SMART‐Tbk ). Management costs were estimated as the cost of an endowment capable of financing management into perpetuity, calculated using Indonesia's inflation rate of 3.56% and bond rate of 7.75% ( www.bi.go.id ) Strategy Parameter Value Reference All strategies that involve managing a forest strictly for carbon storage Program start‐up $51.69 per hectare (Wilson et al . ) Protected area management Ongoing management $70.88 per hectare (McQuistan et al . ) Managing forest for carbon in areas currently designated for logging and agriculture Ongoing management $311.22 ha −1 (McQuistan et al . ) Managing production forest strictly for carbon storage Opportunity cost‐tax $177.21 per hectare (FAO ; Bertault & Sist ; Hinrichs et al . ; HRW 2009) Managing production forest strictly for carbon storage Opportunity cost‐employment $36.73 per hectare (Bertault and Sist ; FAO ; Hinrichs et al . ; HRW 2009; World Bank ) Managing production forest strictly for carbon storage (selective logging, 30 year cycle) Opportunity cost‐ logging company profits $2125.20 per hectare; $639.65 per hectare (Hinrichs et al . ; Ruslandi et al . ) Managing production forest strictly for carbon storage (planned conversion to pulp wood plantation) Opportunity cost‐ logging company profits $1574.55 per hectare if forested $1109.32 per hectare if already deforested (IFCA ) Reduced impact logging Program start‐up $33.87 per hectare (IFCA ) Managing forested agricultural land strictly for carbon storage Opportunity cost‐ palm oil company profits $6766.00 per hectare (Ruslandi et al . ) Managing forested agricultural land strictly for carbon storage Opportunity cost‐ tax and employment $6772.70 per hectare ((AAL‐Tbk ; SMART‐Tbk 2010; Ruslandi et al . ) Establishing new oil palm permit Opportunity cost‐ REDD+ revenues $5 MgC −1 Annual tax opportunity cost per hectare = (a · b −1 ) · (c), where (a) is the $260 million average annual assessed forest taxes in Indonesia between 2003 and 2006 (HRW ), (b) is the 20 million m 3 national average annual reported volume of wood consumed by Indonesia's forestry industry between 2003 and 2006 (HRW 2009), (c) is the 45.2 m 3 /ha harvested on average using conventional logging techniques in Berau (FAO ; Bertault & Sist ; Hinrichs et al . ). Tax revenues are calculated using a 30 year average logging cycle. Annual employment opportunity cost per hectare = (d · e −1 ) · (c · f), where (d) is the 54,140 people employed in the legal forestry sector in 2005, the only year for which data are available (FRA ), (e) is the 29 million m 3 reported volume of wood consumed by Indonesia's forestry industry in 2005 (HRW 2009), f is the $1443.27 per capita gross national income in Indonesia 2005 (World Bank ) and (c) is as above. Employment costs are calculated using a 30 year average logging cycle. Because of the differences in logging volumes across locations in Southeast Asia and through time (Ruslandi et al . ), we limited our data collection to studies which were conducted in the last 10 years and based in Kalimantan. When converting logging volumes to profit per harvested hectare, we used the log prices and harvesting costs presented in Ruslandi et al . ( ). In Berau, logging concessions operate on a 30 year logging cycle, which means that on average 1/30 of their total concession area is harvested each year. To convert logging profits to net present value we used, N P V = ∑ yr = 1 30 P yri 1 + d yri , where P yr is the expected harvest profits in year i . Where new permits are granted in areas that store more carbon than will be sequestered through the growth of oil palms (40 MgC/ha) (Dewi et al . ), the new permit creates an opportunity cost of lost REDD+ revenues at a rate of $5 MgC −1 for each MgC that the area is expected to emit due to oil palm development. Biodiversity features As surrogates for biodiversity values in Berau, we focused on the Bornean orang‐utan ( Pongo pygmaes morio ) and areas identified as High Conservation Value (HCV) (Paoli & Wells ). Orang‐utans are a flagship species and one of the primary targets of conservation efforts in Indonesia, particularly on the island of Borneo (Wich et al . ). Based on P. pygmaes morio's distribution data sourced from the World Atlas of Great Apes and their Conservation (Caldecott & Miles ), P. pygmaes morio is predicted to occur across 594,000 hectares of Berau (WebFigure 1d). For HCVs, we used spatial data from a landscape‐scale mapping of HCVs across the East Kalimantan province (Paoli & Wells ), which includes the Berau regency. The mapping included HCVs 2.1 & 2.2, which focus on large landscapes with a capacity to maintain natural ecological processes, and HCV 3, which are rare or endangered ecosystems (WebTable 1 WebFigure 2e–g; Paoli & Wells ). We distinguished between strategies in their effectiveness at conserving biodiversity features. In particular, strategies which entail full protection (strategies 1, 3, and 4) were considered to fully protect biodiversity features, and reduced impact logging (strategy 2) was assumed to be 85% effective, the lower estimate of species retention from a meta‐analysis of the effects of selective logging (Putz et al . ). Oil palm plantations (strategy 5) were assumed to lack conservation value. Policy simulations We used the Marxan with Zones framework to simulate five plausible policy scenarios for how a biodiversity actor could alter how they prioritize conservation actions and locations in light of REDD+ (Figure ). We assume that the REDD+ actor is entirely focused on emissions reductions and indifferent to biodiversity outcomes. In some cases, this is an oversimplification as REDD+ policy does include specific safeguards for biodiversity (Venter & Koh ). However, the purpose of these safeguards is to prevent biodiversity negative outcomes, such as the conversion of natural forests to plantations, which is not a proposed REDD+ strategy in Berau. Five policy scenarios for how a biodiversity actor could adapt to REDD+ opportunities when prioritizing conservation actions and locations. The policy scenarios fall into two general cases (Figure ). In the first case, a REDD+ actor is currently developing or has developed a REDD+ project in the region, and in the second case, no REDD+ project exists in the region (although Berau already has a developing REDD+ project, many other regions do not). In both cases, the biodiversity actor can ignore REDD+ developments and opportunities (policy scenarios 1 and 4). In the case where a REDD+ project already exists in the region, the biodiversity actor could alternatively react to it by pursuing active collaboration with the project (policy scenario 2), or instead they could choose to free‐ride off the project (policy scenario 3). By securing habitats for native species, forest protection from REDD+ will inadvertently contribute to conservation targets. In the free‐ride scenario, the biodiversity actor essentially identifies the areas that will be, or are likely to be, afforded protection by the REDD+ project, and then prioritizes their biodiversity investments into the remaining unprotected areas of the region, such that the combined protection from each actor ensures the biodiversity targets are met. In the case where no REDD+ project exists in the region, the biodiversity actor can invest their funds into creating a REDD+ project in the region that is then able to harness additional funds from REDD+ funding mechanisms (policy scenario 5). For all policy scenarios, we assume that the biodiversity actor has fixed conservation targets, and they work within a given region, which in our case is the Berau regency. To determine if our results (which are the relative costs of meeting conservation targets under each policy scenario) are sensitive to target size, we tested both low and high targets for both the biodiversity and REDD+ actors, which were respectively set as securing 10% and 50% of each planning feature in the region. The REDD+ target is based on expected carbon emissions, which incorporates information on forest carbon stores and the vulnerability of areas to future land cover change (Dewi et al . ). Some biodiversity actors have very specific conservation objectives, such as securing populations of flagship species, while others have more general conservation objectives, such as protecting a portion of an eco‐type or landscape. To determine if our results are sensitive to conservation objectives, we test both specific and general biodiversity objectives for each policy scenario. The specific objective is to protect 10% or 50% of the orangutan habitat in Berau, and the general target is to protected 10% or 50% of each HCV. Also, because biodiversity protection in scenario 5 occurs as a collateral outcome from the REDD+ project and therefore it could not be predicted, instead of using specific targets sizes we explored the full target space of this scenario by using a high powered computer to run Marxan with Zones 24,000 times for 1 billion iterations each time. Figure and WebPanel 1 contain addition detail on how the policy scenarios were simulated within the Marxan with Zones framework. We do not present maps of our results because of the potential implications for the BFCP. Results In the case where a REDD+ project exists in the region, the total cost of meeting conservation targets in Berau is always lower if the actors collaborate (policy scenario 2) instead of ignoring one another when prioritizing investments (Table and WebTable 2). This is true both for the costs to the biodiversity actor, and the total cost to both actors: for the high conservation targets, collaboration (policy scenario 2) is $8 million cheaper for the biodiversity actor than the ignore scenario, and the total cost to both actors is $15 million lower (Table ). These results are not sensitive to target size, nor are they sensitive to whether the biodiversity targets are general or specific (WebTable 2). The cost to the biodiversity actor for meeting their high targets (50%), and the total cost of meeting planning targets in Berau in the case where a REDD+ project is already developing with the target of reducing expected emissions by 50%. Total cost is the combined cost to the biodiversity and REDD+ actors of meeting planning targets. Numbers in bold are the policy scenarios for each set of target levels that result in the lowest total cost and the lowest cost to the biodiversity actor. The orangutan target is to protect 50% of the distribution of orangutans, and the HCV target is to protect 50% of the extent of each of 13 High Conservation Values Orangutan HCV Cost Scenario target target Biodiversity cost Ignore (scenario 1) $16,203,890 $162,550,093 Collaborate (scenario 2) $8,613,309 $119,217,504 Freeride (scenario 3) $1,809,433 $92,256,177 Total cost Ignore (scenario 1) $439,114,159 $585,460,362 Collaborate (scenario 2) $423,932,998 $498,795,184 Freeride (scenario 3) $424,719,702 $515,166,446 While it is better to collaborate than to ignore REDD+ in Berau, our results indicate that if a REDD+ project exists in the region, free‐riding (policy scenario 3) allows the biodiversity actor to meet the same biodiversity targets with even further reduced spending outlays (Table and WebTable 2). For low conservation targets, the cost reduction is drastic (89% lower than option 1, and 79% lower than option 2). However, it is important to note that the total cost of the conservation network is always more when the biodiversity actor free‐rides (Table and WebTable 2). In the case where no REDD+ project exists in the region, the benefits of investing into creating a carbon‐focused REDD+ project (policy scenario 5) depend both on the type of biodiversity objectives that are sought and their scale (Figure ). The relative costs of creating a REDD+ project increases with increasing biodiversity targets. If biodiversity targets are low, creating a REDD+ project could be a realistic scenario for the biodiversity actor. But if biodiversity targets are greater than around 20%, the relative costs increase rapidly, especially for the more specific biodiversity objective of protecting orangutans. For very high target levels the relative costs start to fall again, which is an artifact of the conservation approaches (policy scenarios 4 and 5) converging as the system approaches near total protection. The relative cost of creating a REDD+ project in Berau (policy scenario 5). These are the costs of the REDD+ project relative to the costs of a traditional biodiversity project, where both achieve the same conservation targets. These costs can be viewed as the amount of surplus revenue that a REDD+ project would need to generate for each dollar invested from the biodiversity actor. Target levels are proportions of the total extent of each biodiversity feature in Berau. Each data point is the result of the best solution for the given target level from running Marxan with Zones 20 times for 1 billion iterations each time. Discussion REDD+ presents novel opportunities for protecting biodiversity in developing countries (Laurance ; Venter & Koh ), but these opportunities may not fully develop on their own. From a regional‐scale case study in Indonesia, we discover that when in the presence of REDD+ projects, biodiversity actors must fundamentally reshape the way they prioritize their conservation investments to truly capitalize on REDD+. From a strictly biodiversity perspective, our results indicate that the best way to adapt to the presence of a REDD+ project is to free‐ride. That is, biodiversity actors should allow the REDD+ project to protect forests that are REDD+ priorities, and then use biodiversity funds to protect the remaining, usually lower carbon, areas. This is because actions and locations prioritized by the REDD+ actor provide considerable collateral benefit to the targets of the biodiversity actor, allowing the biodiversity actor to focus only on biodiversity features not sufficiently protected by the REDD+ actor. However, from a broader conservation perspective that includes both biodiversity and REDD+ objectives, we draw very different conclusions. From this perspective, the best outcomes can be achieved when REDD+ and biodiversity actors actively collaborate. These findings are not sensitive to the level of protection or the type of biodiversity objectives considered. Our findings concord with those of Bode et al . (2011), who investigated the value of collaboration among biodiversity actors. In situations where it may not arise on its own, collaboration could be actively promoted by funding bodies which value both climate mitigation and biodiversity protection, or through direct negotiations between the actors. If a region does not contain a REDD+ project, we find that using biodiversity funds to create a carbon‐focused REDD+ project could deliver mixed results. If the targets are to protect up to 20% of the extent of biodiversity features, as is often the case in conservation, the REDD+ project would need to leverage between $1 and $6 for each dollar invested by the biodiversity actor, which in our opinion seems feasible. But if biodiversity targets are higher or very specific, such as protecting a population of an endangered species, the project would need to leverage up to $50 per dollar invested, in which case traditional conservation approaches may be more effective. Because of Berau's diverse and often charismatic species, substantial forest cover and high rates of deforestation, the region is an obvious target for both biodiversity and REDD+ actors, as would be similar regions across the tropics. We therefore feel that our results may be generally applicable to other locations where REDD+ projects employing site‐based interventions overlap with the actions of a biodiversity actor. Moreover, we believe that the Berau case study contains information relevant to REDD+ at a much larger scale. At the global scale, tropical forests consistently emerge as a global priority for biodiversity conservation (Myers et al . ; Brooks et al . ). In light of REDD+, however, it has been suggested that biodiversity actors should divert their funding away from carbon‐dense tropical forests, toward lower carbon biomes, such as savannahs and grasslands (Miles & Kapos ). This resembles our free‐riding policy scenario, which we have illustrated can indeed lead to substantial increases in the efficiency of biodiversity conservation at the regional scale. On the other hand, we also found that collaboration can substantially reduce the cost of conserving the tropical forest biome, which could make tropical forests an even more attractive investment at the global scale relative to other conservation options. There would be value in future research to clarify how these divergent effects balance out at the global scale. In addition, exploring the relative benefits of free‐riding versus collaboration for cases where the conservation target is a nonforest dependent species would be a valuable addition to our work. We found that for biodiversity actors, free‐riding is cheaper than collaborating with REDD+ actors. But we must note that our modeling assumes that areas and actions prioritized for REDD+ will actually translate into on the ground outputs. The implementation gap means that this may not be the case (Knight et al . ), and if REDD+ fails to deliver at scale, conservation targets could be seriously compromised by free riding behavior. Incorporating this uncertainty into studies of interactor engagement could conceivably reveal that the benefits of collaborating (which can reduce the probability of unexpected outcomes by improving information exchange), increase relative to the benefits of free‐riding. Moreover, we also did not incorporate the benefits of agencies sharing their on‐the‐ground experience, contacts and infrastructure, all of which would increase the benefits of collaborative planning and implementation by decreasing overhead and transaction costs. The actors and the funding mechanisms that drive tropical forest protection are changing. The imminent move toward a more carbon‐focused conservation undoubtedly holds considerable potential to conserve biodiversity in one of the planet's most imperiled biomes. Yet our research clearly demonstrates that those concerned with the fate of biodiversity must not simply stand by as spectators to the expansion of REDD+ initiatives, but either engage the mechanism through novel partnerships, or instead shift their investments to areas that will remain unprotected by REDD+. Continuing with business‐as‐usual conservation in the tropics could mean that REDD+ benefits go largely untapped. Acknowledgments We thank Gary Paoli, Phillip Wells, Sonya Dewi, and Bronson Griscom for their input, and we thank The Nature Conservancy, The Australian Endeavour Program and The Canadian National Science and Engineering Research Council for funding.
Conservation Letters – Wiley
Published: Nov 1, 2013
Keywords: ; ; ; ; ; ; ;
You can share this free article with as many people as you like with the url below! We hope you enjoy this feature!
Read and print from thousands of top scholarly journals.
Already have an account? Log in
Bookmark this article. You can see your Bookmarks on your DeepDyve Library.
To save an article, log in first, or sign up for a DeepDyve account if you don’t already have one.
Copy and paste the desired citation format or use the link below to download a file formatted for EndNote
Access the full text.
Sign up today, get DeepDyve free for 14 days.
All DeepDyve websites use cookies to improve your online experience. They were placed on your computer when you launched this website. You can change your cookie settings through your browser.